Skip to main content

The ‘Historical’ Transformation Problem

  • Chapter
Smith, Marx, & After

Abstract

Why did Marx start in Capital with ‘values’, and then proceed at a later stage in his analysis to ‘transform’ these into the ‘prices of production’ at which commodities under competitive capitalism actually tended to sell? I have been suggesting for many years now that part of the answer to this crucial question lies in the fact that Marx’s argument, although it took a logical form, was also intended to possess a significant ‘historical’ dimension. In putting forward this suggestion, I had never felt that I was saying anything particularly novel or original: I was as it were brought up on this line of thought, which I fondly imagined had been shared by several not unimportant commentators on Marx’s work, including Engels, Böhm-Bawerk, Hilferding, and Lenin. In an article in the June 1975 issue of the Economic Journal,2 however, I was taken to task for adopting this line by two economists, M. Morishima and G. Catephores, who claimed that the transformation problem in fact had no ‘historical’ dimension at all, and that ‘for Marx... value was reduced to a logical category deprived of empirical historical reality’.3 While I was not persuaded by them that my interpretation of Marx’s theory had been essentially wrong or misleading, I felt that they had quite convincingly shown that I had not always expressed myself on this issue with a sufficient degree of clarity and consistency. The reformulation of my views in the present essay will, I hope, do something to remedy this.

This article is an extended (and slightly amended) version of a note which was originally published in the June 1976 issue of the Economic Journal, in the form of a reply to the article by Morishima and Catephores which is referred to below.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. M. Morishima and G. Catephores, “Is There an ‘Historical Transformation Problem?”, Economic Journal, 85, 1975, pp. 309–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Ibid., p. 317.

    Google Scholar 

  3. The translations from and references to this review below are to the version which appears as an appendix to the edition of Marx’s Critique of Political Economy published by Lawrence and Wishart, London, 1971.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Ibid., pp. 224–6.

    Google Scholar 

  5. See, e.g., his letter of 1 November 1891 to Conrad Schmidt.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See, e.g., the reply by Morishima and Catephores which immediately follows my note in the June 1976 issue of the Economic Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Marx, Grundrisse (translated by M. Nicolaus, Penguin Books, London, 1973), pp. 107–8. Cf. Capital, Vol. III ( Foreign Languages Publishing House, Moscow, 1959 ), p. 282.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Grundrisse, pp. 100–1.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Ibid., p. 102.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Ibid., p. 103.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Ibid., p. 105.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Ibid., pp. 106–7.

    Google Scholar 

  13. There is no evidence to suggest that Engels, at the time he wrote the review, had seen the Introduction to the Grundrisse which Marx had written two years before but which he was never to publish. All that Engels probably had to go on, apart from the Critique itself, was Marx’s letter to him of 2 April 1858 describing the plan (as he then envisaged it) of his economic work. On the basis of this letter Engels could easily be forgiven for believing that in Marx’s economic work as a whole logic and history were going to be made to march hand in hand in a fairly uncomplicated way. The letter is studded with references to the relation between the two: at least three ‘transitions’ are described as being ‘historical’ as well as ‘dialectical’; it is pointed out that ‘the most abstract determinations, when more carefully examined, always point to a further definite concrete historical basis’; and, perhaps even more significantly, the prerequisites given for the determination of value by labour time are the same as those which Marx gives elsewhere (e.g. Grundrisse, p. 159) for the emergence of simple commodity production.

    Google Scholar 

  14. For example, by Morishima and Catephores in their article in the June 1975 issue of the Economic Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Commodities’ in Marx’s terminology are goods produced for sale or exchange on some kind of market by ‘private individuals or groups of individuals who carry on their work independently of each other’ (Capital, Vol. I (Foreign Languages Publishing House, Moscow, 1954), pp. 72–3). The ‘simple’ circulation of commodities, according to Marx’s account, is characterized by the formula C—M—C (Commodities—Money—Commodities), its ‘end and aim’ being ‘consumption, the satisfaction of wants, in one word, use-value’ (ibid., p. 149).

    Google Scholar 

  16. Capital, Vol. III, pp. 171–2.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Ibid., pp. 172–4.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Ibid., p. 172.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Ibid., p. 174.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Ibid., pp. 174–5.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Ibid., pp. 192–3.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Capital, Vol. I, p. 169. Cf. Marx’s Theories of Surplus Value, Part III (Lawrence and Wishart, London, 1972), pp. 112–13.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Grundrisse, p. 105.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Ibid., pp. 251–2.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Ibid., p. 252. The passage in which this phrase occurs begins with the following rather significant sentence: ‘As in the theory the concept of value precedes that of capital, but requires for its pure development a mode of production founded on capital, so the same thing takes place in practice’ (p. 251).

    Google Scholar 

  26. Capital, Vol. III, p. 174.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Cf. Capital, Vol. III, p. 189: ‘The value of the commodity remains important as a basis because the concept of money cannot be developed on any other foundation…’

    Google Scholar 

  28. Capital, Vol. I, p. 93.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Critique, pp. 50–1.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Capital, Vol. I, p. 89. Cf. ibid., p. 170.

    Google Scholar 

  31. See, e.g., Capital, Vol. III, pp. 857–8, and Theories of Surplus Value, Part III, pp. 112–13. Cf. also above, pp. 128–9.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Capital, Vol. III, p. 857.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Ibid., p. 14. In Capital, Vol. I, pp. 169–70, Marx goes so far as to say that an inquiry into the circumstances under which ‘all, or even the majority of products take the form of commodities’ would be ‘foreign to the analysis of commodities’.

    Google Scholar 

  34. The most extensive account of this process given by Marx himself is that in the Grundrisse, pp. 459–515.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Critique, p. 225.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Capital, Vol. I, p. 761.

    Google Scholar 

  37. But not in Russia (see Marx’s letter of 8 March 1881 to Vera Zasulich); and not only in western Europe (see Capital, Vol. I, pp. 765–6 ).

    Google Scholar 

  38. Cf. Capital, Vol. I, pp. 334, 583–4, 624, 714–15, 761–2, and 765–6; Vol. II (Foreign Languages Publishing House, Moscow, 1957), pp. 34–5; Vol. III, pp. 172–4 and 581–3; and Theories of Surplus Value, Part III, pp. 377–8.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Capital, Vol. I, pp. 150–1.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Capital, Vol. II, p. 111.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Capital, Vol. I, pp. 184, 248, and 310.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Capital, Vol. III, p. 177. Cf. Theories of Surplus Value, Part II (Lawrence and Wishart, London, 1969), p. 208.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Grundrisse, p. 761. Cf. Capital, Vol. III, p. 156, where Marx says that the rates of profit prevailing in the various branches of production are ‘originally’ very different.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Capital, Vol. III, p. 192. The whole of the passage in which this phrase occurs is of interest in the present connection.

    Google Scholar 

  45. On the role of credit in the process of the equalization of the rate of profit see Capital, Vol. III, pp. 192 and 426; Theories of Surplus Value, Part II, p. 211; and Theories of Surplus Value, Part III, p. 519.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1977 Ronald L. Meek

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Meek, R.L. (1977). The ‘Historical’ Transformation Problem. In: Smith, Marx, & After. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4899-7303-0_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4899-7303-0_7

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-0-470-99161-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4899-7303-0

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics