Skip to main content

Bank mergers and American bank competitiveness

  • Chapter

Abstract

In this paper we attempt to elaborate on the observation that “the common environmental feature that underlies mergers and acquisitions throughout the U.S. economy is increased competition.”1 Motivating this paper is the sharp contrast between the high cost of bank mergers and acquisitions and the large number of such transactions. The existing legal rules and regulations that govern bank mergers and acquisitions make such transactions very costly. The legal environment dramatically increases the transaction costs of mergers and acquisitions and especially of hostile takeovers in the field of banking.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. The Bank Merger Wave of the 90s: Nine Case Studies“, Charles W. Calomiris and Jason Karceski, Office for Banking Research, University of Illinois, Urbana/ Champaign, 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  2. The Economist, September 7, 1996, at 82.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Economist, September 7 at 82.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Macey und Miller, “Bank Failures, Risk Monitoring, and the Market for Bank Control,” 88 Columbia Law Review 1153 (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  5. Dewey, “Mergers and Cartels: Some Reservations About Policy,” 51 American Economic Review Paper and Prat, 255, 257 (1961).

    Google Scholar 

  6. Henry Manne, “Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control,” 73 Journal of Political Economy, 110, 112–13 (1965).

    Google Scholar 

  7. Id. at Ill.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Haddock, Macey und McChesney, “Property Rights in Assets and Resistance to Tender Offers,” 73 Virginia Law Review, 701, 709 (1987).

    Google Scholar 

  9. Calomiris and Karceski, The Bank Merger Wave of the 90s: Nine Case Studies (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  10. Diamond and Dybvig, “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity,” 91 J. Pol. Econ 401, 403 (1983) (“Banks are able to transform illiquid assets (into liquid assets) by offering liabilities with a different, smoother pattern of returns… Illiquidity of assets provides the rationale... for the existence of banks…”).

    Google Scholar 

  11. d. at 402.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Pension fund assets, which now exceed two trillion dollars, include nearly a quarter of all equity securities and half of all corporate debt. The pension fund, now the dominant player in the world of institutional investing, scarcely existed a century ago, and was unimportant until the latter half of this century. In 1950, pension plans accounted for only 15.3% of the total holdings of institutional investors; by 1983 pension fund holdings had risen to 58.5% of institutional investments. R. Ippolito, Pensions, Economics, and Public Policy 157 (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  13. See Macey und Miller, “Good Finance, Bad Economies: An Analysis of the Fraud on the Market Theory,” 42 Stan. L. Rev. 1059 (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  14. Macey und Haddock, “Shirking at the SEC. The Failure of the National Market System,” 1985 U. Ill. L. Rev 315 (describing the origins of the NYSE).

    Google Scholar 

  15. R. Sobel, Inside Wall Street 67 (1982).

    Google Scholar 

  16. Macey und Haddock, supra note 14, at 329–330.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Easterbrook, “Two Agency-Cost Explanation of Dividends,” 74 Am. Econ. Rev. 650, 654 (1984).

    Google Scholar 

  18. Id.at 653. We wish, however, to emphasize that the reduction in bank monitoring in trading markets is replaced by market mechanisms such as the market for corporate control, incentive-based compensation packages for managers, and competition in internal labor markets.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Typically, commercial paper matures in 90 days or less.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Litt, Macey, Miller und Rubin, “Politics, Bureaucracies and Financial Markets: Bank Entry into Commercial Paper Underwriting in the United States and Japan,” 139 U. Pa. L. Rev. 369, 375 (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  21. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  22. The Glass-Steagall Act, officially designated the Banking Act of 1933, is the popular name of Ch. 89, 48 Stat. 162 (codified in amended in scattered sections of 12 U.S.C.).

    Google Scholar 

  23. Section 16 is codified at 12 U.S.C. §16 of Glass-Steagall applicable to state banks that are members of the Federal Reserve System.

    Google Scholar 

  24. U.S.C. §77 et. seq. (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  25. Note, “A Conduct Oriented Approach to the Glass-Steagall Act,” 91 Yale L. J 102, 115 (1981) (Jonathan R. Macey, author, citing J.P. Judd, “Competition Between Commercial Paper Markets and Commercial Banks,” 39, 48 (Staff Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, on file with the Yale Law Journal))

    Google Scholar 

  26. The Securities Act of 1933 ’ 3(a)(3), 15 U.S.C. §77c(a)(3)(1988) exempts from the registration, prospectus delivery, and anti-fraud provisions of the Act notes, drafts, bills of exchange, and bankers’ acceptances arising out of a current transaction that have a maturity at the time of issuance of less than nine months.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Litt, Macey, Miller und Rubin supra note 20, at 378.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Id. at 379.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Haraf und Kushmeider, “Redefining Financial Markets,” in Restructuring Banking and Financial Services in America 3 (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  31. This phenomenon is easy to illustrate. Suppose at the time a loan has been made, a borrower has all of its assets in an investment with a 1.0 probability of returning $1000 at the end of the investment period. Suppose further that $500 of this $1000 must be used to repay the principal and interest which is due to the firms fixed claimants at the end of the investment period. In this expected value for the shareholders is the residual, or $1000 - $500 = $500. Next, suppose the borrower shifts its investments into a riskier investment, one with a.5 chance of a $2000 payoff, and a.5 chance of a $300 pay off. This investment is worse for the fixed claimants because now the investment has an expected value of $400 instead of $500. The expected value of $400 results from the fact that if the second investment does well and produces a return of $2000, the fixed claimants will be paid in full their $500, while if the investment does poorly and returns only $300, the fixed claimants will be paid only $300. The expected value of this investment is therefore $400 ($500X.5 + $300 X.5 = $400). On the other hand, the shareholders prefer the second investment because it increases their expected return from $500 to $1000 ($2000 X.5 + $0 X.5 = $1000). Thus shareholders have an incentive to shift from the first investment to the second investment after a loan has been made.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Macey und Miller, supra note 13, at 206.

    Google Scholar 

  33. See Daniel R. Fischel, “The Economics of Lender Liability,” 99 Yale L. J 131, 140–42 (1989) (discussing various interpretations of the duty of good faith and relevance of this duty in deterring opportunistic behavior by both lenders and borrowers).

    Google Scholar 

  34. See e.g. Farah Mfg. Co,678 S.W. 2d at 690.

    Google Scholar 

  35. See e.g, K.M.C. Co 757 F. 2d at 759–63.

    Google Scholar 

  36. See Fleet Factors Corp.901 F.2d at 1557–68 (noting that a creditor may incur liability for a borrower’s affairs if its participation in management indicates ability to intervene in the corporation’s affairs). But see In re Gergsoe Metal Corp., 910 F.2d 668, 672 (9th Cir. 1990) (stating that “some actual management of the facility” is required to establish liability of secured creditor for a borrower’s affairs).

    Google Scholar 

  37. In re American Lumber Co., 5 B.R. 470 (Bankr. D. Minn. 1980).

    Google Scholar 

  38. Id. at 478.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Mark J Roe, “Political and Legal Restraints on Ownership and Control of Public Companies,” 27 J. Fin. Econ 7, 9–21 (1990) (describing how law constrains financial institutions’ role in the corporate structure).

    Google Scholar 

  40. Lise Simmons, “Banking: D’Amato Introduces Sweeping Legislation Aimed at Financial Services Modernization,” 1995 Daily Report for Executives (BNA) No. 23 (February 3, 1995), available in Lexis, News Library, Curnws File.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1998 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Macey, J.R., Miller, G.P. (1998). Bank mergers and American bank competitiveness. In: Amihud, Y., Miller, G. (eds) Bank Mergers & Acquisitions. The New York University Salomon Center Series on Financial Markets and Institutions, vol 3. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4757-2799-9_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4757-2799-9_8

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4419-5187-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4757-2799-9

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics