Implications for Monetary Reform

  • Thomas Havrilesky
Chapter

Abstract

This Chapter examines the prospects for monetary reform. As the opening quotation states, the perceived need for any sort of reform is a product of suffering. Suffering implies that the costs of the arrangements to be reformed are quite high relative to the benefits. This Chapter begins by considering three types of costs to society associated with the current monetary policy arrangements. The first is the cost of inflation. The first section of this Chapter indicates that a nation’s inflation performance is directly related to the autonomy of its central bank. Thus, one direction of potential monetary reform would be to increase Federal Reserve autonomy. Another type of cost of contemporary monetary policy arrangements is the cost associated with contradictory objectives for monetary policy. The second section of this Chapter deals with contradictory policy assignments. It suggests that the simplification of goals for monetary policy is another bearing that monetary reform might take. In recent years there has been increasing interest in Congress’ restricting the Federal Reserve to a single goal, price stability. The third section of the Chapter examines the idea that today’s monetary policy arrangements exist primarily to enable the Federal Reserve to create monetary surprises. Therefore, socially costly uncertainty and misdirection are essential elements of monetary policy. This suggests that the immediate disclosure of the goals and targets of monetary policy is another direction for monetary policy reform. The next two sections of the Chapter review the findings reported in earlier chapters regarding political attempts to influence monetary policy and the ability of the Federal Reserve to resist these efforts. The final section of the Chapter puts all of the insights provided by earlier sections together and adduces a number of options for practicable and complementary monetary reform.

Keywords

Monetary Policy Public Choice Federal Reserve Monetary Authority Central Bank Independence 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Alesina, Alberto. “Macroeconomics and Politics.” NBER Macroeconmic Annual 1988, ( Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1988 ).Google Scholar
  2. Auerbach, Robert D. “Goal Displacement in the Theory of Government Behavior with Examples from the Federal Reserve.” Manuscript/ 1990.Google Scholar
  3. Bade, Robin, and Parkin, Michael. “Central Bank Laws and Monetary Policy.” Manuscript, (June 1987).Google Scholar
  4. Banian, King, Laney, Leroy, and Willett, Thomas. “Central Bank Independence: An International Comparison.” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, 13 (March 1983), 199–217.Google Scholar
  5. Burdekin, Richard, and Wahar, Mark E. “Monetary Institutions, Budget Deficits and Inflation.” European Journal of Political Economy 6 (1990), 531–551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Burdekin, Richard, and Wahar, Mark E., and Thomas Willett. “Central Bank Reform: The Federal Reserve in International Perspective.” Public Budgeting and Financing Management (1991).Google Scholar
  7. Burns, Arthur. “Statement to Congress.” Federal Reserve Bulletin 63 (3) (March 1977), 238–246.Google Scholar
  8. Cagan, Phillip. “The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation.” In Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, Milton Friedman (ed.), ( Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956 ).Google Scholar
  9. Calmfors, Lars. “The Roles of Stabilization Policy and Wage Setting for Macroeconomic Stability: The Experience of Economies with Centralized Bargaining.” Kyklos 38 (1985), 329–347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Cameron, David. “Social Democracy, Corporatism, Labor Quiescence and the Representation of Economic Interest in Advanced Capitalist Society.” In J. Goldthorpe (ed.), Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism ( New York: Oxford University Press, 1984 ).Google Scholar
  11. Chappell, Henry, Thomas Havrilesky and Rob McGregor, “Partisan Monetary Policies: Presidential Impact Through the Power of Appointment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics (forthcoming 1993 ).Google Scholar
  12. Cukierman, Alex. Central Bank Strategy, Credibility and Independence: Theory and Evidence ( Cambridge: MIT Press, 1992 ).Google Scholar
  13. Dawes, R. M., and R. H. Thaler. “Anomalies: Cooperation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2 (Summer 1988 ), 187–197.Google Scholar
  14. Epstein, Gerald, and Juliet Schorr. The Political Economy of Central Banking. Discussion Paper No. 1281, Harvard Institute of Economic Research (July 1986).Google Scholar
  15. Federal Reserve. “Monetary Policy Objectives.” (Press Release, July 13, 1988 ).Google Scholar
  16. Greider, William. Secrets of the Temple. (Simon and Schuster, 1987 ).Google Scholar
  17. Grier, Kevin T. “Congressional Influence on U.S. Monetary Policy: An Empirical Test,” Journal of Monetary Economics 28 (2) (October 1991), 201–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Harrison, William B. “Federal Reserve District Directors: Support System for a Public Institution.” Journal of Economics and Business 43 (1991): 271–282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Havrilesky, Thomas. “A New Program for More Monetary Stability.” Journal of Political Economy 80 (January-February 1972a), 171175.Google Scholar
  20. Havrilesky, Thomas. “Finding the Optimal Monetary Strategy with Information Constraints,” Journal of Finance (December 1972b).Google Scholar
  21. Havrilesky, Thomas. “The Optimal Monetary Policy Instrument.” Southern Economic Journal 43 (January 1977), 1288–1297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Havrilesky, Thomas. “A Partisanship Theory of Fiscal and Monetary Policy.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 19 (August 1987), 308–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Havrilesky, Thomas. “Electoral Cycles in Economic Policy.” Challenge 31 (July/August 1988), 14–21.Google Scholar
  24. Havrilesky, Thomas. “A Public Choice Theory of the Cycle in Monetary Policy.” Cato Journal 9 (Winter 1990), 709–718Google Scholar
  25. Havrilesky, Thomas. “The Causes and Consequences of Big Bank PAC Contributions.” Journal of Financial Services Research 4 (December 1990), 243–249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Havrilesky, Thomas. “The Chairman as Hero: Our Defense against Monetary Excess.” Cato Journal 11 (Fall 1991), 65–72.Google Scholar
  27. Havrilesky, Thomas., and Gildea, John. “Reliable and Unreliable Partisan Appointees to the Board of Governors.” Public Choice 73 (May 1992), 397–417CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Havrilesky, Thomas., and James Granato. “Determinants of Inflationary Performance: Corporatist Structures vs. Central Bank Autonomy,” Public Choice (December 1992).Google Scholar
  29. Havrilesky, Thomas., and Robert Schweitzer. “A Theory of FOMC Dissent Voting with Evidence from the Time Series.” In Thomas Mayer (ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy ( New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990 ).Google Scholar
  30. Hetzel, Robert L. “The Political Economy of Monetary Policy.” In Thomas Mayer (ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy ( New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990 ).Google Scholar
  31. Janis, Irving. Group Think. ( Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1983 ).Google Scholar
  32. Kane, Edward. “External Pressure and the Operation of the Fed.” In Raymond E. Lombra and Willard E. Witte (eds.), Political Economy of International and Domestic Monetary Relations ( Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1982 ).Google Scholar
  33. Kane, Edward. “Bureaucratic Self-Interest as an Obstacle to Monetary Reform.” In Thomas Mayer (ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy ( New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990 ).Google Scholar
  34. Mayer, Thomas. “Miminizing Regret: Cognitive Dissonance as an Explanation of FOMC Behavior.” In Thomas Mayer (ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy ( New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990 ).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Murray, Alan. “The New Fed, Democracy Comes to the Central Bank.” Wall Street Journal April 5, 1991, 169–190.Google Scholar
  36. Nordhaus, William. “The Political Business Cycle.” Review of Economic Studies 42 (April 1975).Google Scholar
  37. Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido. Macroeconomic Policy Credibility and Politics. (Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publishers, 1990 ).Google Scholar
  38. Poole, William. “Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instruments in a Simple Stochastic Macro Model,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (2) (May 1970), 197–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Rose, R. “How Exceptional Is America?” Political Science Quarterly 104 (1989), 91–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Sargent, T., and N. Wallace. “Rational Expectations and the Dynamics of Hyperinflation.” International Economic Review 14 (June 1973), 328–350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Schmitter, P. “Interest Intermediaries and Regime Governability in Contemporary Western Europe and North America.” In S. Berger (ed.), Organizing Interests in Western Europe. ( New York: Cambridge University Press, 1981 ).Google Scholar
  42. Taylor, J. B. “Union Wage Settlements During a Disinflation.” American Economic Review 73 (5) (December 1983), 981–993.Google Scholar
  43. Timberlake, Richard. “Institutional Evolution of Federal Reserve Hegemony.” Cato Journal 5 (Winter 1986 ).Google Scholar
  44. Woolley, J. Monetary Politics: The Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy. ( New York: Cambridge University Press, 1984 ).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Yeager, L. Experience with Stopping Inflation. ( Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1981 ).Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 1993

Authors and Affiliations

  • Thomas Havrilesky
    • 1
  1. 1.Duke UniversityDurhamUSA

Personalised recommendations