Skip to main content

Banks and Transition a Theoretical Framework

  • Chapter
Institutions in Transition
  • 210 Accesses

Abstract

Three areas of inquiry relate to the transformation of the financial system in Vietnam. The first is the study object per se: a financial system. The second is the transition from a centrally planned system to a market economy, the process in which the financial system receives a new function. The third area is Vietnam itself: the historic and institutional context of the current transformation of the banking system. The common denominator for the approach to these areas is the institutional perspective. Hence, the first section of this chapter introduces this perspective. Section two deals with the main features of finance in a market economy. The final two sections of the chapter deal with the central planning problem and the transition process. The rest of the book deals with the third topic: Vietnam and its banking system.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Commons (1934) argues that transactions should be the basic unit of analysis. Coase (1937) put forth the idea that institutions are a response to transaction costs and lays the foundation of transaction costs analysis in his works of 1937, 1946 and 1960 (see Coase (1988). Williamson (1975). Chapter 1, launches the concept of new institutionalism. Milgrom & Roberts (1992) is a broad overview of issues relating to transaction costs economcs. An issue of the Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (1993), especially Williamson (1993), is a valuable introduction to the new institutionalism and its various sub-fields.

    Google Scholar 

  2. North (1990a), (1990b), (1991), (1993).

    Google Scholar 

  3. North(1990a),p.6.

    Google Scholar 

  4. North(1993),p.36.

    Google Scholar 

  5. North(1990),p.84.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Putnam(1993),p. 179.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Milgrom & Roberts (1992) make the distinction throughout their analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Akerlof (1970) is the classic reference. In the “market for lemons” (i.e. used cars), only used cars of poor quality will be traded.

    Google Scholar 

  9. The classical example of moral hazard is that of insurance. If you are insured, you are less careful, and the risk is higher that your insured goods will be stolen. But if your insurance include self risk you are motivated to take better care. See Holmström (1979).

    Google Scholar 

  10. The maintenance of the prison is costly to the state, and to the prisoner there are costs in terms of losing your personal freedom, and losing your alternative income.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Kornai(1992).

    Google Scholar 

  12. Nove (1986) points out that information, motivation and means together rule action; p. 33.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Mayer & Vives (1993).

    Google Scholar 

  14. The focus in this study is on financial organizations as intermediaries for financial resources. Channelling financial resources through a banking system is, however, only one way to achieve intermediation. Other forms of debt financing are various types of direct lending (such as company securities). In addition, equity may finance the operations of firms.

    Google Scholar 

  15. The institutional perspective distinguishes between institutions, i.e. the rules regulating a certain activity, and organizations, i.e. the physical, organizational reflection of these rules. In the finance literature (and sometimes in other organizational contexts as well), banks and other financial organizations are often referred to as “financial institutions”. The terminology becomes further confusing as the recent developments of financial intermediation theory stress a functional focus (i.e. the functions that banks and other intermediators perform) rather than a focus on the institutional structure (i.e. the kind of organizations which perform these functions, which vary from country to country due to historical reasons). In reality, the former approach is more “institutional” than the latter, as it traces the transaction costs arising in financial exchange, and the resultant institutional responses. In this study, “institutions” are referred to only as rules for interaction: the banking institution is thus the specific pattern of intermediating resources, conducting payments, and handling risk, and not necessarily a bank organization.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See Bhattacharya & Thakor (1993) for a survey of modern banking theory, where this and other central problems in connection with financial intermediation are discussed.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Diamond & Dyvig (1983).

    Google Scholar 

  18. Diamond (1984), and Boyd & Prescott (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  19. Stiglitz and Weiss (1981).

    Google Scholar 

  20. With completely collateralized lending, the function of finance as promotor of productive investments also disappears, however. We would not get what Schumpeter (1934) refers to as “abnormal” credit: credit given against future gains. This is credit not given against a tangible collateral, but rather against the banker’s confidence in the entrepreneur’s ability to transform the credit into production.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Durski (1993) gives a good overview of various forms of Western bank regulation. Bhattacharya & Thakor (1993) provides more of the fundamental, theoretical aspects of regulation.

    Google Scholar 

  22. See Herring & Santomero (1991) pp. 25-30 on the risk of bank runs and the saftey net of the financial system to prevent these runs.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Greenwald & Stiglitz (1991).

    Google Scholar 

  24. Merton (1977).

    Google Scholar 

  25. See further Daltung (1994) [Chapter IV]; see also and Milgrom & Roberts (1992), pp. 170-176 on the collapse of the Savings & Loans associations in the US, which gives ample evidence of these mechanisms.

    Google Scholar 

  26. The Swedish banking crisis in the early 1990s, following fairly abrupt deregulation, is probably a good example of this.

    Google Scholar 

  27. For these aspects of government intervention in banking, see, for example, World Bank (1989), Stiglitz (1991), and Greenwald & Stiglitz (1991).

    Google Scholar 

  28. Hellwig(1991).

    Google Scholar 

  29. Gurley & Shaw (1960), Goldsmith (1969).

    Google Scholar 

  30. King & Levine (1993 a) and (1993b) argue that finance does affect economic growth.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Floro & Yotopoulos (1991) describe this as the traditional approach to capital markets in less developed countries.

    Google Scholar 

  32. King & Levine (1994) labels the focus on capital accumulation “capital fundamentalism”.

    Google Scholar 

  33. See Gersovitz (1988) and Deaton (1989). 34Gonzalez-Vega (1983) and Adams (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  34. According to Braverman & Guasch (1986), on average, only five percent of farmers in low income countries receive 80 percent of credits distributed through low interest rate credit programs.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Although the relationship between interest rates and savings potential is not so clear cut as one might imagine; see Gonzales Arrieta (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  36. McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973) made central contributions to this theory. See Fry (1988) for an extensive overview of the financial liberalization schoool and its opponents: the neo-structuralists. Fry’s support of the financial liberalization thesis is somewhat exaggerated, in my view, considering the fairly ambiguos empirical evidence of the relationship between financial conditions and growth he presents (Román, 1991).

    Google Scholar 

  37. Morisset (1993) shows that the character of financial liberalization is important. Liberalized interest rates by themselves do not guarantee economic growth. See also Park (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  38. The effects of financial liberalization in Latin America has indeed been very discouraging; see Diaz-Alejandro (1985) and Dornbusch & Reynoso (1989).

    Google Scholar 

  39. McKinnon (1991).

    Google Scholar 

  40. Floro & Yotopoulos (1991), p. 15.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Market fragmentation is a main theme in McKinnon (1973). See also Floro & Yotopoulos (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  42. A so-called ROSCA (Rotating Savings and Credit Association) is a club where members make regular contributions (daily, weekly, or perhaps monthly). One member receives the total sum of contributions at each installment. The order of distribution is decided by a lottery. See Callier (1990) and Besley, Coate & Loury (1993) and (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  43. Ghate (1988). See also Ahmed (1989) who shows that transaction costs for small informal loans are lower than for formal credit.

    Google Scholar 

  44. See Edwards (1988) for the relationship between formal and informal finance in the Korean case. Kapur (1992) discusses the specific features of formal and informal finance in general.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Kornai(1992),p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  46. For comprehensive descriptions of the principles and the functions of socialist systems, see Nove (1986), and Kornai (1992); I use both extensively in this section. For more condensed overviews of different socialist countries, see Jeffries (1990), and also Vygodsky (1981).

    Google Scholar 

  47. Kornai (1992), p. 475.

    Google Scholar 

  48. See Komai (1992), Chapter 4, and Nove (1986), p. 325 on ideology, and also Brus & Laski (1989) on this interpretation of Marxism.

    Google Scholar 

  49. The bureaucracy, according to Kornai (1992), includes the totality of the party apparatus, the state administration and other administrative bodies (p. 41).

    Google Scholar 

  50. Kornai (1992), Chapter 3. The party structure is a hierarchy beginning at the bottom in party cells or branches, for specific districts or production units. A number of branches are headed by a district party committee, in turn directed by a province party committee etc. At the top is the central committee, electing the executive body of a political committee. The central leadership has a staff of officials whose activities often parallel those of the state administration in the various ministries. Nove (1986) stresses the dominance of the party over the state apparatus, but also its highly intertwined nature (p. 6).

    Google Scholar 

  51. The privacy, or at least semi-privacy, of signifcant shares of agricultural plots in the USSR should, however, be noted, as discussed by Nove (1986), p. 116 ff. See also Kornai (1990a) and Los (1990) on the private sector and the second economy in Marxist states.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Nove(1986),p.20.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Nuti(1992),p.49.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Wilczynski (1982), p. 43. See also Nove (1986), p. 235, Kornai (1992), p. 131, and Peebles (1991), p. 20, on abolishment of money in early marxism-leninism.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Lenin (1927) recognized the usefulness of a banking system: “Capitalism has created an accounting apparatus in the shape of the banks, syndicates, postal service, consumers’ societies, and office employees’ unions. Without big banks socialism would be impossible... A single State Bank, the biggest of the big, with branches in every rural district, in every factory, will constitute as much as nine-tenths of the socialist apparatus. This will be country-wide book-keeping, country-wide accounting of the production and distribution of goods, this will be so to speak, something in the nature of the skeleton of socialist society.”

    Google Scholar 

  56. For overviews of the socialist financial system see Grossman (1968), Peebles (1991), Kornai (1992), Chapter 8, and Montias (1994), pp. 10-15.

    Google Scholar 

  57. See Kornai (1992), Chapter 8 on the role of planned prices, and Nove (1986), in particular Chapter 7, on prices in theory and practice.

    Google Scholar 

  58. Kornai (1992), p. 232. See also Peebles (1991), pp. 26-27 on savings.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Komai(1992),p. 134.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Grossman (1968), pp. 9-10. 62Peebles(1991),p.29.

    Google Scholar 

  61. The causes behind the imbalances have evoked a heated debate between two schools of thought: the “disquilibrium school” and the “shortage school”. The former, with its prime proponent being Robert Portes, advocates that imbalances are largely a temporary problems due to sticky prices. The main advocate of the shortage school is János Kornai, who argues that shortages are due to systemic micro-related deficiencies in the socialist system, with origins both in the planning problem and in ideology. See van Brabant (1990) for an overview. The following discussion is largely inspired by Kornai, because of his explicit and thorough consideration of the institutional framework which determines the constraints for individual action in the socialist system. See however Ellman (1994) p. 11 on a recent critique against the soft budget constraint as an explanation behind shortages.

    Google Scholar 

  62. Milgrom & Roberts (1992), Chapter 4.

    Google Scholar 

  63. See Kornai (1992), Chapter 7, and Nove (1986), Chapter 2 on the planning process.

    Google Scholar 

  64. Kornai (1992), pp. 150-151.

    Google Scholar 

  65. See Nove (1986), p. 87 ff on the success indicator problem.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Nove (1986), p. 39.

    Google Scholar 

  67. See Nove (1986), Chapter 3. Van Brabant (1990) discusses the flawed idea about planners as omnipotent decision makers with all the control in their hands.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Kornai(1992), p.98.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Kornai (1992), p. 148.

    Google Scholar 

  70. Grossman (1968), p.4.

    Google Scholar 

  71. Grossman (1989), p.39.

    Google Scholar 

  72. This volunteerism could, however, also be regarded from the individual’s longer term perspective, i.e. that he realizes that his contribution to maintaining basic structures in society will benefit him and his family in the longer run.

    Google Scholar 

  73. Kornai (1992) claims that the official ideology of classical socialism makes no promise of equality of incomes; the relatively smaller income differentials are more due to the lack of alternatives for people in higher positions (and thus there is little competition for good managers etc), plus the existence of compensating, non-pencuniary incentives (pp. 324 ff).

    Google Scholar 

  74. Kornai (1992) p. 52 discusses how classical socialism ends when the unqualified faith in the system’s superiority is shaken.

    Google Scholar 

  75. Also discussed by Kornai (1992), p. 65.

    Google Scholar 

  76. Holmström & Milgrom (1991). If the reward was instead related to the asset’s future returns, this would probably make the manager more interested in maintaining the asset. Such an incentive scheme requires accurate and the unbiased measurement of future returns, involving measurement costs, and these could be saved by replacing such a management contract with private ownership.

    Google Scholar 

  77. Nove (1986), pp. 159-165 on problems of innovation. See also Grossman & Hart (1986, and Hart & Moore (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  78. Hayek (1945) claims that the central economic problem is adaption to change which the market system can best handle. Oliver Williamson (1991) discusses this and Barnard’s (1938) opposite position, which is that it is precisely internal organization that manages to adapt to changing circumstances. Williamson, naturally, claims that both are right. For some types of change, the price system is the sufficient statistics to which autonomous enterprises or individuals respond; other kinds of change require coordinated adaption which is best achieved in an hierarchic organization (pp. 277-279).

    Google Scholar 

  79. kornai (1992), p. 162, discusses the system-specific features of risk-taking which create persistent investment hunger, with the absence of individual responsibility, and the possibility of additional funding because of soft budget constraint mechanisms.

    Google Scholar 

  80. See Kornai (1986) for a definition and discussion of the concept.

    Google Scholar 

  81. Kornai(1986),pp.5-6.

    Google Scholar 

  82. Such considerations are typical in the world of Western banking, where a significant amount of loan contracts are renegotiated.

    Google Scholar 

  83. For alternative views on the soft budget constraint, see Ellman (1994) who refers to Gomulka (1994): “The main factors generating shortages now appear to be state control of international and domestic trade, state price control, and macroeconomics disequilibrium”...“The soft budget constraint now appears to be a concept more relevant to help explain inflation than shortages” (p. 11).

    Google Scholar 

  84. Kornai (1992), p. 133.

    Google Scholar 

  85. Kornai (1986), p.9.

    Google Scholar 

  86. See Schmieding (1993), pp. 216-219, and Ellman (1994) for overviews of the transition processes so far.

    Google Scholar 

  87. See Sachs & Wing Thye Woo (1994), and Wing Thye Woo (1994) for discussions on China in comparison to Russia and Poland.

    Google Scholar 

  88. Ellman (1994) quotes Brus (1993): “contrary to the conventional wisdom”...“mono-archy [i.e. communist dictatorship] may play a positive role in this process” (p. 18).

    Google Scholar 

  89. Von Mises (1935 [1920]), in Hayek (1935), referred to by Schumpeter (1987 [1943]), p. 172. Van Brabant (1990), p. 157 refers to the Barone-Lange-von Mises debate.

    Google Scholar 

  90. Hayek (1945) is the classic. See also Hayek (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  91. Schumpeter (1987 [1943]), p. 188. On the other hand, in Schumpeter’s analysis of capitalism, economic organizations become increasingly large-scale and monopolistic; thus there was no reason why not a central authority could not replace such commercial organizations, and be more beneficial to society (p. 189).

    Google Scholar 

  92. See Heilbroner’s (1992) self-critical reflections on the world after communism.

    Google Scholar 

  93. For example, capitalist collapse would come either because of decreasing profit quotas, according to Marx, or because of its overefficiency and eventual satiation of markets, according to Schumpeter. See Nove (1985[1983]), Chapter 1, and Nove (1986), Chapter 4 on Marx and the socialist system. See also Vygodsky (1981) for a pro-marxist account which indirectly supports the notion that Marx had little to say about socialism (p. 247).

    Google Scholar 

  94. A country like Sweden, with a huge public sector and an important welfare system, has been referred to as a socialist country, despite the fact that the lion’s share of the means of production is privately owned.

    Google Scholar 

  95. See Grossman (1968), and Brus & Laski (1989) for the long history of socialist reforms. 98Fforde & Paine (1987). 99 Bardhan & Roemer (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  96. Kornai (1990b), p.58.

    Google Scholar 

  97. Nuti (1992), p. 22.

    Google Scholar 

  98. Bardhan & Roemer (1992), p. 101.

    Google Scholar 

  99. Bardhan & Roemer (1992), p. 103.

    Google Scholar 

  100. See Komai (1992), p. 387 for a discussion of different aspects of transformation, revolution, reform etc.

    Google Scholar 

  101. Blanchard et al (1991) p. xxi. There is a substantial literature of varying quality on the transition processes. Good introductions to the main issues at stake are provided by Blanchard et. al. (1991), Clague & Rausser (1992), Aslund (1992c), Åslund (1994), and Ellman (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  102. Kornai (1992), Chapter 16.

    Google Scholar 

  103. But while doi moi (“new road” or “renovation”) is the Vietnamese equivalent of the Russian perestroika (restructuring), there is no similarly well known phrase in Vietnamese for glasnost (openness).

    Google Scholar 

  104. Olson (1992) argues for the importance of establishing individual rights (and responsibilities) in order to succeed with reform.

    Google Scholar 

  105. There is another way to view the motives behind the reduced subsidies from the state after privatization: if the state wants to ensure a high — but inefficient production — it has to compensate the enterprise by a subsidy. With privatization, the state can no longer order the enterprise to produce a high output. The private enterprise has stronger bargaining power: the compensating subsidy must at least be equal to the profits that a more efficient (and lower) output would yield. In this case, it is not the general interest in enhancing efficiency in the economy which is important to the bureaucracy, but rather the need to reduce costly subsidies; see further Boycko et.al. (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  106. Calvo & Frenkel (1991b).

    Google Scholar 

  107. Aoki & Kim (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  108. The financial sector as a bottleneck in the transition is frequently stressed; see for example Ellman (1994), and Kornai (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  109. Bonin, Long & Noel (1995), p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  110. See, for example, Prindl (1992), Gowland (1992), Roe (1992), Lampe (1992), a special issue of the Journal of Banking and Finance (1993), Bonin & Székely (1994), Griffith-Jones & Drabek (1995), Bonin, Long & Noël (1995), Long & Rutkowska (1995), and Aoki & Kim (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  111. Williamson(1991).

    Google Scholar 

  112. See Blanchard et. al. (1991) on price stabilization.

    Google Scholar 

  113. McKinnon (1991),pp. 121-122.

    Google Scholar 

  114. See Hansson (1992) for reasons behind hyperinflation in transforming countries.

    Google Scholar 

  115. Blanchard et.al. (1991), Chapter 1.

    Google Scholar 

  116. Stiglitz (1992),p. 183.

    Google Scholar 

  117. McKinnon (1992), p. 123.

    Google Scholar 

  118. See Siklos (1994) for a discussion.

    Google Scholar 

  119. Poenish (1992), p. 41. Such transparancy may be difficult to obtain since socialist banking — even more than banking in market economies — are renowned for extreme secrecy. At the same time it is vital to change the public’s impression of banks as organizations which by obscure methods protect the state industry and the established but deficient structure of society.

    Google Scholar 

  120. Siklos(1994).

    Google Scholar 

  121. Poenisch (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  122. Durski (1993), pp. 15-16.

    Google Scholar 

  123. Fischer & Gelb (1991).

    Google Scholar 

  124. But, the literature points out, there are social costs of bankruptcy, especially considering the current state of the transition economies. In particular there are risks that viable enterprises may be forced into bankruptcy because of chain reactions, and the unclear definitions of property rights may also incur further costs (Aoki, 1995, p. 26).

    Google Scholar 

  125. There might, however, be reasons why banking should face somewhat heavier restrictions than other industries as far as competition is concerned, as argued in Chapter II; competition may force banks to squeeze margins, and thus banks may take on too large risks. This may cause losses to society both in terms of financial expenditures (compensating depositors), and in terms of deteriorating confidence in the banks.

    Google Scholar 

  126. Although there has been general agreement of the importance of the bad debt problem (see, for example, Griffith-Jones & FitzGerald, 1995), there seems to emerge a doubt as to whether the problem is as severe as believed (see Berglöf, 1995, p. 86, referring to Dittus, 1994). Although burdening many banks in many countries, some (in the Czech Republic, for example) have managed to (partly) resolve the problem, while in other countries high rates of inflation have reduced the value of financial claims.

    Google Scholar 

  127. Calvo & Frenkel (1991b).

    Google Scholar 

  128. Mates (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  129. Roland(1995).

    Google Scholar 

  130. Montias (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  131. See Åslund (1992c), Chapter 2, for an introduction.

    Google Scholar 

  132. Blanchard et.al (1991), p. xi.

    Google Scholar 

  133. Dewatripont & Roland (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  134. McKinnon (1991), p. 162.

    Google Scholar 

  135. Åslund (1992c), p. 39. Åslund has been a clear proponent of swift reform.

    Google Scholar 

  136. See Fischer & Frenkel (1992), who argues for shock treatment in Russia, but accepts more gradual meas ures in, for example, China (p. 38).

    Google Scholar 

  137. Svejnar (1991).

    Google Scholar 

  138. This insight is gaining recognition as the experiences of reform accumulate; see, for example, Ellman (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  139. Here I follow Schmieding (1993) in the division of these three types of approaches.

    Google Scholar 

  140. Perhaps a reason why real wages may increase too much, i.e. overshoot as described above: since workers experience a real wage reduction at first, they will — perhaps — be overcompensated by a substantial wage increase.

    Google Scholar 

  141. Poenish (1992), pp. 42-44.

    Google Scholar 

  142. Litwack (1991), p.78.

    Google Scholar 

  143. Schmieding (1993), p. 236.

    Google Scholar 

  144. North (1990), p. 140.

    Google Scholar 

  145. Murrell (1992), p.92.

    Google Scholar 

  146. As also argued by Montias (1994). 151Schmieding (1993), p 235.

    Google Scholar 

  147. Montias (1994), p. 10.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1999 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Román, L. (1999). Banks and Transition a Theoretical Framework. In: Institutions in Transition. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4615-4981-9_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4615-4981-9_2

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4613-7261-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4615-4981-9

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics