Skip to main content

Demand Theory: Constraints and Optimization

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Microeconomic Theory and Computation

Abstract

This chapter introduces the budget constraint and combines the budget constraint with the preferences developed in the preceding chapter to provide a model of rational consumer choice.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    A minimal set of commands follows: [px1,py1,m1]:[100,24,2400]$ first:gr2d(explicit(BL(x,m0,px0,py0),x,0,m0/px0))$ second:explicit(BL(x,m1,px1,py1),x,0,m1/px1))$ wxdraw(first,second,columns=2)$.

  2. 2.

    The declare and assume commands allow us to avoid a dialog with Maxima.

  3. 3.

    The complete ICC consists of a segment of the vertical axis from 0 to 4.1667 and the horizontal line in the graph.

  4. 4.

    We assert this for now. We demonstrate the result below.

  5. 5.

    And in a section that follows, where Lagrangian multipliers are employed.

  6. 6.

    Over this range, its income elasticity of demand is 1.0. Why?

  7. 7.

    At least one good must be a normal good. Why?

  8. 8.

    Maxima does not offer distinct notation for simple derivatives and partial derivatives. From an operational viewpoint the two do not differ. The analyst must be aware of the context.

  9. 9.

    We consider only functions with a single local maximum or minimum value. Such functions have a global maximum or minimum value, which corresponds to the local value. Some functions can have multiple local maximum and minimum values and may or may not have a global maximum or minimum value. As an exercise, plot g(x) = sin(x) ⋅ x over a range of at least − 2 ⋅ π to 2 ⋅ π. This function has many local maximum and minimum values but no global maximum or minimum value.

  10. 10.

    Notation: \(\frac{\partial u} {\partial x} \equiv u_{x}\). Likewise for y and z.

  11. 11.

    The x axis is labeled. The y and z labels can be inferred.

  12. 12.

    Be aware that the matrix command is being used in two different ways. The outermost command is used to build a table. The interior commands are used analytically.

References

  1. Baldani J, Bradfield J, Turner RW (1996) Mathematical economics. Dryden, Fort Worth

    Google Scholar 

  2. Doi J, Iwasa K, Shimomura K (2009) Giffen behavior independent of the wealth level. Econ Theory 41:247–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Nicholson W, Snyder C (2008) Microeconomic theory: basic principles and extensions, 11th edn. South-Western, Mason

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hammock, M.R., Mixon, J.W. (2013). Demand Theory: Constraints and Optimization. In: Microeconomic Theory and Computation. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-9417-1_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics