Skip to main content

The Global Joint Distribution of Income and Health

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Recent Advances in Estimating Nonlinear Models

Abstract

We investigate the evolution of global welfare in two dimensions: income per capita and life expectancy. First, we estimate the marginal distributions of income and life expectancy separately. More importantly, we consider income and life expectancy jointly and estimate their joint global distribution for 137 countries during 1970–2000. We reach several conclusions: the global joint distribution has evolved from a bimodal into a unimodal one, the evolution of the health distribution has preceded that of income, global inequality and poverty has decreased over time and the evolution of the global distribution has been welfare improving. Our decomposition of overall welfare indicates that global inequality would be underestimated if within-country inequality is not taken into account. Moreover, global inequality and poverty would be substantially underestimated if the dependence between income and health distributions is ignored.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The two most popular concepts are β-convergence according to which countries that begin at a lower level of income per capita grow at faster rates and σ-convergence according to which the dispersion of country growth rates decreases over time. For a discussion see, for example, Maasoumi et al. (2007) and references therein.

  2. 2.

    Milanovic (2005) discusses the issues and controversies surrounding the definition of the term global inequality.

  3. 3.

    The HDI is an equally weighted average measure of three indicators of achievement: per capita income, life expectancy, and educational attainment (itself a weighted average of the rates of literacy and school enrollment). The HPI is also an equally weighted average measure of three indicators of deprivation: probability of survival to age 40, adult illiteracy, and lack of a decent standard of living (itself an equally weighted average of the proportion of the population without access to improved water source and the proportion of under weight children).

  4. 4.

    For example, suppose there exists a simple economy with two individuals A and B, each endowed with two attributes X and Y. Consider the following two scenarios: (1) \(\left (X_{A} = 2,Y _{A} = 2\right )\) and \(\left (X_{B} = 0,Y _{B} = 0\right )\) and (2) \(\left (X_{A} = 2,Y _{A} = 0\right )\) and \(\left (X_{B} = 0,Y _{B} = 2\right )\). Since the marginal distributions of X and Y are identical for these two scenarios, any “hybrid” index that fails to account for the dependence between the marginal distributions will conclude that the two share the same level of welfare.

  5. 5.

    For a comprehensive discussion of the forces that have shaped changes in mortality and life expectancy during the post-WWII period, see Cutler et al. (2006).

  6. 6.

    The results reported in the next section remain virtually the same when we exclude these countries.

  7. 7.

    Bourguignon and Morrisson (2002) provide data on income distribution for almost two centuries, the last three years being 1970, 1980, and 1992. We used their 1992 income data to represent 1990 in our data set (see also the next footnote). They provided data for few individual countries but in most cases for geographic groups of countries (see their study for group definitions). Our study is based on country-level data. Therefore when individual-country interval data were unavailable we used the corresponding geographic-group data.

  8. 8.

    Income interval data from the WDI are available only for selected years. When referring to data for 2000, we chose the year closest to 2000 with available data (in most cases the late 1990s). This practice is widely adopted in the literature as a practical matter because distribution data are sparse. Many researchers acknowledge that it would not affect results much because income share data do not show wide fluctuations from year to year.

  9. 9.

    For some mainly small countries in our smaple (37 out of the 137), the WDI does not provide share data; we assumed that the distribution of income did not change between 1990 and 2000. These countries account for only 5% of global population in 2000. The results reported in the next section remain virtually the same when we exclude this group from our analysis.

  10. 10.

    To see this, consider again the simple example given in footnote 5. If the data are in the format of \(\left (X_{A} = 2,Y _{A} = 2\right )\) and \(\left (X_{B} = 0,Y _{B} = 0\right )\), then both marginal distributions (of X and Y ) and their joint distribution are identified. In contrast, if the data are reported in the format X = (2, 0) and Y = (2, 0), then only the marginal distributions of X and Y are identified, but not their joint distribution. Our data on income and health for each country are of the second format.

  11. 11.

    Wu and Perloff (2005) use the maximum entropy density approach to estimate China’s income distributions from interval summary statistics.

  12. 12.

    Wu (2003) provides details and additional references. Most of the commonly used mathematical distributions can be characterized or closely approximated by a maxent density. For example, if the first two moments of a distribution are known, maximizing the entropy subject to these two moments yields a normal probability density function.

  13. 13.

    See the monograph by Nelsen (1998) for a general treatment of copulas.

  14. 14.

    In our discussion estimated densities, we use the term “mode” generally such that it refers to both global and local maxima of densities.

  15. 15.

    Bourguignon and Morrisson (2002) plot the estimated density only for 1950 and 1992 and work with relative income (per capita income relative to that of the richest country for each year). Nonetheless, a bimodality is present for 1950 in their graphical analysis as well as a rightward shift of the distribution between 1950 and 1992. A similar “Twin Peaks” phenomenon is reported in Quah (1996).

  16. 16.

    In this issue, see the debate through the pages of The Economist of July 18 2002, March 11 2004, and April 7 2004.

  17. 17.

    Results using the Chen/Ravallion poverty line and other reasonable poverty lines are qualitatively similar in terms of their evolution over time. These additional results are available from the authors upon request.

  18. 18.

    Deaton (2006), Soares (2005), and World Bank (2006) discuss the shape of this curve.  With per capita income plotted along the horizontal and life expectancy along the vertical axes, at low levels of income the curve is steeply upward sloping and tapers off at higher levels of income.

  19. 19.

    The bivariate Gini index used in our calculation, which places equal weights to income and health, is defined in the Appendix. As was discussed in Section 12.1, most commonly used inequality and poverty indices for a single attribute are not uniquely defined in a multidimensional framework. This underlines the importance of joint distribution estimation, which facilitates any welfare inference of interest.

  20. 20.

    Any reasonably defined poverty index resides within the range between the lower and upper bound. Atkinson (1987) discusses the relationship between the bounds of poverty measures and multidimensional stochastic dominance.

References

  • Atkinson, Anthony, B., 1987, “On the Measurement of Poverty,” Econometrica, 55, 749–764.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, Gary S., Tomas J. Philipson and Rodrigo R. Soares, 2005, “The Quantity and Quality of Life and the Evolution of World Inequality,” American Economic Review, 95, 277–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, Albert and John Serieux, 2006, “Riding the Elephants: The Evolution of World Economic Growth and Income Distribution at the End of the Twentieth Century (1980–2000),” U.N. Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Working Paper No. 27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhalla, Surjit, 2002, Imagine There is No Country, Washington DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, François and Christian Morrisson, 2002, “Inequality Among World Citizens: 1820–1992,” American Economic Review, 92, 727–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Shaohua and Martin Ravallion, 2001, “How Did the World’s Poor Fare in the 1990s?” Review of Income and Wealth, 47, 283–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Shaohua and Martin Ravallion, 2004, “How Have the World’s Poorest Fared since the Early 1980s?” World Bank Research Observer, 19, 141–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, David, Angus Deaton and Adriana Lleras-Muney, 2006, “The Determinants of Mortality,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 97–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, Angus, 2005, “Measuring Poverty in a Growing World (or Measuring Growth in a Poor World),” Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, Angus, 2006, “Global Patterns of Income and Health: Facts, Interpretations, and Policies,” NBER Working Paper No. 12735.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, James, Joel Greer, and Erik Thorbecke, 1984, “A Class of Decomposable Poverty Measures,” Econometrica, 52, 761–766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gakidou, E.E., C.J.L. Murray and J. Frenk, 2000, “Defining and Measuring Health Inequality: An Approach Based on the Distribution of Health Inequality,” Bulletin of the World Health Organization, 78, 42–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goesling, Brian and Glenn Firebaugh, 2004, “The Trend in International Health Inequality,” Population and Development Review, 30, 131–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaynes, Edwin T., 1957 “Information Theory and Statistical Mechanics.” Physics Review, 106, 620–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maasoumi, Esfandiar, 1986, “The Measurement and Decomposition of Multidimensional Inequality,” Econometrica, 54, 991–997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maasoumi, Esfandiar, 1999, “Multidimensional Approaches to Welfare Analysis,” ed. J. Silber. Dordrecht and Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maasoumi, Esfandiar, Jeffrey Racine, and Thanasis Stengos, 2007, “Growth and Convergence: A Profile of Distribution Dynamics and Mobility,” Journal of Econometrics, 136, 483–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic, Branko, 2005, Worlds Apart: Measuring International and Global Inequality, Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrisson, Christian and F. Murtin, 2006, “Education Inequalities Among World Citizens: 1870–2000,” Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelsen, R.B., 1998, Introduction to Copulas, Spring Verlag: Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pradhan, Menno, David E. Sahn and Stephen D. Younger, 2003, “Decomposing World Health Inequality,” Journal of Health Economics, 22, 271–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quah, Danny T, 1996, “Twin Peaks: Growth and Convergence in Models of Distribution Dynamics,” Economic Journal, 106, 1045–1055.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, 2006, “The World Distribution of Income: Falling Poverty and... Convergence, Period,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 351–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soares, Rodrigo R., 2005, “Mortality Reductions, Educational Attainment, and Fertility Choice,” American Economic Review, 95, 580–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, Vinod, Yan Wang and Xibo Fan, 2000, “Measuring Education Inequality: Gini Coefficients of Education,” World Bank Working Paper, No. 2525

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, 2005, World Population Prospects: The 2004 Revision, available online at http://esa.un.org/unpp/

  • United Nations Development Programme, 2006, Human Development Report 2006, Beyond Scarcity: Power, Poverty and the Global Water Crisis, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank, 2006, World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development, New York: Oxford University Press for the World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu, Ximing, 2003, “Calculation of Maximum Entropy Densities with Application to Income Distribution,” Journal of Econometrics, 115, 347–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, Ximing, 2007, “Exponential Series Estimator of Multivariate Density,” working paper, Texas A&M University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu, Ximing and Jeffrey, M. Perloff, 2005, “China’s Income Distributions, 1985–2001,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 763–775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ximing Wu .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Wu, X., Savvides, A., Stengos, T. (2014). The Global Joint Distribution of Income and Health. In: Ma, J., Wohar, M. (eds) Recent Advances in Estimating Nonlinear Models. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-8060-0_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics