Skip to main content

Political Parties and Constitutional Change

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Abstract

This chapter explores why constitutions are changed. The chapter begins with an overview of why constitutional design and redesign are important questions. The second section provides a background to the study of constitutional change which has tended to be embedded within legal scholarship rather than political science. The third section reviews competing theories of constitutional change, noting the general absence of political parties from these theories and the lack of success in explaining observed patterns of constitutional amendments. The next section suggests the need to “bring the party in” and suggests how incorporating the preferences of parties and the shape of the party system can advance our understanding of constitutional change. A number of empirical cases suggest that parties and party systems shape constitutional change are discussed briefly. The chapter concludes with suggestions for how further progress can be made in integrating research on parties and party systems with research on constitutional change.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Few countries establish absolute barriers to amending any of the articles in their constitutions. Outlier examples include Germany and the United States. In Germany, the federal system is protected against changes. Similarly, amendments of the basic principles of Articles 1 (on human dignity) and 20 (on basic principles of state order and the right to resist) are inadmissible (see Article 79). Article 5 of the US Constitution says, “No state, without its Consent, shall be deprived of its equal Suffrage in the Senate”. A recent example to the same effect appears in the constitutional framework of Bosnia-Herzegovina, based on the Dayton agreement. Paragraph 2 of Article 10 states: “No amendment to this Constitution may eliminate or diminish any of the rights and freedoms referred to in Article II of this Constitution or alter the present paragraph”.

  2. 2.

    Judicial activism, defined here as “a willingness to find unconstitutional the laws and actions of duly elected officials” (Hodder-William 1992: 17), may not necessarily have a constitutional basis. For example, the executive may be held judicially accountable for breaching legislation rather than the constitution.

  3. 3.

    The rank-order coefficient Spearman’s rho is however positive and significant at conventional levels (rho = 0.580; sig. 0.012). This correlation is produced by the two countries with no change at all on both series (Denmark and Japan), and it disappears (and Pearson’s r turns negative) if the two countries are removed.

  4. 4.

    The previous institutional arrangement—not used since 1927—was seen as obsolete. The voting results indicate that this status quo was located outside the unanimity core of the major parliamentary players and that the new proposal belonged to the unanimity winset.

  5. 5.

    Article 15 says, “Any person who holds a seat in the Council of State has the duty to submit his application to resign once the Storting has passed a vote of no confidence against that Member of the Council of State or against the Council of State as a whole.” This had been a reality for more than 100 years.

  6. 6.

    Formally, amendments to New Zealand’s constitution occur in the same way as ordinary legislation. Thus, the Constitution Act 1986, as with other standard legislation, can be amended by a simple parliamentary majority. In practice, any major changes in a constitutional nature are typically the subject of a binding referendum, but these have been rare. However, a few entrenched provisions in the Electoral Act 1993 require a super majority for amendment. The entrenching provision is not itself entrenched and thus (in theory at least) could be amended or removed by a simple majority.

  7. 7.

    Lorenz (2005: 353, Table 4) reports adjusted R2 ranging from 0.77 to 0.92 in regression models with rigidity measures and length of constitution as independent variable. For example, Lutz’ index of difficulty and length explains 95 % of the variance in the dependent variable. It is questionable whether these high coefficients are reliable.

References

  • Anckar, D., & Karvonen, L. (2002, August). Constitutional amendment methods in the democracies of the world. Paper presented at the 13th Nordic Political Science Congress (pp. 15–17). Aalborg, Denmark.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergman, T., Müller, W. C., Strøm, K., & Blomgren, M. (2003). Democratic delegation and accountability: Cross-national patterns. In K. Strøm, W. C. Müller, & T. Bergman (Eds.), Delegation and accountability in parliamentary democracies (pp. 109–220). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (1999). Setting the rules of the game: The choice of electoral systems in advanced democracies. American Political Science Review, 93(3), 609–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunner, G. (2000). The constitutional judiciary in Hungary: Analysis and collected decisions 1990–93. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J. M., & Reynolds, A. (2011). The impact of election systems. Journal of Democracy, 22(4), 36–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chemerinsky, E. (1997). Constitutional law: Principles and policies. New York: Aspen Law & Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colomer, J. M. (2005). It’s parties that choose electoral systems (or, Duverger’s Law’s upside down). Political Studies, 53(1), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2001). On the durability of king and council: The continuum between dictatorship and democracy. Constitutional Political Economy, 12(3), 193–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2003). Improving democracy through constitutional reform: some swedish lessons. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Couso, J. (2003). The politics of judicial review in Chile in the era of democratic transition, 1990–2002. Democratization, 10(4), 70–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (2004). Setting the agenda. Responsible party government in the U.S. house of representatives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. T., & Mackay, R. J. (1983). Gatekeeping and monopoly power of committees: An analysis of sincere and sophisticated behaviour. American Journal of Political Science, 27(4), 740–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Depauw, S., & Martin, S. (2009). Legislative party discipline and cohesion in comparative perspective. In D. Giannetti & K. Benoit (Eds.), Intra-party politics and coalition governments in parliamentary democracies (pp. 103–120). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixon, R. (2011). Constitutional amendment rules: a comparative perspective. In T. Ginsburg & R. Dixon (Eds.), Comparative constitutional law (pp. 96–111). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixon, R., & Holden, R. (2012). Constitutional amendment rules: The denominator problem. In T. Ginsburg (Ed.), Comparative constitutional design. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Domingo, P. (2000). Judicial independence: the politics of the Supreme Court in Mexico. Journal of Latin American Studies, 32(3), 705–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duverger, M. (1954). Political parties: Their organization and activity in the modern state. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elgie, R. (1998). The classification of democratic regime types: Conceptual ambiguity and contestable assumptions. European Journal of Political Research, 33(2), 219–238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elgie, R. (2005). France: Stacking the deck. In M. Gallagher & P. Mitchell (Eds.), The politics of electoral systems (pp. 119–136). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1995). Forces and mechanisms in the constitution-making process. Duke Law Review, 45(2), 364–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (2000). Ulysses unbound: Studies in rationality, precommitment, and constraints. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L., Knight, J., & Shvetsova, O. (2001). The role of constitutional courts in the establishment of democratic systems of government. Law and Society Review, 35(1), 117–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, D. M. (2011). Electoral systems: A comparative introduction (2nd ed.). Houndmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. (1997). The politics of imperfection: The amendment of constitutions. Law and Social Inquiry, 22(2), 501–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, M. (1987). Does Ireland need a new electoral system? Irish Political Studies, 2(1), 27–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ganghof, S. (2003). Promises and pitfalls of veto player analysis. Swiss Political Science Review, 9(2), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geddes, B. (2003). Paradigms and sand castles: Theory building and research design in comparative politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, J. L., & Caldeira, G. A. (2009). Confirmation politics and the legitimacy of the U.S. Supreme Court: Institutional loyalty, positivity bias, and the Alito nomination. American Journal of Political Science, 53(1), 139–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburg, T. (2003). Judicial review in new democracies: Constitutional courts in Asian cases. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Giovannoni, F. (2003). Amendment rules in constitutions. Public Choice, 115(1/2), 37–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardarson, Ó. T., & Kristinsson, G. H. (2011). Iceland. European Journal of Political Research, 50(7/8), 999–1003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, W. B. (2001). Making policy stick: Why the government gets what it wants in multiparty parliaments. American Journal of Political Science, 45(4), 780–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodder-Williams, R. (1992). Six notions of “political” and the United States Supreme Court. British Journal of Political Science, 22(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, M., & Deschouwer, K. (2011). Veto players and electoral reform in Belgium. West European Politics, 34(3), 626–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hylland, A. (1994). Konstitusjonell treghet. Bør noen saker være unndratt flertallets kontroll? In E.R. Bjørn & K. Midgaard (Eds.), Representativt demokrati. Spilleregler under debatt. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kannar, G. (1990). The Constitutional catechism of Antonin Scalia. The Yale Law Journal, 99(6), 1297–1357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kastellec, J. P., Lax, J. R., & Phillips, J. H. (2010). Public opinion and senate confirmation of Supreme Court nominees. The Journal of Politics, 72(3), 767–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelly, A. H. (1983). The American Constitution: Its origins and development (6th ed.). New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelsen, H. (1945). General theory of law and state. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kommers, D. P. (1997). The constitutional jurisprudence of the Federal Republic of Germany. Durham: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, J. (1996). Constitutions and political theory. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1994). Electoral systems and party systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy: Government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz, A. (2005). How to measure constitutional rigidity: Four concepts and two alternatives. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 17(3), 339–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lutz, D. S. (1994). Toward a theory of constitutional amendment. American Political Science Review, 88(2), 355–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lutz, D.S. (1995). Toward a theory of constitutional amendment. In S. Levinson (Ed.), Responding to imperfection. The theory and practice of constitutional amendment (pp. 237–274). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lutz, D. S. (2006). Principles of constitutional design. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Maddex, R. L. (1996). Constitutions of the world. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moraski, B. J., & Shipan, C. R. (1999). The politics of Supreme Court nominations: a theory of institutional constraints and choices. American Journal of Political Science, 43(4), 1069–1109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (1999). On amending constitutions. Constitutional Political Economy, 10(4), 385–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, W. C. (2002). Parties and the institutional framework. In K. R. Luther & F. Müller-Rommel (Eds.), Political parties in the new Europe (pp. 249–292). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, W. (2000). Constitutional interpretation as constitutional creation: The 1999–2000 Harry Eckstein lecture. Center for the Study of Democracy. University of California at Irvine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Negretto, G. (2009). Political parties and institutional design: Explaining constitutional choice in Latin America. British Journal of Political Science, 39(1), 117–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters, G. B. (1998). The new institutionalism. London: Cassells.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pildes, R. (2010). Political parties and constitutionalism. New York University Public Law and Legal Theory Working Papers. Paper No. 179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pilet, J. B., & Bol, D. (2011). Party preferences and electoral reform: How time in government affects the likelihood of supporting electoral change. West European Politics, 34(3), 568–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasch, B. E. (1995). Parliamentary voting procedures. In H. Döring (Ed.), Parliaments and majority rule in Western Europe. Frankfurt/New York: Campus/St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasch, B. E., & Congleton, R. (2006). Stability and constitutional amendment procedures. In R. Congleton & B. Swedenborg (Eds.), Democratic constitutional design and public policy: Analysis and design. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Renwick, A. (2009). The politics of electoral reform: Changing the rules of democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agenda, and the status quo. Public Choice, 33(4), 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, B. R. (2004). Crafting a constitution for Afghanistan. Journal of Democracy, 15(3), 5–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segal, J. A., & Cover, A. D. (1989). Ideological values and the votes of U.S. Supreme Court justices. American Political Science Review, 83(2), 557–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A., & Weingast, B. R. (1987). The institutional foundations of committee power. American Political Science Review, 81(1), 85–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M. S. (2008). Inherent and contingent factors in reform initiation in plurality systems. In A. Blais (Ed.), To keep or to change first past the post? The politics of electoral reform (pp. 7–60). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sinnott, R. (2010). The electoral system. In J. Coakley & M.Gallagher (Eds.), Politics in the Republic of Ireland (pp. 111-136). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, E. (1993). Høyesterett og folkestyret. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone, A. (1992). The Birth of judicial politics in France: The constitutional council in comparative perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strøm, K. (2003). Parliamentary democracy and delegation. In K. Strøm, W. C. Müller, & T. Bergman (Eds.), Delegation and accountability in parliamentary democracies (pp. 55–106). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Szmer, J., & Songer, D. (2005). The effects of information on the accuracy of presidential assessments of Supreme Court nominee preferences. Political Research Quarterly, 58(1), 151–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taube, C. (2001). Constitutionalism in Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania: A study in comparative constitutional law. Uppsala: Iustus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: Veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25(3), 289–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players. How political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (1999). Explaining constitutional change. A positive economics approach. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whittington, K. E. (1999). Constitutional interpretation: Textual meaning, original intent, and judicial review. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research has been supported by the Norwegian Research Council (FRISAM Project No. 222442).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shane Martin .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix I: Formal Amendment Rules in Selected Countries

Appendix I: Formal Amendment Rules in Selected Countries

Country

Legislative decision(s)

Referendum and/or ratification

Comments

Australia (federation)

- Lower house 1/2

- Upper house 1/2

Majority (1/2+)

Constitutional amendment must secure the support of a majority of the whole electorate and majorities in a majority of states (i.e. in 4 of 6 states).

Austria (federation)

- Lower house 2/3

(Referendum threat)

Referendum if claimed by more than 1/3 of lower or upper house

Separate procedure for “total revision” (referendum required)

Belgium (federation)

- Pre-election declaration of revision (by federal legislative power)

  

- Post-election lower 2/3

- Post-election upper 2/3

Denmark

- Pre-election 1/2

Majority (1/2+)

Referendum majority more than 40 % of electorate

- Post-election 1/2

Estonia

- First vote 1/2

(Selected articles only)

Referendum required to amend important articles (e.g. general provisions). 3/5 in parliament to call referendum

- Second vote 3/5

Urgency: single decision with 4/5 majority

Finland

- Pre-election 1/2

 

Urgency: single decision with 5/6 majority

- Post-election 2/3

France

Either (I)

Majority (if Procedure I)

No referendum if president decides to submit proposed amendment to parliament convened in congress (i.e. Procedure II)

- Lower house 1/2

- Upper house 1/2 or (II)

The republican form of government is not subject to amendment.

- Parliament 3/5

Germany (federation)

- Lower house 2/3

 

Some articles of the constitution cannot be amended (e.g. division of federation into states)

- Upper house 2/3

Greece

- Pre-election 3/5 twice

 

The pre-election decisions should be separated by at least one month. Reversed majority requirements possible (i.e. absolute majorities before election and 3/5 majority after election)

- Post-election 1/2

Some articles of the constitution cannot be amended (e.g. the basic form of government)

Iceland

- Pre-election 1/2

(Selected articles only)

Referendum required to change the status of the church

- Post-election 1/2

- Consent by president

Ireland

- Lower house 1/2

Majority 1/2

 

- Upper house 1/2

Italy

Either (I)

(Referendum threat if Procedure I)

Referendum according to Procedure I (absolute majority—but less than two-thirds—in second vote in the chambers) if claimed by (1) 1/5 of members of either chamber (2) 500.000 electors or (3) at least five regional councils

- Lower house 1/2 twice

- Upper house 1/2 twice or (II)

- Lower house 1/2 and 2/3

- Upper house 1/2 and 2/3

Japan

- Lower house 2/3

Majority

Referendum requirement: “the affirmative vote of a majority of all votes cast thereon”

- Upper house 2/3

Latvia

- 2/3 majority in three readings

(Selected articles only)

Referendum required to amend important articles (e.g. general provisions)

Lithuania

- First vote 2/3

(Selected articles only)

Referendum required to amend important articles (in which ¾ of electorate support the amendment)

- Second vote 2/3

Delay of at least 3 months between decisions in parliament

Luxembourg

- Pre-election 1/2

  

- Post-election 2/3

Netherlands

- Pre-election lower 1/2

 

Ratification by king required

- Pre-election upper 1/2

- Post-election lower 2/3

- Post-election upper 2/3

New Zealand

- Majority vote (1/2)

(Majority)

Confirmation in referendum expected or customary if the amendment is considered sufficiently important

Norway

- Pre-election proposal by MPs (no decision)

 

Delay, but single decision in parliament

- Post-election 2/3 (closed rule)

Portugal

- Parliament 2/3

 

Some limits on revision of substance of the constitution specified in Article 288.

Spain

Either (I)

(Referendum threat)

Referendum if claimed by more than 1/10 of the members of either chamber

- Lower house 3/5

- Upper house 3/5 or (II)

Separate procedure for total revision (i.e. 2/3 majority in each chamber, dissolution, 2/3 majority in both chambers, and ratification by referendum)

- Lower house 2/3

- Upper house 1/2

Absolute majority required in the Senate according to Procedure II

Sweden

- Pre-election 1/2

(Referendum threat)

Referendum if claimed by more than 1/3 of MPs

- Post-election 1/2

Switzerland (federation)

- Lower house 1/2

Majority (1/2+)

In referendum, majority of votes nationwide as well as majority support in a majority of Cantons

- Upper house 1/2

United States (federation)

Either (I)

Ratification by ¾ of the states

Procedure II has never been used.

- Lower house 2/3

- Upper house 2/3 or (II)

- Constitutional convention (called by 2/3 of the states)

  1. Notes Key to table: Simple or absolute majority = 1/2; qualified majorities indicated by 3/5, 2/3, 4/5, etc. Sources Formal constitutions (www.uni-wuerzburg.de/law), Taube 2001, and Rasch 1995

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Martin, S., Rasch, B.E. (2013). Political Parties and Constitutional Change. In: Müller, W., Narud, H. (eds) Party Governance and Party Democracy. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-6588-1_11

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics