Skip to main content

Uncertainty Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: International Series in Operations Research & Management Science ((ISOR,volume 188))

Abstract

This chapter seeks to reconcile fundamental financial approaches with uncertainty. Uncertainty is defined by the unknown rather than the predictable, counted and accounted for. While financial decisions are reached based on what we know, what we can predict and what we can presume based on experience and the rationalities that financial agents assume. The uncertainty we consider is defined in a limited sense, namely, a partial knowledge of future state preferences and their quantification. There are many approaches to do so such as negligence of the unknown, human intentional rationalities as well behavioral and psychological approaches to confront the unknown. This chapter focuses its attention on the use of entropy for “non-extensive systems” (a term commonly used in physics with its parallel in finance, which we define as “incompleteness”) based on a parametric generalization of the Boltzmann–Gibbs entropy (which assumes extensive systems). Optimization of the Tsallis parametric entropy for non-extensive systems is then used to derive implied power laws and standardized probability distributions that are both asymmetric and have fat tails. This approach provides a parametric definition of the “missing”, namely the tail probabilities not accounted for in selecting an asset future price distribution.

Subsequently, the chapter outlines a number of approaches to robust decision models and ex-post risk management. It concludes with a discussion of risk externalities in financial and environmental regulation and draws a parallel between “banks’ risks” for which they do not assume responsibility for and pollution risks of firms and consumers who consume and who do not assume their pollution consequences. Both cases, call for an efficient regulation and statistical controls which is the topic of Chap. 11.

(*with OREN TAPIERO)

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

References

  • Abdellaoui, M., & Munier, B. (1997). Experimental determination of preferences under risk: The case of very low probability radiation. Ciencia and Tecnologia dos Materiais, 9, 25–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abdellaoui, M., & Munier, B. (1999). How consistent are probability tradeoffs in individual preferences under risk? In M. J. Machina & B. Munier (Eds.), Beliefs, interactions and preferences in decision making (pp. 285–295). Dordrecht/Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abe, S. (1997). Physics Letters A, 224, 326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ahlbrecht, M., & Weber, M. (1997). Preference for gradual resolution of uncertainty. Theory and Decision, 43, 167–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akturk, E., Bagci, G. B., & Sever, R. (2007). Is Sharma-Mittal entropy really a step beyond Tsallis and Renyi entropies? asXiv:cond-mat/07032771v1, gbb0002@unt.edu.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allais, M. (1953). Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque, Critique des postulats et axiomes de l'ecole Americaine. Econometrica, 21, 503–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amato, J. D., & Remolona, E. M. (2005). The pricing of unexpected credit losses. BIS, Working Paper No. 190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ang, B. W. (1999). Is the energy intensity a less useful indicator than the carbon factor in the study of climate change? Energy Policy, 27, 943–946.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, B. W., & Pandiyan, G. (1997). Decomposition of energy-induced CO2 emissions in manufacturing. Energy Economics, 19, 363–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1982). Risk perception in psychology and in economics. Economics Inquiry, 20, 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J., Colombatto, E., Perlman, M., & Schmidt, C. (Eds.). (1996). The rational foundations of economic behavior. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aschauer, D. A. (1989a). Is public expenditure productive. Journal of Monetary Economics, 23, 177–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aschauer, D. A. (1989b). Does public capital crowd out private capital. Journal of Monetary Economics, 24, 171–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Batten, D. F., & Karlsson, C. (Eds.). (1996). Infrastructure and the complexity of economic development (Advances in spatial science, pp. 49–60). Heidelberg and New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Berndt, E. R., & Harrison, B. (1991). Measuring the contribution of public infrastructure in Sweden, NBER WP n° 3842.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borges, E. P., & Roditi, I. (1998). A family of nonextensive entropies. Physics Letters A, 246, 399–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borland, L., & Bouchaud, J. P. (2004). A non Gaussian option pricing model with skew. Quantitative Finance, 4(5), 499–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brannlund, R., Ghalwash, T., & Nordstrom, J. (2006). Increased energy efficiency and the rebound effect: Effects on consumption and emissions, Energy Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. (1986). Distinguishing random and deterministic systems. Journal of Economic Theory, 40(1), 168–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A., & Dechert, W. D. (1988). Theorems on distinguishing deterministic systems. In W. Barnett, E. Berndt, & H. White (Eds.), Dynamic econometric modeling (pp. 247–265). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Brody, D. C., Buckley, I. R. C., & Constantinou, I. C. (2007). Option price calibration from Renyi entropy. Physics Letters A, 366, 298–3007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3(2), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. (1953). Une economie de l’incertain. Working Paper, Electricite de France, Paris, France (Published in 1960 in Economie Appliquee 13, no.1, pp. 111–116).

    Google Scholar 

  • DeCanio, S. J. (1997). Economic modeling and the false tradeoff between environmental protection and economic growth. Contemporary Economic Policy, 15, 10–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dembo, R. S. (1989). Scenario optimization. Algorithmics Inc. Research Paper 89.01.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dembo, R. S. (1993). Scenario immunization. In S. A. Zenios (Ed.), Financial optimization. London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dempster, M. A. H., Medova, E. A., & Yang, S. W. (2007). Empirical copulas for CDO tranche pricing using relative entropy, Center for Financial Research, Judge Business School, University of Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyer, J. S., & Jia, J. (1997). Relative risk-value model. European Journal of Operational Research, 103, 170–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N. (1996). The Economics of Networks, International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 14, No 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eeckhoudt, L., Gollier, C., & Schlesinger, H. (1996). Changes in background risk and risk taking behavior. Econometrica, 64, 683–689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eeckoudt, L., & Kimball, M. (1991). Background risk prudence and the demand for insurance. In G. Dionne (Ed.), Contributions to insurance economics. Boston: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellsberg, D. (1961). Risk, ambiguity and the savage axioms (pp. 643–669). 75: Quarterly Journal of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fraundorf, P. (2007). Thermal roots of correlation-based complexity. Complexity, 13(3), 18–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1976). Price Theory, Aldine de Gruyler.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M., & Savage, L. J. (1948). The utility analysis of choices involving risk. Journal of Political Economy, 56, 279–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M., & Savage, L. J. (1952). The expected utility hypothesis and the measurability of utility. Journal of Political Economy, 60, 463–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbs, J. W. (1961). The scientific papers of J.W. Gibbs (Vol. 1). New York: Dover Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilboa, I., & Schmeidler, D. (1995). Case-based decision theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99, Août 1995. p. 605-639.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gollier, C., & Pratt, J. W. (1996). Risk vulnerability and the tempering effect of background risk. Econometrica, 64, 1109–1123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Good, I. J. (1965). The estimation of probabilities: An essay on modern Bayesian methods (Research Monograph no 30). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Good, I. J. (1968). Utility of a distribution. Nature, 219, 139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gramlich, E. M. (1994). Infrastructure: A review essay. Journal of Economic Literature, 32, 1176–1196 (see important list of references at the end of the paper).

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovskii, A., Dincer, I., & Rosen, M. A. (2006). Environmental and economic aspects of hydrogen production and utilization in fuel cell vehicles. Journal of Power Sources, 157(1), 411–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greaker, M. (2006). Spillovers in the development of new pollution abatement technology: A new look at the Porter-hypothesis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 52, 411–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greening, L. A., Greene, D. L., & Difiglio, C. (2000). Energy efficiency and consumption—The rebound effect—A survey. Energy Policy, 28, 389–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, F. H. (1909). Mess. Math. 38, 1909, 57, Quarterly Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics, 41, 193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jia, J., & Dyer, J. S. (1996). A standard measure of risk and risk-value models. Management Science, 42(12), 1691–1705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jia, J., Dyer, J. S., & Butler, J. C. (2001). Generalized disappointment models. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 22(1), 59–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk, Econometrica, March, pp. 263–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kapur, J. N., & Kesavan, H. K. (1992). Entropy optimization principles with applications. San Diego, CA: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M., & Shapiro, C. (1985). Network externalities, competition, and compatibility. American Economic Review, 75(3), 424–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C. (1978). Manias, panics, and crashes: a history of financial crises, Basic Books

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profits. Boston, MA: Houghton, Mifflin & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kullback, S. (1959). Information theory and statistics. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kullback, S. (1987). The Kullback-Leibler distance. The American Statistician, 41, 340–341.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kullback, S., & Leibler, R. A. (1951). On Information and sufficiency. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 22(1), 79–86. doi:10.1214/aoms/1177729694 DOI:10.1214%2Faoms%2F1177729694.MR39968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J. J. (1989). The economics of uncertainty and information. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J. J. (1995). Regulation, moral hazard and insurance of environmental risks. Journal of Public Economics, 58, 319–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, N., & Cosgel, M. M. (1993). Frank Knight on risk, uncertainty and the firm: A new reinterpretations. Economic Inquiry, 31(3), 456–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leland, H., & Pyle, D. (1977). Information asymmetries, financial structure and financial intermediation. Journal of Finance, 32, 371–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leroy, S. F., & Singell, L. D., Jr. (1987). Knight on risk and uncertainty. Journal of Political Economy, 95(21), 394–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S., & Margolis, S. (1994). Network externality: An uncommon tragedy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(2), 133–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1982). Regret theory: An alternative to rational choice under uncertainty. The Economic Journal, 92, 805–824.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1987). Some implications of a more general form of regret theory. Journal of Economic Theory, 41, 270–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz, E. (1966). Large-scale motions of the atmosphere: Circulation. In P. M. Hurley (Ed.), Advances in earth science. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M. J. (1982). Expected utility analysis without the independence axiom. Econometrica, 50, 277–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M. J., & Munier, B. (Eds.). (1999). Beliefs, interactions and preferences in decision making. Boston: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magill, M., & Quinzii, M. (1996). Theory of incomplete markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandelbrot, B. (1997). Three fractal models in finance: Discontinuity, concentration, risk. Economic Notes, 26, 171–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandelbrot, B., & Wallis, J. (1968). Noah, Joseph and operational hydrology. Water Resources Research, 4, 909–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • May, R. (1974). Biological populations with non-overlapping generations: Stable points, stable cycles, and chaos. Science, 186, 645–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, C., & Schwartz, A. (1996). State infrastructure and productive performance. American Economic Review, 86, 1095–1111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulvey, J. M., Vanderbei, R.J., & Zenios, S.A. (1991). Robust optimization of large scale systems. Report SOR 13, Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munier, B. (1986). Complexité et Décision stratégique dans l'Incertain : Que peut-on retenir de la Théorie?. In: Boiteux, M., Th. de Montbrial and B. Munier, eds., Marchés, Capital et Incertitude, Paris, Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munier, B. (1991). Market uncertainty and the process of belief formation. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 4, 233–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munier, B. (1995). From instrumental to cognitive rationality: Contributions of the last decade to risk modeling. Revue d'Economie Politique, 105, 5–70 (French, with abstract in English).

    Google Scholar 

  • Munier, B. (Ed.). (2012). Global uncertainty and the volatility of agricultural commodities. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: IOS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munier, B., Selten, R., et al. (1999). Bounded rationality modeling. Marketing Letters, 10(3), 233–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munnell, A. H. (1992). Infrastructure investment and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6, 189–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nau, R. (2011). Risk, ambiguity and state-preference theory. Economic Theory, 48(2–3), 437–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naudts, J. (2007). Generalized thermostatistics. Belgium: University of Antwerpen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nijkamp, P., & Blaas, E. (1993). Impact assessment and evaluation in transportation planning. Amsterdam: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peter, E. E. (1995). Chaos and order in capital markets. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (1998). Psychology and economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 11–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riordan, M. (1984). Uncertainty, asymmetric information and bilateral contracts. Review of Economic Studies, 51, 83–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Wets, R. J.-B. (1992). A dual strategy for the implementation of the aggregation principle in decision making under uncertainty. Applied Stochastic Models and Data Analysis, 8, 245–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. (1998). Modeling bounded rationality. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1963). Risk and uncertainty: A fallacy of large numbers. Scientia, 98, 108–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1965). Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Industrial Management Review, 6, 41–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanchez-Robles, B. (1998a). The Role of Infrastructure Investment in Development: Some Macroeconomic Considerations International-Journal-of-Transport-Economics; 25(2), June, pages 113-36. http://wwwdte.spol.uniroma1.it/trasporti/journal.html

  • Sanchez-Robles, B. (1998b). Infrastructure investment and growth: Some empirical evidence. Contemporary Economic Policy, 16(1), 98–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sato, A.-H. (2010). q-Gaussian distributions and multiplicative stochastic processes for analysis of multiple financial time series, Mathematical Analysis of Generalized Entropies and their Applications,, Journal of Physics, Conference Series 201, 012008

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1979). Models of man. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1982). Models of bounded rationality (Vol. 2). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stanley, M. H. R., Amaral, L. A. N., Bulkdyrev, S. V., Havlin, S. V., Leschron, H., Mass, P., Salinger, M. A., & Stanley, H. E. (1996). Nature, 397, 804.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taleb, N. N. (2007). The Black Swan: The impact of the highly improbable. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taleb, N. N. (2008). The fourth quadrant: A map of the limits of statistics. Edge, http://www.edge.org/3rd_culture/taleb08/taleb08_index.html.

  • Taleb, N. N. (2009). Errors, robustness, and the fourth quadrant. International Journal of Forecasting, 25(4), 744–759.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taleb, N. N., & Tapiero, C.S. (2010). Risk Externalities and Too Big to Fail, Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Applications 2010

    Google Scholar 

  • Tapiero, C. (1995a). Complexity and industrial systems. Special Issue Editor, RAIRO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tapiero, C. S. (1995b). Acceptance sampling in a producer-supplier conflicting environment: Risk neutral case. Applied Stochastic Models and Data Analysis, 11, 3–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tapiero, C. S. (2005a). Risk management, encyclopedia on actuarial and risk management. New York and London: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tapiero, O. (2012). Implied Risk neutral Distribution: The Non Extensive Entropy Approach, Ph.D Dissertation, Bar Ilan University, Israel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., et al. (1997). The effect of myopia and loss aversion on risk taking: An experimental test. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 647–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances is prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P. P. (1994). Separating marginal utility and probabilistic risk aversion. Theory and Decision, 36, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P. P. (2001). On the composition of risk preference and belief. Psychological Review, 111, 236–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P. P. (2010). Prospect theory for risk and ambiguity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P., & Tversky, A. (1993). An axiomatization of cumulative prospect theory. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7, 147–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weston, J. F. The profit concept and theory: A restatement. Journal of Political Economy, 62((2), 152–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xepapadeas, A. P. (1994). Controlling environmental externalities: Observability and optimal policy rules. In C. Dosi & T. Tomasi (Eds.), Nonpoint source pollution regulation: Issues and analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xepapadeas, A. P. (1995). Observability and choice of instrument mix in the control of externalities. Journal of Public Economics, 56, 485–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renyi, A. (1961). On measures of entropy and information. In Proceedings of the 4th Berkeley Symposium on Mathematics, Statistics and Probability; Statistical Laboratory of the University of California, Berkeley, CA, USA, 20 June–30 June, 1960; University of California Press: Berkeley, California, 1961; Volume 1, pp. 547–561.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsallis, C. (1988). Possible generalization of Boltzmann-Gibbs statistics. Journal of Statistical Physics, 52, 479–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

References and Additional Reading

References and Additional Reading

Uncertainty and risks are issues that remain debatable. Brock (1986) and Brock and Dechert (1988) distinguish between random and deterministic systems. In Chap. 5 these issues were both discussed and referred to, each approach seeking some way to formalize our lack of knowledge in some rational and quantified form. In particular, we have used incomplete state preferences (Knight 1921) to define uncertainty. It is however a specific type of uncertainty. Other approaches seek to define alternatives to rational decision making based on a weighting of probabilities. For example, Machina 1982, 1987; Samuelson 1963, 1965 (on the limits of the explanatory power of “numbers”), Machina and Munier 1999; Abdellaoui and Munier 1997, 1999 on the belief and probability assignments to rare events (see also Munier 1986, 1995, 1991; Munier et al. 1999; Rabin 1998 on economics psychology), Simon 1979, 1982 on bounded rationality, Munier 2012 (on volatility and uncertainty supported by an extensive empirical analysis of agricultural commodities), Ahlbrecht and Weber 1997 on the gradual resolution of uncertainty, etc.

The literature in this domain is thus extremely large and applied to a broad set of issues and problems. The references below define various formalizations to decision making with behavioral and psychological factors: Dyer and Jia 1997, Jia and Dyer 1996, Jia et al. 2001 on perceived risks, Eeckoudt and Kimball 1991, Eeckhoudt et al. 1996, Gollier and Pratt 1996 (on background risks), Ellsberg 1961 on ambiguity and Savage Axioms (regret), Evans on Psychological Reasoning and rationality, Gilboa and Schmeidler 1995, Kahneman and Tversky 1979 on Prospect Theory, Thaler et al. 1997; Wakker 1994, 2001, 2010; Wakker and Tversky 1993; Taleb 2007, 2008, 2009.

Implications to economics include seminal papers by Arrow (1963b) on welfare of medical care, Arrow (1982) on the risk perception and psychology in economics, Arrow et al. (1996) on Rational Foundations for decision making, Debreu (1953) on the economics of uncertainty, Friedman and savage (1948, 1952) on utility analysis, Kindleberger (1978) on Mania and panics, Laffont (1989, 1995) on the economics of uncertainty, regulation insurance and environmental risks, Loomes and Sugden (1982, 1987), Mulvey et al. (1991) on scenario based uncertainty and Magill and Quinzii (1996) on markets incompleteness.

Risk externalities are a special form of uncertainty (at least for the public at large, unaware of the actions that parties take with consequences they do not assume). In this sense, Coase (1937, 1960), important contributions discussed in this chapter provide a guideline to assess their effects. For applications, references are given in the text. We refer in particular to Xepapadeas (1994, 1995) on risk externalities and environmental issues.

Chaos, complexity or “the lack of order” are some of the more important sources of uncertainty. Chaos is a field originating in forms of “unpredictability”. For example, a process that cannot converge to any particular end, bifurcating continuously in an unpredictable manner is chaotic. This leads to statements, that a “sneeze” may lead one catch a cold in New York! Namely, that anything and everything are unpredictable and therefore everything may occur. Lorenz (1966) for example, studied and defined chaos in atmospheric data, May (1974) defined dynamic systems in biological systems that are “chaotic”, Gleick (1987) and Peter Edgar (1995) have written popular books on chaos, etc.

In physics, uncertainty in its economic sense, is characterize by non-extensive systems (parallel to incomplete financial markets) and extensive systems (complete financial markets).The characterization of such systems are difficult however. Statistical physics following Gibbs (1961), Boltzmann, Shannon and others, have used entropy as a measure of disorder. The greater the entropy, the greater “disorder”. In this sense entropy has become a “probability” measure to define “disorder” in terms of particular metrics. Stanley et al. (1996) for example, have made immense contributions to such approaches based statistical, economic and financial physics. Numerous attempts have been made to generalize both the measures and the metrics to define and estimate “non-extensiveness”. The results outlined in this chapter were based on such studies. In particular, Jackson (1909) provided an approach to calculate for “jump” derivatives. Jackson’s formulation has shown in this chapter, that Tsallis entropy (Tapiero 1995a, b) and the BG entropy differ only in the metric used to define “disorder”. Sato (2010) uses the Jackson derivative under mean–variance assumptions to obtain a q-Gaussian distributions (based on Tsallis entropy). Other references (not referred to in the text) include Kapur and Kesavan (1992) entropy maximization, Renyi (1961), Dempster et al. (2007) applied empirical copulas to CDO tranche pricing using relative entropy, Akturk et al. (2007) on Sharma-Mittal entropy, Nau (2011) and Naudts (2007) on statistical dynamics and entropy. And Fraundorf (2007) on complexity, Kullback (1959, 1987), Kullback and Leibler (1951), Good (1965, 1968) on information and utility, have provided however a statistical approach to entropy as a metric—both of information and a metric.

Fractal models defined in Chap. 5 (Mandelbrot 1997; Mandelbrot and Wallis 1968 on fractal models for example), provide also another form of uncertainty, modeled by the nonlinear growth of volatility. While information asymmetry and financial intermediation based on contractual agreements, unexpected credit losses, etc. are also sources of uncertainty we have considered in Chaps. 8 and 9 (see also Leland and Pyle 1977 on Riordan 1984; Amato and Remolona 2005).

Finally, networks, the intricate relationships of networked agents, firms, their exchange etc. are a source of uncertainty. Even though, there are some research papers that recognize specific characteristics of networks and networking in economic and financial systems, it remains a challenging topic (Economides 1996). Katz and Shapiro (1985, 1994) provide an outline of networks externalities and their effects on system competition, Liebowitz and Margolis (1994), emphasize as well the uncommon tragedy of network externality.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Charles S. Tapiero

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tapiero, C.S. (2013). Uncertainty Economics. In: Engineering Risk and Finance. International Series in Operations Research & Management Science, vol 188. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-6234-7_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics