Skip to main content

Does Formal Work Pay in Serbia? The Role of Labor Taxes and Social Benefit Design in Providing Disincentives for Formal Work

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: Economic Studies in Inequality, Social Exclusion and Well-Being ((EIAP,volume 8))

Abstract

There are two particular issues of the Serbian labor market of extreme importance in the recent debate: the high levels of inactivity and informal employment among the Serbian working-age population. Both of these issues lead to the question if it is actually “worthwhile” for the working-age population to engage in income-generating activities in Serbia. This chapter focuses on the role of labor taxation and social benefit design, how it relates to informal employment and inactivity, and what disincentives for formal work might be provided to people in working age so they choose to “exit” into informality or inactivity.

The analysis shows that there are three main reform options to decrease informal employment and to activate the inactive (1) to make formal work pay for low-wage earners, (2) to genuinely means test any entitlements to free health insurance or other municipal entitlements, and (3) to step up inspections and enforcement. The two main policy tools to make formal work pay are to decrease labor taxation at the lower wage levels and to reform benefit design for social assistance and family benefits.

Michael Weber contributed to the empirical analysis focusing on integrating income data from the household budget survey with data from the labor force survey. Background papers have been provided by Nikica Mojsoska-Blazevski, Victor Macias, Sasa Randjelovic, Bojan Ristic, and Jelena Zarkovic Rakic. This chapter greatly benefited from a close cooperation with Tatiana Gordine, Herwig Immervoll, and Dominique Partout at the Social Policy Division of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). Generous financial support has been provided by the governments of Austria, Germany, Korea, and Norway through the Multi-donor Trust Fund on Labor Markets, Job Creation, and Economic Growth.

The views and opinions expressed in this chapter are solely those of the authors and do not represent the views and opinions of the World Bank, its board of Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The literature acknowledges that the share of informal employment might be pro-cyclical or countercyclical, although in most countries, it appears to be countercyclical. For a literature overview on this topic, see Perry et al. (2007).

  2. 2.

    In Serbia, full-time work at 33% of the average wage is below the legal minimum wage, but the same tax wedge applies to someone receiving average wage but working 33% part-time. The same holds for most other countries, although there can be slight variations of the tax wedge for part-time workers.

  3. 3.

    The assumed relationship is that tax systems need to raise a certain fixed amount of resources, and those that put higher taxes on lower wages have less of need to increase taxes at higher wages and hence display less progressivity.

  4. 4.

    The terms mini-jobs and midi-jobs originate from the social welfare reforms (Hartz IV) in Germany in the early 2000s, which aimed at making work more lucrative for low-wage earners in this labor market segment.

  5. 5.

    Only workers who are not registered at all are considered; partially formal workers who underreport their wages are not considered.

  6. 6.

    For a detailed definition and discussion of the FTR, see Koettl and Weber (2012).

  7. 7.

    Clearly, no causality between high work disincentives and high levels of informal employment can be established without further empirical analysis. Koettl and Weber (2012), though, using similar concepts and a more elaborate empirical analysis find a strong positive correlation between work disincentives (METR, FTR) and informal employment in six new EU member states.

  8. 8.

    The matching procedure only takes into account labor income, not income from agriculture, self-employment, capital income, or other forms of income.

  9. 9.

    Only about 8% of the population is currently not covered by the Serbian health insurance fund (HIF).

  10. 10.

    Arguably, the role of social assistance in providing disincentives for formal work for a large number of people might be limited. About 170,000 people—including children and elderly—currently benefit from social assistance in Serbia, which is about 2.5% of the population, although the numbers have been increasing rapidly in recent months. In any case, as the social safety net of Serbia is being modernized, the disincentive effect and the marginal effective tax rate should be kept in mind.

References

  • Eurostat (2010) Statistics Database. Available at http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat.

  • Hussmanns, R. (2003) Statistical definition of informal employment: Guidelines endorsed by the Seventeenth International Conference of Labour Statisticians (2003). Geneva, Switzerland: International Labour Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koettl, J. and M. Weber (2012) “Does Formal Work Pay? The role of labor taxation and social benefit design in the New Member States.” Research in Labor Economics. 34:167–204.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perry, G., W. Maloney, O. Arias, P. Fajnzylber, A. Mason, and J. Saavedra-Chanduvi (2007) Informality. Exit and Exclusion. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2009) BEEPS at-a-Glance 2008–09. Serbia. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2010) World Development Indicators. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. April.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Johannes Koettl .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix Table 9.8 Number of tax payers in contributors to social security in Bosnia and Herzegovina—Republika Srpska, Macedonia, and Serbia

Appendix Table 9.8 Number of tax payers in contributors to social security in Bosnia and Herzegovina—Republika Srpska, Macedonia, and Serbia

 

2006

2007

2008

2009

Average annual change (%)

Bosnia and Herzegovina—RS

Number of registered payers of taxes and contributions

n.a.

974,976

1,121,126

1,197,456

10.9

Macedonia

Number of registeredcontributors to pension fund

394,882

424,338

451,491

n.a.

6.9

Individuals filing tax reports on nonwage income

19,447

77,017

120,396

150,569

125.8

Serbia

Number of registered payers of taxes and contributions

n.a.

2,188,503

2,229,236

2,162,145

−0.6

  1. n.a. not available
  2. Source: Administrative data

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Koettl, J. (2013). Does Formal Work Pay in Serbia? The Role of Labor Taxes and Social Benefit Design in Providing Disincentives for Formal Work. In: Ruggeri Laderchi, C., Savastano, S. (eds) Poverty and Exclusion in the Western Balkans. Economic Studies in Inequality, Social Exclusion and Well-Being, vol 8. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-4945-4_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics