Skip to main content

US Generic Advertising and Promotion Programs

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
US Programs Affecting Food and Agricultural Marketing

Part of the book series: Natural Resource Management and Policy ((NRMP,volume 38))

  • 1414 Accesses

Abstract

Nine in ten US farmers collectively contribute about $1 billion annually to generic advertising and promotion campaigns. This chapter discusses the rationale and history of these controversial programs; explains the importance of the legal battles that shaped their development; and discusses the modern problems facing these campaigns. An especially difficult challenge is promoting commodities in a marketplace where food manufacturing is increasingly concentrated, brands are more and more prevalent, and consumer preferences are fluid. Areas for future research are cited.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Iron’s (1982) discussion (Chaps. 68) shows that both the farmers and the lawyers working on the AAA were hardly unanimous in the type of programs to put into place. See also the discussion of the New Deal agricultural policy reform by Paarlberg (1983), Harl (1999, p. 388), and Gilbert (2000).

  2. 2.

    The Tenth Amendment states, “The powers not delegated to the United States by the Constitution, nor prohibited to it by the States, are reserved to the States respectively, or to the people.”

  3. 3.

    The Supreme Court upheld the Act and the Order in 1939 in a 5 to 4 decision (United States v. Rock Royal CO-OP., Inc. 307 U.S. 533). The ensuing years would still be filled with litigation involving marketing orders, but most of these complaints were along procedural grounds such as the timing or calling of board elections and voting, or the Secretary’s handling of various suspensions of program provisions. There would be no serious challenge to the constitutionality of the programs for nearly 50 years.

  4. 4.

    This is based on an Internet search using the academic search engine EconLit on the key words “generic/commodity and advertising/promotion”.

  5. 5.

    See, for example, the summary of various studies provided in Alston et al. (2007).

  6. 6.

    In October 2002, a U.S. district judge in Michigan, Richard Enslen, also citing United Foods, ruled that similar legislation for the pork check-off program was not only unconstitutional but “rotten” as well (Michigan Pork Producers Association v. Campaign for Family Farms, 229 F. Supp 2d 772 W.D. Mich. 2002), and struck down the entire pork check-off, including the portions for research and education.

  7. 7.

    Modern agricultural markets also feature increasing use of what economists call “vertical control” implemented through various types of contracts. Traditional “spot” or auction markets wherein prices are “discovered” on a continuous basis are increasingly rare. Mushroom marketers, for example, report that there is a single window of time during the year when they are able to negotiate prices with food retailers, and the price is fixed for the rest of the year. How does generic advertising work in this environment? What if it succeeds in raising consumer demand, but retailers capture that demand shift in the form of higher prices? No more farm product is sold in such a case, and, thus, farmers derive no benefit from a program that “worked” in the sense of raising consumer demand. Little research has been conducted into such possibilities. One exception is the work by Carman et al. (2009), which used retail-level scanner data to examine price and quantity impacts of promotions conducted by the Hass Avocado Board. This study found no evidence that retailers raised prices in response to avocado promotions.

  8. 8.

    These concerns also tie in with nonmarket social values and government market intervention as discussed in the introductory chapter in that consumers may want certain food attributes.

References

  • Alston JM, Freebairn JW, James JS (2001) Beggar-thy-neighbor Advertising. Amer J of Agr Econ 83:888-902.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alston JM, Brunke H, Gray R, Sumner DA (2005a) Demand Enhancement through Food-Safety Regulation: A Case Study of the Marketing Order for California Pistachios. In: Kaiser HM, Alston JM, Crespi JM, Sexton RJ (eds) Commodity Promotion Programs in California: Economic Evaluation and Legal Issues, Peter Lang Publishing, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alston JM, Chalfant JA, James JS (2005b) Evaluation of Nutrition Education by the Dairy Council of California. In: Kaiser HM, Alston JM, Crespi JM, Sexton RJ (eds) Commodity Promotion Programs in California: Economic Evaluation and Legal Issues, Peter Lang Publishing, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alston JM, Crespi JM, Kaiser HM, Sexton RJ (2007) An Evaluation of California’s Mandated Commodity Promotion Programs. Review of Agricultural Economics 29:40-63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breimeyer HF (1983) Conceptualization and Climate for New Deal Farm Laws of the 1930s. Amer J of Agr Econ 65:1153-57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carman HF, Li L, Sexton RJ (2009) An Economic Evaluation of the Hass Avocado Promotion Order’s First Five Years. Giannini Foundation Research Report No. 351, University of California, Division of Agriculture and Natural Resources.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarti A, Janiszewski C (2004) The Influence of Generic Advertising on Brand Preferences. J. Consumer Research 30:487-502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chung C, Kaiser HM (2000) Distribution of Generic Advertising Benefits Across Participating Firms. Amer J of Agr Econ 82:659-664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congressional Research Service (2005) Agriculture: A Glossary of Terms, Programs, and Laws, 2005 Edition. CRS Report for Congress, Order Code 97-905, June 16, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespi JM, Marette S (2002) Generic Advertising and Product Differentiation. Amer J of Agr Econ 84:151-161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespi JM, McEowen RA (2006) The Constitutionality of Generic Advertising Check-off Programs. Choices 21:61-65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespi JM, Marette S (2009) The Pro-Competitive Effects of Demand Enhancing Check-off Programs. Amer J of Agr Econ 91: 389-401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ezekiel M, Bean LH (1993) Economic Bases for the Agricultural Adjustment Act. United States Department of Agriculture, December, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forker OD, Ward R (1993) Commodity Advertising: The Economics and Measurement of Generic Programs, Lexington Books, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert J (2000) Eastern Urban Liberals and Midwestern Agrarian Intellectuals. Agr Hist 74:162-180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harl NE (1999) Agricultural Law Volume 9, Chapter 70. Matthew Bender & Company, Inc., New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iron PH (1982) The New Deal Lawyers. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen HH, Kesavan T (1993) Sources of Information, Consumer Attitudes on Nutrition, and Consumption of Dairy Products. J Consumer Affairs 27:357-76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kawaguchi T, Suzuki N, Kaiser HM (1997) A Spatial Equilibrium Model for Imperfectly Competitive Milk Markets. Amer J of Agr Econ 79:851-859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messer KD, Schmit TM, Kaiser HM (2005) Optimal Institutional Mechanisms for Funding Generic Advertising: An Experimental Analysis. Amer J of Agr Econ 87:1046-1060.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messer KD, Poe GL, Kaiser HM (2007) Voluntary Funding for Generic Advertising Using a Provision-Point Mechanism: An Experimental Analysis of Option Assurance. Rev of Agr Econ 29:612-631.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messer KD, Kaiser HM, Schulze W (2008) The Problem with Generic Advertising: Parallelism and Possible Solutions from the Lab. Amer J of Agr Econ 90:540-552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messer KD, Kaiser HM, Payne C, Wansink B (2011) Can Generic Advertising Alleviate Consumer Concerns over Food Scares? Appl Econ 43:1535-1549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norman G, Pepall L, Richards D (2008) Generic Product Advertising, Spillovers, and Market Concentration. Amer J of Agr Econ 90:719-732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paarlberg D (1983) Effects of New Deal Farm Programs on the Agricultural Agenda a Half Century Later and Prospect for the Future. Amer J of Agr Econ 65:1163-1167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park J, Capps O Jr (2002) Impacts of Advertising, Attitudes, Lifestyles and Health on the Demand for U. S. Pork: A Micro-Level Analysis. J Agr and Appl Econ 34:1-15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richards TJ, Patterson PM (2005) The Economic Value of Spin Control: Food Safety and the Strawberry Case. In: Kaiser HM, Alston JM, Crespi JM, Sexton RJ (eds) Commodity Promotion Programs in California: Economic Evaluation and Legal Issues, Peter Lang Publishing, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulz LL, Crespi JM (2012) Presence of Check-off Programs and Industry Concentration in the Food Manufacturing Sector. Agribusiness 28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suzuki N, Kaiser HM (1997) Imperfect Competition Models and Commodity Promotion Evaluation: The Case of U.S. Generic Milk Advertising. J of Agr Appl Econ 29:315-325.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woeste VS (1998) The Farmer’s Benevolent Trust: Law and Agricultural Cooperation in Industrial America, 1865-1945. The University of North Carolina Press, Chapel Hill, NC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wohlgenant MK, Piggott NE (2003) Distribution of Gains from Research and Promotion in the Presence of Market Power. Agribusiness 19:301-314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang M, Sexton RJ (2002) Optimal Commodity Promotion when Downstream Markets Are Imperfectly Competitive. Amer J of Agr Econ 84:352-365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to Walt Armbruster, Ron Knutson, and three anonymous reviewers for helpful comments, and they are held blameless for any errors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John M. Crespi .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Federal Orders and Check-Offs That Include Promotion and Advertising

The 51 industries covered by federal marketing orders and stand-alone research and promotion (check-off) programs that can partake in generic advertising and promotion are listed here. Not all programs are active and some have more activities than others. Other commodity promotion programs have state authorization and operate exclusively within the boundaries of the authorizing state. As of 2011, there are three Federal research and promotion programs under consideration (raspberries, Christmas trees, and softwood lumber).

Marketing orders for fruits, vegetables, and nuts

 

1

Marketing Order 981: California Almonds

2

Marketing Order 922: Washington Apricots

3

Marketing Order 915: Florida Avocados

4

Marketing Order 923: Washington Cherries

5

Marketing Order 930: Tart Cherries

6

Marketing Order 905: Florida Citrus

7

Marketing Order 906: Texas Citrus

8

Marketing Order 929: Cranberries

9

Marketing Order 987: California Dates

10

Marketing Order 925: California Desert Grapes

11

Marketing Order 982: Oregon and Washington Hazelnuts

12

Marketing Order 920: California Kiwifruit

13

Marketing Order 916: California Nectarines

14

Marketing Order 932: California Olives

15

Marketing Order 958: Idaho and Oregon Onions

16

Marketing Order 959: South Texas Onions

17

Marketing Order 955: Georgia Vidalia Onions

18

Marketing Order 956: Walla Walla Onions

19

Marketing Order 917: California Peaches

20

Marketing Order 927: Oregon and Washington Pears

21

Marketing Order 983: California Pistachios

22

Marketing Order 993: California Dried Prunes

23

Marketing Order 924: Washington-Oregon Prunes

24

Marketing Order 945: Idaho and Eastern Oregon Potatoes

25

Marketing Order 946: Washington Potatoes

26

Marketing Order 947: Oregon and California Potatoes

27

Marketing Order 948 Colorado Potatoes

28

Marketing Order 953: Virginia and North Carolina Potatoes

29

Marketing Order 989: California Raisins

30

Marketing Order 985: Far West Spearmint Oil

31

Marketing Order 966: Florida Tomatoes

32

Marketing Order 984 California Walnuts

Milk marketing orders

 

33

Dairy Federal Milk Marketing Orders (currently there are 11 federal marketing orders)

Current research and promotion check-off programs

 

34

Beef Promotion and Research Program

35

Blueberry Promotion, Research and Information Order

36

Cotton Research and Promotion

37

Dairy Producer Check-off Program

38

Egg Research & Promotion

39

Fluid Milk Processor Promotion Program

40

Hass Avocado Research and Promotion Plan

41

Honey Packers and Importers Research, Promotion, and Information Order

42

Lamb Promotion and Research Program

43

Mango Promotion, Research and Information Order

44

Mushroom Research and Promotion Plan

45

Peanut Promotion, Research and Information Order

46

Popcorn Promotion, Research and Consumer Information Order

47

Pork Promotion and Research Program

48

Potato Research and Promotion Plan

49

Sorghum Promotion, Research, and Information Program

50

Soybean Promotion and Research Program

51

Watermelon Research and Promotion Plan

How Economists Measure the Benefits of Generic Promotions

There are a number of methods for measuring the benefits and costs of generic promotion programs. Here we present the method discussed by Alston et al. (2007) because it has been used extensively and because an understanding of this method is useful to understand other methods that have been proffered. The analysis begins with a model of supply and demand, as in Fig. 7.1, where S 0 represents the initial market supply of a commodity and D 0 represents the initial market demand. The market equilibrium price is P 0 and equilibrium quantity is Q 0.

Fig. 7.1
figure 1

Model of generic advertising

Applying some additional standard assumptions in applied economics, the same supply and demand curves can be used to measure the total variable costs and benefits from consumption. Specifically, these assumptions state that (1) the area beneath the demand curve represents total consumer benefits from consuming the commodity; (2) the area beneath the supply curve represents total variable costs of production; and (3) we can add up benefits and costs across producers and consumers. Hence, for the initial quantity of Q 0, total benefits from consumption are equal to the trapezoidal area 0abQ 0 and, given consumer expenditure of P 0 Q 0  =  area 0P 0 bQ 0, consumer surplus is equal to the area of the triangle, abP 0. Similarly, for the initial quantity of Q 0, total variable costs of production are equal to the trapezoidal area 0cbQ 0 and, given total revenue of P 0 Q 0  =  area 0P 0 bQ 0, producer surplus is equal to the area of the triangle, P 0 bc. The total net benefit in this market is equal to the sum of producer surplus and consumer surplus, the area abc.

Now suppose a check-off of k per unit is collected from producers of the commodity. We can model the check-off as a parallel shift in supply from S 0 to S 1. The check-off generates revenue, R, that is used to finance promotions designed to enhance demand. Suppose the expenditure of R results in a shift in demand from D 0 to D 1, reflecting an increase in consumers’ willingness-to-pay for the commodity by r per unit for any quantity. The combined effects of the check-off and promotion shift the industry equilibrium from point b to point e, the market price (inclusive of the check-off) increases to P 2, and the quantity demanded increases to Q 2, which is also the quantity supplied at a producer net price of P 2  −  k. This represents the final equilibrium, reflecting both the promotion-induced increase in willingness-to-pay of r per unit and collection of the check-off of k per unit that finances the promotion. The total expenditure on promotion equals the amount raised by the check-off: R  =  kQ 2.

Areas in Fig. 7.1 represent the implications for consumer, producer, and national welfare. Only the key elements of Fig. 7.1 that are required for the welfare analysis are replicated in Fig. 7.2. First, we wish to measure the change in producer surplus between the initial equilibrium at point b (P 0, Q 0) and the final equilibrium reflecting the check-off and the induced demand shift, point e (P 2, Q 2). This producer net benefit can be represented as the area of additional producer surplus associated with the increase in production from Q 0 to Q 2 measured along the supply curve that includes the check-off, S1—in other words, the trapezoidal area P 2 ejg. When studies report benefit–cost ratios, generally they refer to the producers’ gross gain associated with the promotion (which is best measured as the change in producer surplus, area P 2 ejg in Fig. 7.2) divided by either (a) the loss of producer surplus associated with collection of the check-off, which is equal to area P 1 df(P 2  −  k) in Fig. 7.1—the final producer incidence of the check-off, or (b) the total expenditures on promotion, which are equal to P 2 ef(P 2k)  =  kQ 2 in Figs. 7.1 and 7.2—the initial incidence of the check-off that does not take the shifting of the tax into account.

Fig. 7.2
figure 2

Measuring benefits and costs of generic r advertising

How the benefits are reported differs across studies. For many studies a simple comparison of total benefits and total costs yields a measure of an average benefit–cost ratio, comparing the costs and benefits from having the program with a hypothetical alternative of no program. Other studies compute a marginal benefit–cost ratio by comparing the costs and benefits associated with a small hypothetical change in the size of the program. The average benefit–cost measure indicates whether a program was profitable while the marginal measure indicates whether it would have been profitable to increase the size of the program (marginal ratio >1) or reduce it (marginal ratio <1). Both ratios can be computed using the above methodology. Typically such computations are performed after collecting data and estimating the necessary functions, usually using some type of statistical analysis. Often researchers are forced to approximate key demand and supply variables, such as prices and quantities, with industry averages or aggregate-level data. Issues arise here as to the appropriateness of the chosen data, though more recent uses of retail-level scanner data gathered directly from supermarkets have lessened these concerns. Another issue that has led to debate among researchers is the appropriateness of the functional forms chosen to represent supply and demand.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Crespi, J.M., Sexton, R.J. (2013). US Generic Advertising and Promotion Programs. In: Armbruster, W., Knutson, R. (eds) US Programs Affecting Food and Agricultural Marketing. Natural Resource Management and Policy, vol 38. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-4930-0_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-4930-0_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, New York, NY

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4614-4929-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4614-4930-0

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics