Skip to main content

Policy Analysis

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 3368 Accesses

Part of the book series: Springer Series in Statistics ((SSS,volume 272))

Abstract

The objective of this chapter is to introduce the use of the concentration curves and the Gini methodology in the areas of taxation and progressivity of public expenditures. Most of the literature in these areas considers the case of a representative individual, which means that issues of income distributions are ignored and the only issue that is considered is efficiency. For the Gini methodology and concentration curves to be useful we extend the model to include issues of income distributions as discussed by Diamond (1975) and Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980). We start with a crude characterization of optimal (mostly indirect) taxation which includes the issue of redistribution in addition to efficiency considerations. In a typical model the investigator assumes a social welfare function (SWF) and optimizes it subject to the behaviors of the individuals and to the instruments that are used by the government. Using those ingredients she gets the first-order conditions for optimization so that the relationships among the instruments in an optimal setting are determined (see, as a background, Atkinson &Stiglitz, 1980, pp. 386–393). Note that by assuming the existence of an SWF, the issues of horizontal equity and of comparisons of utilities of households with different structures are skipped because the mere existence of an SWF implies that one knows how to rank individuals according to economic well-being.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Mayshar and Yitzhaki (1996) extend the approach so that “economic well-being” can be affected by two parameters—ability and needs. Then, the investigator should be able to agree that given ability, the higher the needs the lower the well-being of the household, and given needs, the higher the ability the higher is its well-being. This kind of extension is useful for handling family size (needs increase with the number of children but one does not want to commit himself to a specific magnitude) or rural–urban distinctions (e.g., rural populations need less income to achieve a certain level of well-being than urban populations (Ravallion, 1993, p. 31)). There are some technical requirements for this extension to hold. This and other types of extensions are beyond the scope of this book.

  2. 2.

    One can derive this relationship under two alternative sets of assumptions: (a) the household is a utility maximizer and by Roy’s identity \( \partial {{\rm{v}}^{\rm{h}}}\left( {} \right){/}\partial {{\rm{t}}_{\rm{i}}} = - {{\uplambda }^{\rm{h}}}{\rm{x}}_{\rm{i}}^{\rm{h}} \), where v is the indirect utility function and \( \lambda \) is the marginal utility of income. The marginal benefit is the income equivalent of the change caused by the reform, or (b) no optimization is carried out by the household and we are only interested in a Slutsky’s compensation to the household.

  3. 3.

    This distinguishes Pareto improving reform from DI reform. Under Pareto improving reform all MBh, h = 1,..,H must be nonnegative.

  4. 4.

    An instrument is a parameter that the government can change.

  5. 5.

    For the derivation of (14.19) see Lerman and Yitzhaki (1985) or Stark, Taylor, and Yitzhaki (1986).

  6. 6.

    To see this note that E = PQ, where P is price and Q is quantity. Let Y be income then \( \Delta E \approx P\Delta Q + Q\Delta P \). Hence \( {\frac{{\Delta E}}{{\Delta Y}}} {\frac{E}{Y}} \approx \frac{{\Delta Q}}{{\Delta Y}} {\frac{Y}{Q}} + \frac{{\Delta P}}{{\Delta Y}} {\frac{Y}{P}}. \)

  7. 7.

    To see the amount of efficiency gain, add up the MECFs multiplied by the revenue changes: 1.0 × 1.083 − 1.035 × 1.083 + 0.035 × 2.70 = 0.008.

References

  • Atkinson, A. B., & Stiglitz, J. (1980). Lectures on public economics. London: McGraw-Hill.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Bibi, S., & Duclos, J.-Y. (2007). Poverty-decreasing indirect tax reforms: Evidence from Tunisia. International Taxation and Public Finance, 14, 165–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Central Bureau of Statistics of Indonesia (1990). National social Economic Survey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corlett, W. J., & Hague, D. C. (1953). Complementarity and the excess burden of taxation. Review of Economic Studies, 21, 21–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A. (1975). A many-person Ramsey tax rule. Journal of Public Economics, 4, 335–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duclos, J.-Y., & Makdissi, P. (2004). Restricted and unrestricted dominance for welfare, inequality and poverty ordering. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 6(1), 145–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duclos, J.-Y., Makdissi, P., & Wodon, Q. (2005). Poverty-reducing tax reforms with heterogeneous agents. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 7(1), 107–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duclos, J.-Y., Makdissi, P., & Wodon, Q. (2008). Socially improving tax-reforms. International Economic Review, 49(4 (November)), 1505–1537.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. S. (1972). Distributional equity and the optimal structure of public spending. American Economic Review, 62(1 (March)), 32–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert, P., & Yitzhaki, S. (1995). Equity, equality and welfare. European Economic Review, 39, 674–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerman, R. I., & Yitzhaki, S. (1985). Income inequality effects by income source: A new approach and application to the U.S. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67, 151–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerman, R. I., & Yitzhaki, S. (1994). The effect of marginal changes in income sources on U.S. income Inequality. Public Finance Quarterly, 22(4), 403–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, J. D. (1993). Energy pricing, tax policy, and the environment in Indonesia. Development discussion paper no. 455. Harvard Institute for International Development. Cambridge, MA, June.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundin, D. (2). Welfare-improving carbon dioxide tax reform taking externality and location into account. International Tax and Public Finance, 8, 815–835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makdissi, P., & Mussard, S. (2008). Analyzing the impact of indirect tax reforms on rank-dependent social welfare functions: A positional dominance approach. Social Choice and Welfare, 30, 385–399.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Mayshar, J., & Yitzhaki, S. (1995). Dalton-improving indirect tax reforms. American Economic Review, 85(4 (September)), 793–808.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayshar, J., & Yitzhaki, S. (1996). Dalton-improving indirect tax reform II—With differences in needs and ability. Journal of Public Economics, 62(3 (November)), 399–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion, M. (1993). Poverty comparisons. Switzerland/Philadelphia, PA: Chur/Harwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod, J., & Yitzhaki, S. (2). Integrating expenditure and tax decisions: The marginal cost of funds and the marginal benefit of projects. National Tax Journal, 65(2 (June)), 189–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stark, O., Taylor, J. E., & Yitzhaki, S. (1986). Remittances and inequality. Economic Journal, 96(September), 722–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wodon, Q., & Yitzhaki, S. (2002b). Inequality and social welfare. In Klugman, J. (Ed.), Poverty reduction strategy papers sourcebook. Washington, DC: The World Bank. http://povlibrary.worldbank.org/files/11044_chap2.pdf.

  • Yitzhaki, S. (1982c). A tax programming model. Journal of Public Economics, 19, 107–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yitzhaki, S. (1994b). On the progressivity of commodity taxation. In W. Eichhorn (Ed.), Models and measurement of welfare and inequality (pp. 448–465). Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Yitzhaki, S., & Lewis, J. (1996). Guidelines on searching for Dalton-improving tax reforms: Illustrations with data from Indonesia. The World Bank Economic Review, 10(3), 541–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, H. (1920). The measurement of the inequality of income. Economic Journal, 30, 348–361 [Reprinted in the appendix to his the inequality of income. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul LTD.].

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Yitzhaki, S., Schechtman, E. (2013). Policy Analysis. In: The Gini Methodology. Springer Series in Statistics, vol 272. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-4720-7_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics