Skip to main content

Price Discrimination and Other Marketing Strategies

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover New Perspectives on Industrial Organization

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 4941 Accesses

Abstract

A perfectly competitive firm has no need for marketing. Price and firm demand are exogenously determined, making price competition impossible. Expensive advertising campaigns are unprofitable because advertising can have no effect on firm demand. The only thing the firm must decide is how much output to produce and bring to market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Formally, price discrimination does not exist for products i and j that are of like quality when p i /mc i  = p j /mc j , even if p i  ≠ p j .

  2. 2.

    Consumer surplus is 50(120 − 70)/2, producer surplus is 50(70 − 20), and total surplus is consumer surplus plus producer surplus.

  3. 3.

    In this case, consumer surplus is 100(120 − 20)/2.

  4. 4.

    More formally, the firm’s total revenue of producing q′ can be described by an integral, which sums up the demand price when q ranges from 0 to q′. Formally, this can be written as \( \int_{{q = 0}}^{{q^{\prime}}} {D(q^{\prime})dq} \). Total cost is TC(q′). The firm’s problem is to maximize its profit with respect to output, where profit is π = \( \mathop{\int }\nolimits D(q)dq - {\hbox{TC}}(q) \). Because the derivative of \( \mathop{\int }\nolimits D(q)dq \) is D(q), the first-order condition is D(q) − MC = 0. That is, the profit-maximizing level of output occurs where D(q) = MC.

  5. 5.

    The price does not remain constant, and this causes a consumer’s budget line to be nonlinear. See Varian (2010, 28–29) for further discussion.

  6. 6.

    The process of identifying the optimal pricing scheme is rather tedious, so we will not discuss it here. For a more detailed discussion, see Varian (2010, Chap. 25).

  7. 7.

    That is, π * = (p − AC)Q = (7 − 2)5.

  8. 8.

    In this case, π * = (p − AC)Q = (5.5 − 2)7 = 24.5.

  9. 9.

    This need not always be the case, however. We will see in a review question at the end of the chapter that some children will enter the resort when marginal cost is sufficiently low.

  10. 10.

    The problem is more complicated when marginal cost is not a constant, because greater sales in one market causes marginal costs to change overall. For further discussion, see Pindyck and Rubenfeld (2009, Chap. 11).

  11. 11.

    This assumes that the utility of adults is not raised or lowered by having children present.

  12. 12.

    Recall that the price elasticity of demand (η) is the absolute value of the slope of demand (∂Q/∂p) times the equilibrium price divided by the equilibrium quantity. For both adults and children, ∂Q/∂p = –1. For adults, p * = 7, Q * = 5, and η A = 1.4. For children, p * = 4, Q * = 2, and η C = 2.

  13. 13.

    For a more recent study of the use of coupons in the breakfast cereal industry, see Nevo and Wolfram (2002).

  14. 14.

    Of course, children could be priced out of the market if costs are sufficiently high.

  15. 15.

    For a formal discussion, see Schmalensee (1981) and Shih et al. (1988).

  16. 16.

    In addition, firms may use price discrimination to reduce competition, an issue we take up in Chap. 20.

  17. 17.

    For further discussion, see Paul (2010). You can see a Mad TV performance of this song on YouTube, http://www.youtube.com, accessed May 23, 2010.

  18. 18.

    For a list of companies that offer free samples, see the Shop4Freebies Web site at http://www.shop4freebies.com, accessed July 10, 2011.

  19. 19.

    In the case of rational addiction, as in Becker and Murphy (1988), consumers consider both the past and the future. Behavioral economics suggests that at least some consumers are myopic, however (e.g., Akerlof and Dickens, 1982).

  20. 20.

    To read more about the theory of peak-load pricing, see Crew et al. (1995).

  21. 21.

    These examples derive from Deneckere and McAfee (1996), McAfee (2007), and Dixit and Nalebuff (2008).

  22. 22.

    The first to formally address this idea was Oi (1971), who was inspired by the two-part pricing strategy used at Disneyland in the 1960s. Disneyland and Disneyworld only charge a fixed entry fee today, however, perhaps to lower consumer time spent waiting in line.

  23. 23.

    This discussion also holds for many consumers with identical demand functions.

  24. 24.

    You can verify this by comparing profits for different prices and fixed fees.

  25. 25.

    This assumes that fee discrimination is uneconomic (i.e., the firm cannot charge a higher fee to the high-valuation consumer).

  26. 26.

    For a more detailed discussion, see Oi (1971) and Bernheim and Whinston (2008, Chap. 18).

  27. 27.

    This will cost $39.89 ($29.99 + $0.45 · 22), whereas all other plans will cost $39.99.

  28. 28.

    This information is available at http://www.consumerreports.org, accessed December 22, 2009.

  29. 29.

    According to Naughton (2002), Wal-Mart is the “Everyday Low Price” king among discount stores.

  30. 30.

    A similar argument would apply to consumers. If Sears tires were always on sale on the first week of the month, this information would become common knowledge and consumers would purchase tires only during sale periods.

  31. 31.

    Federal Trade Commission, 277, 281 (1957). For further discussion of this case, see V. Tremblay and C. Tremblay (2005).

  32. 32.

    For a more complete discussion of a generalized war of attrition, see Bulow and Klemperer (1999).

  33. 33.

    For a more complete discussion of the war of attrition in brewing, see V. Tremblay and C. Tremblay (2007) and Iwasaki et al. (2008). This discussion ignores the growth in numbers of the microbreweries, as they produce darker lagers and ales that compete with imports more than the light lagers produce by the mass-producing brewers. See V. Tremblay and C. Tremblay (2005) for more discussion of the microbrewery movement.

  34. 34.

    In these examples, firms do not engage in blatant deception and dishonesty. Instead, their primary goal is to exploit our inherent weaknesses. See Lindsey-Mullikin and Petty (2011) for a list of firm pricing strategies and rewards promises that are more deceptive in nature. Deception and puffing, especially associated with advertising, will be discussed in more detail in later chapters.

  35. 35.

    Another concern is that if firm 1 runs negative ads about firm 2, firm 2 will run negative ads about firm 1, which is bad for the industry as a whole. For further discussion of these issues, see Wilson (1976), McAfee (2002, 114), and del Barrio-Garcia and Luque-Martinez (2003).

  36. 36.

    For example, would you spend an hour of your time in exchange for a free package of gum, a 100% discount?

  37. 37.

    For a more complete discussion, see Stigler (1968, Chap. 15).

  38. 38.

    Note that any other price option will earn the firm less profit. For example, sales are 0 at a price above 100. At a price of 39, 2 units will be sold for a profit of 78.

  39. 39.

    For a discussion of additional cases where bundling increases firm profits, besides when consumers have negatively correlated demand functions, see McAfee et al. (1989).

  40. 40.

    International Business Machines Corp. v. U.S., 298 U.S. 131, 139-140 (1936).

  41. 41.

    For a review of the evidence, see Camerer and Lovallo (1999), Rabin and Schrag (1999), Camerer et al. (2005), and Grubb (2009).

  42. 42.

    In a Consumer Reports (2011a, b) survey, 20% of consumers received an unexpected charge on their cell phone bill.

  43. 43.

    This begs the question of how firms know that many consumers underestimate their variance of use. Because a considerable amount of money is at stake, cell phone companies hire economists to estimate consumer demand. They have also learned from trial and error.

  44. 44.

    See http://www.oreck.com/customer-service/30-day-risk-free-trial.cfm, accessed May 27, 2010.

References

  • Akerlof GA, Dickens WT (1982) The economic consequences of cognitive dissonance. Am Econ Rev 72(3):307–319

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell LS, Bernheim BD (1996) Veblen effects in a theory of conspicuous consumption. Am Econ Rev 86(3):349–373

    Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein S, Ross NL (1994) Competition and price dispersion in the U.S. airline industry. J Polit Econ 104(4):653–683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breit W, Elzinga KG (1974) Product differentiation and institutionalism: new shadows on old terrain. J Econ Iss 5(4):813–826

    Google Scholar 

  • Bulow J, Klemperer P (1999) The generalized war of attrition. Am Econ Rev 89:439–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C (1997) Progress in behavioral game theory. J Econ Perspect 11:167–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Loewenstein G, Prelec D (2005) Neuroeconomics: how neuroscience can inform economics. J Econ Lit 43:9–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Lovallo D (1999) Overconfidence and excess entry: an experimental approach. Am Econ Rev 89(1):306–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Consumer Reports (2011a) Stop phone-bill shock. August 2011, 6

    Google Scholar 

  • Consumer Reports (2011b) Chevrolet Volt. October 2011, 58–60

    Google Scholar 

  • Crew MA, Fernando CS, Kleindorfer PR (1995) The theory of peak-load pricing: a survey. J Regul Econ 8:215–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Barrio-Garcia S, Luque-Martinez T (2003) Modeling consumer response to differing levels of comparative advertising. Eur J Market 37:256–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Nalebuff BJ (2008) The art of strategy: a game theorist’s guide to success in business and life. W. W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards CD (1944) Economic and political aspects of international cartels, U.S. Senate, Subcommittee on War Mobilization of the Committee on Military Affairs, 78th Congress, Second Session

    Google Scholar 

  • Green EJ, Porter RH (1984) Noncooperative collusion under imperfect price information. Econometrica 52(1):87–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubb MD (2009) Selling to overconfident consumers. Am Econ Rev 99(5):1770–1807

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iwasaki N, Seldon BJ, Tremblay VJ (2008) Brewing wars of attrition for profit and concentration. Rev Ind Organ 33:263–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAfee RP (2002) Competitive solutions: the strategist’s toolkit. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • McAfee RP (2007) “Pricing damaged goods,” Economics: the open access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 1, 2007. http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2007-1

  • McAfee RP, McMillan J, Whinston MA (1989) Multi-product monopoly, commodity bundling, and correlation of values. Quart J Econ 103:371–383

    Google Scholar 

  • Narasimhan C (1984) A price discrimination theory of coupons. Market Sci, Spring 1984

    Google Scholar 

  • Nash J (1950) Equilibrium points in n-Person games. Proc Natl Acad Sci 36:48–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nevo A, Wolfram C (2002) Prices and coupons for breakfast cereal. Rand J Econ 33:319–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oi W (1971) A Disneyland dilemma: two-part tariffs for a Mickey Mouse monopoly. Quart J Econ 85:77–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paul I (2010) Five ways early adopters have been screwed. PCWorld, February 9, 2010, at http://www.pcworld.com/article/188889/five_ways_early_adopters_have_been_screwed.html, accessed may 23, 2010

  • Pindyck RS, Rubenfield DL (2009) Microeconomics. Pearson Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin M, Schrag JL (1999) First impressions matter: a model of confirmatory bias. Quart J Econ 114(1):37–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers EM (1962) Diffusion of innovations. Free Press, Glencoe

    Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg JJ, Saloner G (1986) A supergame-theoretic model of price wars during booms. Am Econ Rev 76(3):390–407

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee R (1981) Output and welfare implications of monopolistic third-degree price discrimination. Am Econ Rev 71:242–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Shih J, Mai C, Liu J (1988) A general analysis of the output effect under third-degree price discrimination. Econ J 98:149–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiller RJ (2005) Irrational exuberance. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Stavins J (2001) Price discrimination in the airline market: the effect of market concentration. Rev Econ Stat 83(1)

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1968) The organization of industry. Richard D. Irwin, Homewood, IL

    Google Scholar 

  • Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (2005) The U.S. brewing industry: data and economic analysis. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (2007) Brewing: games firms play. In: Tremblay CH, Tremblay VJ (eds) Industry and firm studies. ME Sharpe, Armonk, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (1980) A model of sales. Am Econ Rev 70:651–659

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (2010) Intermediate microeconomics: a modern approach. W.W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen T (1899) The theory of the leisure class. Macmillan

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein ND (1980) Unrealistic optimism about future life events. J Pers Soc Psychol 39(5):806–820

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson RD (1976) An empirical evaluation of comparative advertising messages. Adv Consum Res 3:53–57

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tremblay, V.J., Tremblay, C.H. (2012). Price Discrimination and Other Marketing Strategies. In: New Perspectives on Industrial Organization. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-3241-8_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics