Skip to main content

A Consumption Theory with Competitive Markets for Work-in-Household

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1339 Accesses

Abstract

Earlier home production models of consumption have considered households as one coordinated decision-making unit. Instead, this chapter assumes that individuals who are either married or considering marriage continue to be independent decision-makers after they form couples. In light of the concepts of Work-In-Household (WiHo, a particular type of household production benefiting a spouse) and its price (see Chap. 2), and assuming that traditional gender roles prevail, an analysis of markets where women are WiHo-workers and men WiHo-users leads to novel implications for the study of consumption. It follows from the model that there will be a gender gap in the price elasticity of commercial goods that could be home-produced. This helps explain, among other implications, why women may pay more for dry-cleaning than men. Sex ratio effects on consumption are also predicted: for example, it is predicted that in countries with more emigration of men than women, women will be expected to make higher contributions to newlyweds’ costs of housing. It is also shown how compensating differentials in marriage associated with various types of husband/wife matches could also be associated with different consumption patterns. For instance, relative to women married to men who are close to their own age, women married to considerably older men are predicted to have relatively more control over the use of the couple’s income and they may consume more goods that benefit them personally.

I dedicate this chapter to the late H. Gregg-Lewis for it uses techniques he taught in a graduate labor economics course I took at the University of Chicago in 1973–1974 (This chapter is adapted from Grossbard-Shechtman Shoshana. 2003. A consumer theory with competitive markets for work in marriage. Journal of Socio-Economics 31(6):609–645. http://www-rohan.sdsu.edu/faculty/sgs/documents/consumption_paper_JSE2003.pdf. I thank Marina Adshade, George Davis, and Joni Hersch for helpful comments).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Grossman (1972) is a consumption model to the extent that it models household demand for health care services.

  2. 2.

    Z is called a “commodity,” following Becker (1965).

  3. 3.

    Oana Tocoian points out that restaurants may also price discriminate in terms of spousal WiHo availability when they only issue coupons that cannot be used by single customers (free entree with purchase of another, dinner for two for X dollars, etc.).

  4. 4.

    I thank Victoria Vernon for calculating these numbers specially for this book.

  5. 5.

    Barbara Bergmann, personal communication. Her observation is based on data she collected with the help of students in the Washington, DC area. Some states, including California, have banned gender-based price differentials in dry-cleaning services (see also Cohen 1999).

  6. 6.

    Women, thus, seem to get penalized twice by men’s unwillingness to do their wives’ laundry. First, women rarely have the option of relying on that form of help in the home. Second, they may get charged more for commercial services if they go to the cleaners, as a result of their lower elasticity of demand which in turn is partially explained by the low levels of WiHo that men supply.

  7. 7.

    Again, this assumes that sellers can take advantage of buyers’ less elastic demand.

  8. 8.

    See Davis (2014) for a review of FAH versus FAFH and the implications for nutrition and Health.

  9. 9.

    Prices may be stable if supply side outpaced the demand side, assuming nothing else on the demand side changed.

  10. 10.

    The demand for frozen dinners aimed at children is expected to be very price-elastic as both mothers and fathers may possibly substitute for their children’s cooking activities.

  11. 11.

    Testing for this will be very complicated, for there may also be some gender differences in the symbolic value of a car. Also, it has been documented that relative to men women are worse at bargaining prices down.

  12. 12.

    A spouse’s time is likely to be a better substitute for the time of professional services than is the case with own time.

  13. 13.

    I have borrowed the term “role reboot” from .

  14. 14.

    John Treble contributed this citation.

  15. 15.

    A more ambitious treatment of WiHo and shared consumption commodities is found in my WOC model in Grossbard-Shechtman (2003a).

  16. 16.

    Another factor affecting the disutility of spousal labor is whether small amounts of WiHo are being supplied. This idea can also be found in Blau et al. (1998, Ch. 3). Also, see Amy Wax (1998).

  17. 17.

    I thank Marina Adshade (who can be followed @dollarsandsex) for this insight.

  18. 18.

    I thank Marina Adshade for this insight.

  19. 19.

    The model also leads to a demand for WiHo contributed by a spouse, hj, and a supply of labor li. The model could be extended to include the derivation of a supply of own WiHo, hj.

References

  • Allgeier, E. R., and M. W. Wiederman. 1991. Love and mate selection in the 1990s. Free Inquiry 11:25–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Apps, P., and R. Rees. 1997. Collective labor supply and household production. Journal of Political Economy 105:178–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. 1965. A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal 75:493–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. 1973. A theory of marriage: Part I. Journal of Political Economy 81:813–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. 1974a. A theory of marriage: Part II. Journal of Political Economy 82:S11–S26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. 1974b. A theory of social interactions. Journal of Political Economy 82 (6): 1063–1093.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bishai, D., and S. Grossbard. 2010. Far above rubies: The association between bride price and extramarital sexual relations in Uganda. Journal of Population Economics 23 (4): 1177–1188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, F. D., M. A. Ferber, and A. E. Winkler. 1998. The economics of women, men, and work. 3rd ed. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonke, J. 2015. Pooling of income and sharing of consumption within households. Review of Economics of the Household 13 (1). (Forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronfenbrenner, M. 1971. A note on the economics of the marriage market. Journal of Political Economy 79:1424–1425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, P. H. 2009. Dowry and intrahousehold bargaining: Evidence from China. Journal of Human Resources 44 (1): 25–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., F. Bourguignon, C. Pierre-Andre, and V. Lechene. 1994. Incomes and outcomes: A structural model of intra-household allocation. Journal of Political Economy 102 (6): 1067–1096.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaloupka, F. J., and R. L. Pacula. 1998. An examination of gender and race differences in youth smoking responsiveness to price and tobacco control policies. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 6541, April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Z., and F. Woolley. 2001. A Cournot – Nash model of family decision making. The Economic Journal 111 (474): 722–748.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. 1988. Rational household labor supply. Econometrica 56:63–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. 1992. Collective labor supply and welfare. Journal of Political Economy 100:437–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. 1997. Introducing household production in collective models of labor supply. Journal of Political Economy 105:191–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A, B. Fortin and G. Lacroix 1998. Household labor supply, sharing rule and the marriage market. Ms., University of Chicago, May.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christian, T., and I. Rashad. 2009. Trends in US food prices, 1950–2007. Economics & Human Biology 7 (1): 113–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, R. 1999. Cut-rate rationale. The Ethicist Column, New York Times Magazine, 18. July, p. 20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, G. C. 2014. Food at home production and consumption: Implications for nutrition quality and policy. Review of Economics of the Household 12 (3): 565–588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Folbre, Nancy. 1994. Who pays for the kids? Gender and the structures of constraint. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Friedan, Betty. 1963. The feminine mystique. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gimenez-Nadal, J. I., and A. Sevilla-Sanz. 2012. Trends in time allocation: A cross-country analysis. European Economic Review 56 (6): 1338–1359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, Claudia. 1988. Marriage bars: Discrimination against married women workers, 1920’s to 1950’s. NBER Paper 2747, Oct.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, Claudia. 1990. Understanding the gender gap. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., A. Seshadri, and M. Yorukoglu. 2005. Engines of liberation. Review of Economic Studies 72 (1): 109–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griskevicius, V., J. M. Tybur, J. M. Ackerman, A. W. Delton, T. E. Robertson, and A. E. White. 2012. The financial consequences of too many men: Sex ratio effects on saving, borrowing, and spending. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 102 (1): 69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gronau, Reuben. 1977. Leisure, home production, and work—The theory of the allocation of time revisited. Journal of Political Economy 85:1099–1124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, Amyra. 1984. A theory of allocation of time in markets for labor and marriage. Economic Journal 94:863–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, Shoshana. 1993. On the economics of marriage. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, Shoshana. 2003a. A consumer theory with competitive markets for work in marriage. Journal of Socio-Economics 31 (6): 609–645.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, Shoshana. 2003b. Marriage and the economy. In Marriage and the economy: Theory and evidence from advanced industrial societies, ed. S Grossbard-Shechtman. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Michael. 1972. On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. Journal of Political Economy 80 (2): 223–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heer, D. M., and A. Grossbard-Shechtman. 1981. The impact of the female marriage squeeze and the contraceptive revolution on sex roles and the women’s liberation movement in the United States, 1960 to 1975. Journal of Marriage and the Family 43:49–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, Joy. 1985. Marriage in a recently industrialized society: Japan. In Contemporary marriage: Comparative perspectives on a changing institution, ed. K. Davis and A. Grossbard-Shechtman. New York: Russell Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hersch, Joni. 2003. Marriage and household production. In Marriage and the economy, ed. S. Grossbard-Shechtman. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hersch, Joni. 2009. Home production and wages: Evidence from the American time use survey. Review of Economics of the Household 7:159–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hersch, J., and L. S. Stratton. 2000. Household specialization and the male marriage wage premium. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 54:78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kephart, W. M. 1967. Some correlates of romantic love. Journal of Marriage and the Family 29:470–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kureishi, Wataru, and Midori Wakabayashi. 2013. What motivates single women to save? The case of Japan. Review of Economics of the Household 11:681–704.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laferrere, Anne. 2001. Marriage settlements. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 103: 485–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, K. J. 1966. A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy 74:132–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, Jungmin, and Mark Pocock. 2007. Intrahousehold allocation of household finances. Review of Economics of the Household 5 (1): 41–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S., and R. A. Pollak. 1993. Separate sphere bargaining and the marriage market. Journal of Political Economy 101:988–1010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S., R. A. Pollak, and T. J. Wales. 1997. Do husbands and wives pool their resources? Evidence from the U.K. child benefit. Journal of Human Resources 32:463–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McElroy, M. B. 1990. The empirical content of Nash-Bargained household behavior. Journal of Human Resources 25:559–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McElroy, M. B., and M. J. Horney. 1981. Nash bargained household decisions: Toward a generalization of the theory of demand. International Economic Review 22:333–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, Jacob. 1962. Labor force participation of married women: A study of labor supply. In Aspects of labor economics, ed. H. Gregg Lewis. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pahl, Jan. 1983. The allocation of money and the structuring of inequality within marriage. Sociological Review 13 (2): 237–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, Maria. 2015. How do sex ratios in China influence marriage decisions and intra-household resource allocation? Review of Economics of the Household. http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11150-014-9262-9. (Forthcoming)

  • Rao, V. 1993. The rising price of husbands: A hedonic analysis of dowry increases in rural India. Journal of Political Economy 101 (4): 666–677.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, R. J. 2014. Eleanor Roosevelt talks to John F. Kennedy about the status of women in society. The Atlantic Feb. 19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., and M. A. Oliveira Sotomayor. 1990. Two-matching: A study in game-theoretic modeling and analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sevilla-Sanz, A., J. I. Gimenez-Nadal, and C. Fernandez. 2010. Gender roles and the division of unpaid work in Spanish households. Feminist Economics 16 (4): 137–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sterne, Laurence. 1760. The life and opinions of Tristram Shandy, Gentleman. U.K.: Ann Ward.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, George. 1946. Domestic servants in the United States, 1900–1940. Occasional Paper No. 24, National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, Duncan. 1990. Intra-household resource allocation: An inferential approach. Journal of Human Resources 25:635–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wax, Amy L. 1998. Bargaining in the shadow of the market: Is there a future for egalitarian marriage? Virginia Law Review 84 (4): 509–672.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woolley, Frances. 2003. Marriage and control over money. In Marriage and the economy, ed. S. Grossbard-Shechtman. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shoshana Grossbard .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Grossbard, S. (2015). A Consumption Theory with Competitive Markets for Work-in-Household. In: The Marriage Motive: A Price Theory of Marriage. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-1623-4_10

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-1623-4_10

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, New York, NY

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4614-1622-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4614-1623-4

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics