Skip to main content

Measuring the Performance of Life-Cycle Asset Allocation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Consumer Knowledge and Financial Decisions

Part of the book series: International Series on Consumer Science ((ISCS))

  • 1334 Accesses

Abstract

The United States’ aging population puts pressure on the pension system. Pension reforms consider putting more weight on individually managed retirement savings. Public policy and financial planners, being concerned with households making wise asset allocation decisions, need measures to evaluate individual investment performance. In this chapter, we illustrate two measures for the evaluation of asset allocation performance: a preference-free measure and a preference-based measure. We compare the suitability of both measures along several dimensions. The choice of the measure turns out to be important for the ranking of the performance of asset allocation decisions, and thus great care should be taken when deciding on public policy aimed at improving asset allocation behavior. Furthermore, we show that some classical rules of thumb used to mimic optimal life-cycle asset allocation strategies do not necessarily improve investment performance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Further research on these and other important aspects regarding rationality of individual wealth accumulations (like choosing an optimal retirement age) is surveyed in Burtless (2010).

  2. 2.

    All coefficients, except the dummy variables for Education (High) and Occupation (Retired) (both insignificant), are significant at the 1% level.

  3. 3.

    We ran our analysis for savings ratios of 70 and 90%. The assumption on the savings ratio is ­critical when calculating expected wealth values. For comparing different households’ performance, however, our results are robust to this assumption. That means the order of different households in their performance does not change.

  4. 4.

    In particular, we use an inter-temporally-separable utility function and impose borrowing and short-selling constraints. We allow for a maximum age of the household of 100 years and account for uncertain lifetime. With again a starting age of 50 years, the utility function used is mathematically defined as: \( U(C)={\displaystyle \sum _{t=0}^{100-50}{\delta }^{t}{p}_{t+1}{U}_{t}\left({C}_{t}\right)}\), where C is consumption. The one-period utility function U t has constant relative risk aversion of 2, and δ, the subjective discount factor (the measure of the household’s time preference) is set to 0.97. The probability of a household to survive from period 0 at least another t years, p t , is calibrated according to the United States Life Tables 2003 (Arias, 2006). In case the household dies, utility is set to zero, which implies absence of bequest motives.

  5. 5.

    Formally, one solves V *0 W 0,  L 0)  =  V 0 act W 0  +  ΔW 0,  L 0) for ΔW 0.

  6. 6.

    For a further discussion of such approaches, see Kotlikoff (2008).

  7. 7.

    Only under more rigorous assumptions, such models can be solved analytically (see, e.g., Lachance, 2010).

  8. 8.

    This is demonstrated, for example, by the commercially available software ESPlanner (Kotlikoff, 2008).

  9. 9.

    Preference-free evaluations of such funds are contained, for example, in Lewis (2008).

References

  • Arias, E. (2006). United States life tables 2003. National Vital Statistics Report, 54, 1–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagliano, F. C., Fugazza, C., & Nicodano, G. (2010). Pension funds, life-cycle asset allocation and performance evaluation. In R. Hinz, H. P. Rudolph, P. Antolin, & J. Yermo (Eds.), Evaluating the financial performance of mutual funds (pp. 159–201). World Bank: Washington.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bodie, Z., & Treussard, J. (2007). Making investment choices as simple as possible, but not simpler. Financial Analysts Journal, 63, 42–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucks, B. R., Kennickell, A. B., & Moore, K. B. (2006, February). Recent changes in U.S. family finance: Evidence from the 2001 and 2004 Survey of Consumer Finance. Federal Reserve Bulletin, 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burtless, G. (2010). Do workers prepare rationally for retirement? In A. Drolet, N. Schwarz, & C. Yoon (Eds.), The aging consumer: Perspectives from psychology and economics (pp. 103–130). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvet, L. E., Campbell, J. Y., & Sodini, P. (2007). Down or out: Assessing the welfare costs of household investment mistakes. The Journal of Political Economy, 115, 707–747.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, C. D., & Samwick, A. A. (1997). The nature of precautionary wealth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 40, 41–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cocco, J. F., Gomes, F. J., & Maenhout, P. J. (2005). Consumption and portfolio choice over the life-cycle. The Review of Financial Studies, 18, 491–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curcuru, S., Heaton, J., Lucas, D., & Moore, D. (2010). Heterogeneity and portfolio choice: Theory and evidence. In Y. Ait-Sahalia & L. P. Hansen (Eds.), Handbook of financial econometrics (pp. 337–382). Oxford: North Holland.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • John Hancock Financial Services. (2002). Eighth annual defined contribution survey. Boston, MA: John Hancock Financial Services.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kotlikoff, L. J. (2008). Economics’ approach to financial planning. The Journal of Financial Planning, 21, 42–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachance, M. (2010). Optimal onset and exhaustion of retirement savings in a life-cycle model. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance (forthcoming) doi:10.1017/S1474747210000284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, N. D. (2008). Making ends meet: Target date investment funds and retirement wealth creation. Pensions, 13, 130–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi, A., & Mitchell, O. (2007). Financial literacy and retirement preparedness: Evidence and implications for financial education. Business Economics, 42, 35–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C., & Samuelson, P. A. (1974). Fallacy of the log-normal approximation to optimal portfolio decision-making over many periods. Journal of Financial Economics, 1, 67–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Post, T., GrĂĽndl, H., Schmit, J. T., & Zimmer, A. (2010). The impact of investment behavior for individual welfare. working paper, Maastricht University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J., Rauh, J., Venti, S., & Wise, D. (2007). Defined contribution plans, defined benefit plans, and the accumulation of retirement wealth. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 2062–2086.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Reno, V. P., & Lavery, J. (2007). Social security and retirement income adequacy. Social Security Brief No. 25. Washington, DC: National Academy of Social Insurance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1937). A note on measurement of utility. The Review of Economic Studies, 4, 155–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scholz, J. K., Seshadri, A., & Khitatrakun, S. (2006). Are Americans saving “optimally” for retirement? The Journal of Political Economy, 114, 607–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spitzer, J. J., & Singh, S. (2012). Target-date mutual funds. In D. J. Lamdin (Ed.), Consumer knowledge and financial decisions. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, J. (2007). Are you sure you’re saving enough for retirement? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21, 59–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viceira, L. M. (2009). Life cycle funds. In A. Lusardi (Ed.), Overcoming the saving slump: How to increase the effectiveness of financial education and saving programs (pp. 140–177). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Post .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Post, T., Schmit, J.T. (2011). Measuring the Performance of Life-Cycle Asset Allocation. In: Lamdin, D. (eds) Consumer Knowledge and Financial Decisions. International Series on Consumer Science. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-0475-0_18

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics