Skip to main content

Why Don’t Veto Players Use Their Power?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Reform Processes and Policy Change

Part of the book series: Studies in Public Choice ((SIPC,volume 16))

  • 1459 Accesses

Abstract

Why do the member states with veto power usually support a policy change proposed by a Commission initiative when their own position is located closer to the status quo? Why do we frequently witness consensus in the Council and rarely observe a rejection of Commission initiatives even after additional veto players, such as new member states or the European Parliament, have increased the constraints on policy change by legislative decision making in the European Union (EU)? To answer these questions, this study investigates the voting preferences and logrolling opportunities of the member states on 48 Commission proposals. We find that models that derive the voting preferences from each Commission initiative are scarcely able to explain the consensus in the Council. One reason is that the Commission attempts to avoid a divided Council by initiating proposals for which member states favour a policy change in the same direction. When member states still dispute the size of policy change, we show that they can find a solution by mutually benefiting from logrolling across proposals that either belong to the same policy domain or are negotiated during the same period. Hence, inter-temporal and domain-specific logrolling can provide a powerful explanation for consensus even in a contested Council.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The data set for the empirical analysis in this article can be found at http://eup.sagepub.com/supplemental. By voting preferences, we mean the relative distance between the status quo and an actor’s ideal position and between the proposed change and his/her ideal position. This preference is measured by the actor’s position in multidimensional policy spaces weighted by his/her relative saliency across dimensions. If the difference between the two distances is negative, the actor is predicted to vote in favour of the status quo; otherwise, he/she supports the proposed change.

  2. 2.

    In the period under study, 62 out of 87 total votes are needed for the adoption of a Commission proposal under the qualified majority rule in the Council. The Treaty of Amsterdam provided Germany, Italy, France and the United Kingdom with ten votes, Spain with eight votes, Austria, Belgium, Greece, the Netherlands, Portugal and Sweden with four votes and Denmark, Ireland and Finland with three votes, while Luxembourg has only two votes.

  3. 3.

    To guarantee some public awareness and controversy, proposals have been selected for the study only if they had been mentioned in the Agence Europe, a news service for EU affairs, and revealed at least a minimum level of conflict in the interviews (Thomson et al. 2006).

  4. 4.

    In a recent study, König et al. (2006) checked the reliability of CELEX data using PreLex – another EU legislative database PreLex – and found that more than 90% of all cases correspond across these different sources of information, although PreLex documents the legislative process, CELEX contains legislative events.

  5. 5.

    Comparing the DEU with data on seven cases negotiated in the conciliation committee, they find a surprisingly high similarity regarding the point locations of the EP, the Commission, the status quo, the outcome and the Council pivot. Although most experts were rapporteurs, the DEU experts came primarily from the Council, and although these experts were asked at different points in time, the point location of 15 positions is the same (deviation of 0–5 on a scale ranging from 0 to 100), 13 positions are very close (deviation of 6–25), 4 positions are not comparable owing to missing values and only 3 measures indicate a large deviation (50, 50 and 70). Closer inspection of these three deviating cases reveals that two of them list a slight Council qualified majority position and the minority position is again almost identical with the Council estimate. This suggests that the Council may have introduced the minority position in the bargaining of the conciliation process (König et al. 2007).

  6. 6.

    Note that voting predictions are not affected by voting weights (in contrast to outcome predictions); we therefore do not distinguish between predictions with and without voting weights with respect to voting predictions in the table.

  7. 7.

    In EU legislation, under QMV abstention is de facto a vote against a proposal, whereas under the unanimity rule it supports adoption.

  8. 8.

    This particularly applies in the framework of deterministic models.

References

  • Achen CH (2006) Institutional realism and bargaining models. In: Thomson R, Stokman FN, Achen CH, König T (eds). The European Union decides. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 86–123

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bailer S, Schneider G (2006) Nash versus Schelling? The importance of constraints in legislative bargaining. In: Thomson R, Stokman FN, Achen CH, König T (eds). The European Union decides. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. pp 153–177

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin RE, Francois JF, Portes R, Rodrik D, Szekely IP (1997) The costs and benefits of eastern enlargement: the impact on the EU and Central Europe. Econ Policy 12(24):125–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crombez C (1996) Legislative procedures in the European Community. Br J Polit Sci 26(2): 199–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crombez C (1997) The co-decision procedure in the European Union Legis Stud. Q 22(1):97–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Crombez C (2000) Institutional reform and co-decision in the European Union. Const Polit Econ 11(1):41–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enelow JM, Hinich MJ (1984) The spatial theory of voting: an introduction. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Franchino F (2007) The powers of the union: delegation in the EU. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Franklin MN, Wlezien C (1997) The responsive public – issue salience, policy change, and preferences for European unification. J Theor Polit 9(3):347–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hage F (2007) Committee decision-making in the council of the European Union. Eur Union Polit 8(3):299–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hage F (2008) Who decides in the council of the European Union? J Common Mark Stud 46(3):533–558

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagemann S, de Clerck-Sachsse J (2007) Old rules, new game: decision-making in the council of ministers after the 2004 enlargement. Special Report, Centre for European Policy Studies

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayes-Renshaw F, Aken WV, Wallace H (2006) When and why the EU Council of ministers votes explicitly. J Common Mark Stud 44(1):161–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heisenberg D (2005) The institution of “consensus” in the European Union: formal versus informal decision-making in the Council. Eur J Polit Res 44(1):65–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39 (153):41–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Junge D, König T (2007) What’s wrong with EU spatial analysis? The accuracy and robustness of empirical applications to the interpretation of the legislative process and the specification of preferences. J Theor Polit 19(4):465–487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King G, Honaker J, Joseph A, Scheve K (2001) Analyzing incomplete political science data: an alternative algorithm for multiple imputation. Am Polit Sci Rev 95(1):49–69

    Google Scholar 

  • König T (2007) Divergence or convergence? From ever-growing to ever-slowing European legislative decision making. Eur J Polit Res 46(3):417–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König T, Bräuninger T (2004) Accession and reform of the European Union – a game-theoretical analysis of eastern enlargement and the constitutional reform. Eur Union Polit 5(4):419–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König T, Luetgert B (2009) Troubles with transposition? Explaining trends in member-state notification and the delayed transposition of EU directives Br J Polit Sci 39(1):163–194

    Google Scholar 

  • König T, Pöter M (2001) Examining the EU legislative process. The relative importance of agenda and veto power. Eur Union Polit 2(3):329–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König T, Proksch S-O (2006) A procedural exchange model of EU legislative politics. In: Thomson R, Stokman FN, Achen CH, König T (eds). The European Union decides. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 211–238

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • König T, Finke D, Daimer S (2005) Ignoring the non-ignorables? Missingness and missing positions. Eur Union Polit 6(3):269–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König T, Luetgert B, Dannwolf T (2006) Quantifying European legislative research. Using CELEX and PRELEX in EU legislative studies. Eur Union Polit 7(4):553–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König T, Lindberg B, Lechner S, Pohlmeier W (2007) Bicameral conflict resolution in the European Union: an empirical analysis of conciliation committee bargains. Br J Polit Sci 37(2):281–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis J (2003) Institutional environments and everyday EU decision making: rationalist or constructivist? Comp Polit Stud 36(1/2):97–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mastenbroek E (2003) Surviving the deadline – the transposition of EU directives in the Netherlands. Eur Union Polit 4(4):371–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattila M (2004) Contested decisions – empirical analysis of voting in the EU council of ministers. Eur J Polit Res 43(1):29–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattila M, Lane J-E (2001) Why unanimity in the council? A roll call analysis of council voting. Eur Union Polit 2(1):31–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Napel S, Widgren M (2004) Power measurement as sensitivity analysis. A unified approach. J Theor Polit 16(4):517–538

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole KT (2005) Spatial models of parliamentary voting. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Romer T, Rosenthal H (1978) Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice 33(4):27–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sapir A (2004) An agenda for a growing Europe: the Sapir report. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf FW (2006) The joint-decision trap revisited. J Common Mark Stud 44(4):845–864

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider G, Steunenberg B, Widgren M (2006) Evidence with insight: what models contribute to EU research. In: Thomson R, Stokman FN, Achen CH, König T (eds). The European Union decides. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 299–316

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Selck TJ (2004) The impact of procedure: analyzing European Union legislative decision-making Cuvillier, Gottingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Slapin JB (2006) Who is powerful? Examining preferences and testing sources of bargaining strength at European intergovernmental conferences. Eur Union Polit 7(1):51–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B (1994) Decision making under different institutional arrangements: legislation by the European community. J Inst Theor Econ 150(4):642–669

    Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B (1997) Codecision and its reform: a comparative analysis of decision-making rules in the European Union. In: Steunenberg B, van Vught F (eds). Political institutions and public policy: perspectives on European decision making. Kluwer Academic Publisher, Dortrecht, pp 205–229

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B, Selck TJ (2006) Testing procedural models of EU legislative decision-making. In: Thomson R, Stokman FN, Achen CH, König T (eds). The European Union decides. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 54–85

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sutter M (2000) Fair allocation and re-weighting of votes and voting power in the EU before and after the next enlargement. J Theor Polit 12(4):433–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tallberg J (2004) The power of the presidency: brokerage, efficiency and distribution in EU negotiations. J Common Mark Stud 42(5):999–1022

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson R, Hosli M (2006) Who has power in the EU? The commission, council and parliament in legislative decision-making. J Common Mark Stud 44(2):391–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson R, Stokman F, Achen C König T (eds) (2006) The European Union decides. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Tollison RD, Willett TD (1979) An economic theory of mutually advantageous issue linkage in international negotiations. Int Organ 33(4):425–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G (1994) The power of the European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter. Am Polit Sci Rev 88(1):128–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G (1995) Decision making in political systems: veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism und multipartyism. Br J Polit Sci 25(3):289–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G (2002) Veto players: how political institutions work. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G (2008) Thinking about the recent past and the future of the EU. J Common Mark Stud 46(2):265–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G, Garrett G (2000) Legislative politics in the European Union. Eur Union. Polit 1(1): 9–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G, Garrett G (2001) The institutional foundations of intergovernmentalism and supranationalism in the European Union. Int Organ 55(2):357–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G, Proksch S-O (2007) The art of political manipulation in the European Convention. J Common Mark Stud 45(1):157–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yataganas X, Tsebelis G (2005) The treaty of nice, the convention draft and the constitution for Europe under a veto players analysis. Eur Const Law Rev 1(3):429–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

This chapter is a reprint of an article entitled ‘Why Don’t Veto Players Use Their Power?’ by Thomas König and Dirk Junge, which originally appeared in European Union Politics (2009) 10:507–534.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas König .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

König, T., Junge, D. (2011). Why Don’t Veto Players Use Their Power?. In: König, T., Debus, M., Tsebelis, G. (eds) Reform Processes and Policy Change. Studies in Public Choice, vol 16. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-5809-9_8

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics