Skip to main content

Domestic Veto Players, Commission Monitoring and the Implementation of European Policy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1431 Accesses

Part of the book series: Studies in Public Choice ((SIPC,volume 16))

Abstract

In this chapter, I analyze implementation of European directives by focusing on the interplay between domestic political and administrative actors and the Commission as the “guardian” of European policy. Being unaware of the Commission’s true preferences, the domestic actors have to decide whether and to what extent they will adopt an implementing policy that deviates from the legislative policy as embedded in a directive. The model indicates that, in general, deviations only occur when both domestic actors and the Commission prefer so. In addition, uncertainty about the Commission’s preferences plays a limited role: only when the Commission wants a minor deviation from the European policy, the national actors may have difficulty in shaping a proposal that also accounts of what the Commission wants. Being too ambitious the domestic actors may overestimate the Commission’s true preferences and risk to be challenged.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For example, Crombez (1996), Tsebelis (1994), Tsebelis and Garrett (2000), and

    Steunenberg (1994). See Dowding (2002) for an excellent overview.

  2. 2.

    For example, Mastenbroek (2003), König and Luetgert (2009), Falkner et al. (2005), and :̧def :̧def Thomson et al. (2007).

  3. 3.

    See Steunenberg and Rhinard (2005) and Steunenberg and Kaeding (2009) for a different conceptualization of a veto player index to address this problem. The empirical findings using this new index are consistent with veto player theory.

  4. 4.

    See Asser Instituut (2004: 24–25) and Steunenberg and Voermans (2006) for overviews of different national legal instruments in several EU member states.

  5. 5.

    The dynamics of the enforcement process could be a further extension of the model presented here. The enforcement process is, for instance, modelled by Steunenberg (2010), using a different model in which the Commission has to decide whether or not to open its gates and accept that an enforcing player – the European Court of Justice, or a large number of member states – determines a new interpretation of the European policy.

  6. 6.

    Although the model is specified for a one-dimensional outcome space, the main results may also apply to a multi-dimensional space. The only difference is that in a multi-dimensional outcome space more instances of compromising and accommodating Commission types exist, making a straightforward objection against a policy shift during implementation, as the guardian type does, less frequent. Because using a multi-dimensional space will make the presentation of the main argument more complex, I prefer the simpler presentation.

  7. 7.

    See Schmidt (2000) for examples of how the Commission may present different interpretations of the status quo. Note that Schmidt’s analysis is about legislative decision making at the European level.

  8. 8.

    Before the game begins, the other national players are also uncertain about the preferences of the Commission but know the views of the other domestic players including the national authority. The other players will make the same conjectures as the national authority and follow this player assessing the position of the Commission. Collecting information independently about the Commission preferences might be costly to these players because they are not well linked to existing formal or informal policy networks.

  9. 9.

    More specifically, compromising Commission types have an ideal point between z and q, with z = P + 1 ∕ 2(qP).

  10. 10.

    If both types are guardian (combination I in Table 10.1), there will be no separation since the domestic players cannot distinguish between both types. In equilibrium, the Commission signals x = q, the national authority proposes y = q, which will not be vetoed (v = 0) or challenged (w = 0) leading to q as the outcome.

  11. 11.

    For the combinations II and III in Table 10.1, there are equilibria in which national authority correctly identifies the Commission as guardian and one in which the Commission is identified as compromising (combination II) or accommodating (combination III).

  12. 12.

    As indicated, a guardian type of Commission will not deviate from the status quo. So, given some interpretation x. ≠q, the Council knows that the Commission (weakly) prefers some outcome to the status quo and is at least of a compromising type. If C 1 is an accommodating type of Commission, then C 2 is an accommodating type too, since C 1 > C 2. The national authority can simply propose P, and the Commission will not challenge.

  13. 13.

    Both Commission types can be compromising, C 1 > C 2, so that they are willing to accept c 1(q). The national authority is not able to distinguish both types. Consequently, it has to rely on its prior beliefs in making a decision, which, if it wrongly assumes that the Commission is type C 2, leads to a challenge. In other equilibria with compromising types the national authority makes the right guess about the Commission type.

  14. 14.

    Interestingly, as Mastenbroek (2007: 142) shows, the implementation of the points system was set up in such a way that the responsible agency did not receive information from the courts on offences. As a consequence, the agency was not able to apply the system.

References

  • Asser Instituut (2004) Implementatie EG richtlijnen vergeleken: Een onderzoek naar de implementatiepraktijk in een aantal EU-lidstaten in het bijzonder op het terrein van het maritiem vervoer. T.M.C. Asser Instituut, Den Haag

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks JS (1991) Signaling games in political science. Harwood Academic, Chur

    Google Scholar 

  • Börzel TA (2003) Guarding the treaty: the compliance strategies of the European Commission. In: Börzel TA, Cichowski RA (eds) The state of the European Union: Law, politics and society, vol 6. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 197–220

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter JR, Schap D (1987) Executive veto, legislative override, and structure-induced equilibrium. Public Choice 52:227–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crombez C (1996) Legislative procedures in the European community. Br J Polit Sci 26:199–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dearden JA, Husted TA (1990) Executive budget proposal, executive veto, legislative override and uncertainty: a comparative analysis of the budgetary process. Public Choice 65:1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dimitrova A, Steunenberg B (2000) The search for convergence of national policies in the European Union: an impossible quest? EU Polit 1:201–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Dimitrova A, Steunenberg B (2009) Living in parallel universes? The implementation of EU rules on cultural heritage in Bulgaria. Paper presented at the 2009 General Conference of ECPR in Potsdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowding K (2002) Rational choice and institutional change: an overview of current theories. In: Steunenberg B (ed) Widening the European Union: the politics of institutional reform and change. Routledge, London, pp 21–38

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Falkner G, Treib O, Hartlapp M, Leiber S (2005) Complying with Europe? The impact of minimum harmonization and soft law in the member states. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Franchino F (2004) Delegating powers in the European community. Br J Polit Sci 34:269–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franchino F (2007) The powers of the union: delegation in the EU. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Giuliani M (2003) Europeanization in comparative perspective: institutional fit and national adaptation. In: Featherstone K, Radaelli C (eds) The politics of Europeanization. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 134–155

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hartlapp M, Falkner G (2009). Problems of operationalisation and data in EU compliance research. EU Polit 10:281–304

    Google Scholar 

  • Héritier A (2001) Differential Europe: The European Union impact on national policymaking. In: Héritier A et al (eds) Differential Europe: the European Union impact on national policymaking. Rowman and Littlefield, Lanham, MA, pp 1–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaeding M (2006) Determinants of transposition delay in the European Union. J Public Policy 26:229–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiewiet DR, McCubbins MD (1988) Presidential influence on congressional appropriations decisions. Am J Polit Sci 32:713–736

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König T, Luetgert B (2009) Troubles with transposition: Explaining trends in member state notification failure and timelines. Br J Polit Sci 39:163–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linos K (2007) How can international organizations shape national welfare states? Evidence from compliance with European Union directives. Comp Polit Stud 40:547–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marks G, Hooghe L, Blank K (1996) European integration from the 1980s: state-centric v. multi-level governance. J Common Market Stud 34:341–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mastenbroek E (2003) Surviving the deadline: the transposition of EU directives in the Netherlands. EU Polit 4:371–395

    Google Scholar 

  • Mastenbroek E (2007) The politics of compliance: explaining the transposition of EC directives in the Netherlands. PhD thesis, Leiden University, Leiden

    Google Scholar 

  • Matthews SA (1989) Veto threats: rhetoric in a bargaining game. Q J Econ 104:347–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mbaye H (2001) Why national states comply with supranational law: Explaining implementation infringements in the European Union 1972–1993. EU Polit 2:259–281

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1986) An agenda for the study of institutions. Public Choice 48:3–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romeijn M (2008) Compliance with EU social policies: Work in progress. PhD thesis, Radboud University Nijmegen, Nijmegen

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt SK (2000) Only an agenda setter? The European Commission’s power over the Council of Ministers. EU Pol 1:37–61

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle KA, Weingast BR (1981) Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice. Public Choice 37:503–519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B (1994) Decision making under different institutional arrangements: legislation by the European community. J Theor Inst Econ 150:642–669

    Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B (1996) Agent discretion, regulatory policymaking, and different institutional arrangements. Public Choice 86:309–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B (2007) A policy solution to the European Union’s transposition puzzle, Interaction of interests in different domestic arenas. West Eur Polit 30:23–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B (2010) Is big brother watching? Commission oversight on the national implementation of EC directives. Eu Polit, forthcoming

    Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B, Kaeding M (2009) “As time goes by”: explaining the transposition of maritime directives. Eur J Polit Res 48:432–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B, Rhinard M (2005) Hare or turtle? Member states catching up with the transposition of EC directives. Working paper, Leiden University, Leiden

    Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg B, Voermans W (2006) The transposition of EU directives. A comparative study of instruments, techniques and processes in six member states. Leiden University/WODC, Leiden

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomson R, Torenvlied R, Arregui J (2007) The paradox of compliance: Infringements and delays in transposing European Union directives. Br J Polit Sci 37:685–709

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G (1994) The power of the European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter. Am Polit Sci Rev 88:128–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G (1995) Decision making in political systems: veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartism. Br J Polit Sci 25:289–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G (2002) Veto players: how political institutions work. Princeton University Press/Russell Sage Foundation, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G, Garrett G (1997) Agenda setting, vetoes and the European Union’s co-decision procedure. Legist Stud 3:74–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G, Garrett G (2000) Legislative politics in the European Union. EU Polit 1:9–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Versluis E (2007) Even rules, uneven practices, opening the ‘Black Box’ of EU Law in action. West Eur Polit 30:50–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank the participants of the conference “Reform processes and policy change: How do veto players determine decision making in modern democracies” (14–16 May 2009, Mannheim), and the 2009 Conference of the Dutch Political Science Association (28–29 May 2009, Berg en Dal), and particularly Daniel Finke, for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bernard Steunenberg .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Steunenberg, B. (2011). Domestic Veto Players, Commission Monitoring and the Implementation of European Policy. In: König, T., Debus, M., Tsebelis, G. (eds) Reform Processes and Policy Change. Studies in Public Choice, vol 16. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-5809-9_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics