Skip to main content

The Inframarginal Analysis of Demand and Supply and the Relationship between a Minimum Level of Consumption and the Division of Labour

  • Chapter
Increasing Returns and Economic Analysis
  • 104 Accesses

Abstract

The purpose of this chapter is twofold. First, a minimum level of consumption is introduced into each person’s utility-maximization problem in order to explore the general equilibrium implication of our particular specification of the minimum consumption constraint for the analysis of demand function. There are at least two ways to specify a minimum level of consumption in a person’s utility-maximization problem. The first is to specify a fixed amount of consumption in a person’s utility function such that the contribution of consumption to utility is positive only if the consumption level is greater than that fixed amount. This is analogous to the specification of a fixed input cost in a production function. Compared to the utility function without the minimum level of consumption, this specification is equivalent to shifting the indifference curve up the right-hand side. If the original utility function is of Cobb-Douglas or log Cobb-Douglas, such a way of introducing the minimum level of consumption will generate a linear expenditure system, proposed by Stone (1954). However, a minimum level of consumption in the real world is often associated with a constraint for the utility-maximization problem instead of with the shift of the indifference curve that represents tastes. If the minimum level of consumption is specified as a constraint for the utility-maximization problem, then marginal analysis that is based on interior solutions does not work because corner solutions may take place.

The author is grateful to the Center for East Asian Studies, the University of Chicago, for their support.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Baumgardner, J. (1988), ‘The Division of Labor, Local Markets, and Worker Organization’, Journal of Political Economy, 96(3) 509–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1981), A Treatise on the Family (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, L. and Cooper, K. (1969), Modern History (Morristown, Silver Burdett).

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. and Murphy, K. (1992), ‘The Division of Labor, Coordination Costs, and Knowledge’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107: 1137–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borland, J. and Yang, X. (1992), ‘Specialization and a New Approach to Economic Organization and Growth’, American Economic Review, 82, 386–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borland, J. and Yang, X. (1994), ‘Specialization, Product Development, Evolution of the Institution of the Firm, and Economic Growth’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 5, 19–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1994), ‘The Return to Increasing Retums’, in J. Buchanan and Y. Yoon (eds), The Return to Increasing Retums (Ann Arbor, The University of Michigan Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. and Stubblebine, W. (1962), ‘Externality’, EconOmica, 29, 371–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1946), ‘The Marginal Cost Controversy’, Economica, 13, 169–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960), ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D. (1987), ‘Cold Homes in Warm Climates and Vice Versa: a Paradox of Rational Heating’, Journal of Political Economy, 95, 1089–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houthakker, M. (1956), ‘Economics and Biology: Specialization and Speciation’, Kyklos, 9, 181–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kendrick, D. (1978), The Planning of Industrial Investment Programs — A Methodology (Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, S. (1989), ‘Labor Specialization and the Extent of the Market’, Journal of Political Economy, 97: 692–709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lievowitz, S. and Margolis, S. (1994), ‘Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 133–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Little, I. and Mirrlees, J. (1980), Manual of Industrial Project Analysis in Developing Countries (Paris: OECD).

    Google Scholar 

  • Locay, L. (1990), ‘Economic Development and the Division of Production between Households and Markets’, Journal of Political Economy, 98: 965–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1890), Principles of Economics, 8th edn (New York, Macmillan: 1948).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1978), ‘Substitution and the Division of Labor’, Economica, 45, 235–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1983), ‘Specialization and Human Capital’, Journal of Labor Economics, 1, 43–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. E. Cannan (reprint, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1976).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1951), ‘The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of the Market’, Journal of Political Economy, 59, 185–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, J. (1954), ‘Linear Expenditure Systems and Demand Analysis: An Application to the Pattern of British Demand’, Economic Journal, 64, 511–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wen, M. (1994), ‘An Analytical Framework with Consumer-producers, Economies of Specialization, and Transaction Costs’, Working Paper, Department of Economics, Monash University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. (1991), ‘Development, Structural Changes, and Urbanization’, Journal of Development Economics, 34, 199–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. (1994), ‘Endogenous vs. Exogenous Comparative Advantages and Economies of Specialization vs. Economies of Scale’, Journal of Economics, 60, 29–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. and Borland, J. (1991), ‘A Microeconomic Mechanism for Economic Growth’, Journal of Political Economy, 99, 460–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. and Ng, Y.-K. (1993), Specialization and Economic Organization: A New Classical Microeconomic Framework (Amsterdam, North-Holland).

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. and Ng, Y.-K. (1995), ‘Theory of the Firm and Structure of Residual Rights’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 26, 107–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. and Rice, R. (1994), ‘An Equilibrium Model Endogenizing the Emergence of a Dual Structure between the Urban and Rural Sectors’, Journal of Urban Economics, 25, 346–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. and Shi, H. (1992), ‘Specialization and Product Diversity’, American Economic Review, 82, 392–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. (1928), ‘Increasing Retums and Economic Progress’, The Economic Journal 38, 527–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 1998 Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lio, M. (1998). The Inframarginal Analysis of Demand and Supply and the Relationship between a Minimum Level of Consumption and the Division of Labour. In: Arrow, K.J., Ng, YK., Yang, X. (eds) Increasing Returns and Economic Analysis. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-26255-7_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics