Advertisement

Africa: Exclusion and the Containment of Anarchy

  • Ankie Hoogvelt
Chapter

Abstract

We have argued that with globalisation the world capitalist system has reached a new and higher level of integration. It has, in the words of Peter Drucker, become a ‘transnational economy, one that is shaped and driven, not by production and trade, but by money flows’. These money flows he calls ‘the symbol economy’.1 The symbol economy has its own dynamics and is not determined by the real economy. However, as mentioned before, the connections between the world of high finance and the fundamentals of world trade and production are not completely severed (see p. 129). The electronic integration of the world’s financial markets and the development of a whole range of novel financial instruments, permitted since the deregulation of these markets, have made it possible to connect up the arteries of real production and trade, and thus squeeze workers and peasants all over the world for their last drop of surplus in a manner that makes invisible, and therefore unchallengeable, the innumerable threads that lead to the pension funds, the share prices and the bank accounts in the core of the world system.

Keywords

Structural Adjustment Debt Crisis Structural Adjustment Programme Debtor Country Core Country 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes and References

  1. 1.
    P. Drucker, The New Realities (London: Heinemann, 1989) p. 120.Google Scholar
  2. 2.
    S. George, The Debt Boomerang (London: Pluto Press and the Transnational Institute, 1992) pp. 84–5.Google Scholar
  3. Note that Susan George’s figures are based on OECD data published in OECD, Financing and External Debt of Developing Countries, 1989 Survey (Paris: OECD, 1990).Google Scholar
  4. 3.
    The first five sections of this chapter are a reworked and shortened version of an earlier paper published in ROAPE, see A. Hoogvelt, ‘Debt and Indebtedness: The Dynamics of Third World Poverty’, Review of African Political Economy, no. 47 (Spring 1990) pp. 117–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. 5.
    R. T. Naylor, Hot Money and the Politics of Debt (Toronto: McClelland & Stewart, 1987).Google Scholar
  6. 6.
    Bank for International Settlements, 59th Annual Report 1989 (Basle: BIS, 1989) p. 135–6.Google Scholar
  7. 9.
    UNCTAD, Trade and Development Report, 1989 (New York: United Nations, 1989) Table 19, p. 38.Google Scholar
  8. 11.
    Quoted in S. Bransford and B. Kucinski, The Debt Squads (London: Zed Books, 1988) p. 18.Google Scholar
  9. 13.
    A. Leftwich, ‘Governance, Democracy and Development in the Third World’, Third World Quarterly, 14 (3) (1993) p. 607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. 15.
    For references, see J. Toye in Dilemmas of Development (Oxford: Blackwell, 1987) Chapter 5. Toye gives an overview of the ‘counter revolution’ in development theory in the 1980s and he describes its resonance with the orthodox Marxist left.Google Scholar
  11. 16.
    UNCTAD, Trade and Development Report, 1989, p. 106. On the virtues of debt conversion schemes, see also International Monetary Fund, Annual Report, 1988 (Washington: IMF, 1988) p. 46.Google Scholar
  12. 18.
    World Bank, Adjustment in Africa: Reform, Results, and the Road Ahead, a World Bank Policy Research Report (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994). Note that the World Bank has commissioned many reports and reviews of its structural adjustment lending.Google Scholar
  13. For a good discussion and comprehensive bibliography, see S. Ponte, ‘The World Bank and “Adjustment in Africa”’, Review of African Political Economy, no. 66 (1994) pp. 539–58.Google Scholar
  14. 19.
    D. Ghai and C. Hewitt de Alcantara, ‘The Crisis of the 1980s in Africa, Latin America and the Caribbean: An Overview’, in D. Ghai (ed.), The IMF and the South (London: Zed Books on behalf of United Nations Research Institute for Social Development, 1991) paras pp. 14–17.Google Scholar
  15. 22.
    K. Watkins, ‘Debt Relief for Africa’, Review of African Political Economy, no. 62 (1994) pp. 117–27, p. 126.Google Scholar
  16. For further reading on the evolution of poverty, social conditions and income inequality under structural adjustment, see also G. Cornia, S. Jolly and F. Stewart (eds), Adjustment with a Human Face: Protecting the Vulnerable and Promoting Growth (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1987);Google Scholar
  17. and P. Gibbon, ‘The World Bank and African Poverty 1973–91’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 30 (2) (1992) pp. 193–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. 25.
    B. Martin, ‘Gains without Frontiers’, New Statesman and Society (9 December 1994) pp. 22–3. The senior manager whom Martin quotes is Davison Budhoo. See also B. Martin, In the Public Interest? Privatisation and Public Sector Reform (London: Zed Books, 1994).Google Scholar
  19. 28.
    A. Leftwich, ‘Governance, Democracy and Development in the Third World’, Third World Quarterly, 14 (3) (1993) pp. 605–24, p. 610. For further reading on the pressures towards democratisation in Africa, see other contributions to the same issue of Third World Quarterly, including the literature review by E. Reinierse, pp. 647–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. 29.
    C. Bayliss, ‘Political Conditionality and Democratisation’, Review of African Political Economy, no. 65 (1995) pp. 321–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. 32.
    B. Gills, J. Rocamora and R. Wilson (eds), Low Intensity Democracy, Political Power in the New World Order (London: Pluto Press, 1993).Google Scholar
  22. 33.
    A. Sawyer, ‘The Politics of Adjustment Policies’, ECLA Document ECA/ICHD/88/29, quoted in C. Hewitt de Alcantara and D. Ghai, op. cit., note 19, p. 27. See also J.-J. Barya, ‘The New Political Conditionalities of Aid: An Independent View from Africa’, IDS Bulletin, 24 (1) (1993) pp. 16–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. 34.
    For example, R. Sandbrook, The Politics of Africa’s Economic Recovery (London: Cambridge University Press, 1993); C. Bayliss, op. cit., note 29, passim, p. 333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. 35.
    J. Walton and D. Seddon, Free Markets and Food Riots: The Politics of Global Adjustment (Oxford: Blackwell, 1994). See also M. Chossudovsky who holds the World Bank team in Rwanda directly responsible for the political and social repercussions of shock therapy that brought the country to civil war, in ‘IMF/World Bank Policies and the Rwandan Holocaust’, Third World Resurgence, no. 52 (1994).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. 38.
    S. P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven & London: Yale University Press, 1968).Google Scholar
  26. 39.
    J. C. Scott, Comparative Political Corruption (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1972) p. 35.Google Scholar
  27. 40.
    M. Duffield, The Symphony of the Damned: Racial Discourse, Complex Political Emergencies and Humanitarian Aid (Birmingham: School of Public Policy, University of Birmingham, occasional paper, 2 March 1996).Google Scholar
  28. 41.
    Cf. M. Barrett, The Politics of Truth (Oxford: Polity Press, 1991) p. 130 passim. Google Scholar
  29. 42.
    Examples of this ‘discourse analysis’ approach to the new aid agenda, are A. Leftwich, ‘Goverance, the State and the Politics of Development’, Development and Change, no. 25 (1994) pp. 363–86;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. and M. Robinson, ‘Aid, Democracy and Political Conditionality in Sub-Saharan Africa’, in G. Sorensen (ed.), Political Conditionality (London: Frank Cass, 1993) pp. 85–99; and ‘Strengthening Civil Society in Africa: The Role of Foreign Political Aid’, IDS Bulletin, 26 (2) (1995) pp. 70–80.Google Scholar
  31. 43.
    ODI, NGOs and Official Donors (London Overseas Development Institute Briefing Paper 1–4, August 1995), quoted in M. Duffield, op. cit., note 40, p. 8.Google Scholar
  32. For a comprehensive review and detailed advocacy of the NGO approach to ‘development’ see M. Edwards and D. Hulme (eds), Making a Difference, NGOs and Development in a Changing World (London: Earthscan, 1992).Google Scholar
  33. See also J. Clark, Democratising Development: The Role of Voluntary Organisation (London: Earthscan, 1991). Clark notes that there are today some 4000 development NGOs working in OECD member countries, dispersing almost $3 billion dollars worth of assistance every year and that they work with between 10000–20000 southern NGOs.Google Scholar
  34. For a critical assessment on the role of NGOs in development, see Alan Fowler, ‘Distant Obligations: Speculations on NGO Funding and the Global Market’, Review of African Political Economy, no. 55 (1992) pp. 9–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. 44.
    M. Duffield, op. cit., note 40. Much of this section of the chapter is based on Duffield’s thesis as developed in this work. Note, however, that Duffield has also elaborated his thesis in connection with other zones of insecurity on the edge of the global economy, notably the Balkan. In an outstanding report for UNICEF, in 1994, Duffield first developed his theory of ‘complex political emergencies’ with reference to both Angola and Bosnia. See M. Duffield, ‘Complex Political Emergencies’, an exploratory report for UNICEF (Birmingham: University of Birmingham, School of Public Policy, 1994).Google Scholar
  36. 45.
    M. Barker, The New Racism (London: Junction Books, 1992).Google Scholar
  37. 47.
    P. Richards, mimeo, ‘Fighting for the Rain Forest: Youth, Insurgency and Environment in Sierra Leone’ (University College London: Department of Anthropology, 1995); and M. Duffield, op. cit., note 40, p. 10 and passim. Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Ankie Hoogvelt 1997

Authors and Affiliations

  • Ankie Hoogvelt

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations