Skip to main content
  • 209 Accesses

Abstract

It has become a cliché to say that the world economy is in crisis, or, that it has been in crisis for over 20 years. Or that existing theories, whether of the neo-classical or Marxist variety, are no longer adequate to comprehend this crisis, and to predict how it is being resolved.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes and References

  1. K. Mannheim, Man and Society in an Age of Reconstruction (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1940) p. 174 (first published in German in 1935).

    Google Scholar 

  2. J. P. Womack, D. T. Jones and D. Roos, The Machine that Changed the World (New York: Rawson Associates, 1990) p. 27.

    Google Scholar 

  3. D. Harvey, The Condition of Postmodernity (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1989) p. 142.

    Google Scholar 

  4. For a discussion of these concepts and the role of technical change in economic theory, see G. Dosi et al., Technical Change and Economic Theory (London & New York: Pinter, 1988) especially the contribution by C. Freeman and C. Perez, ‘Structural Crises of Adjustment, Business Cycles and Investment Behaviour’, pp. 38–66.

    Google Scholar 

  5. K. Dohse et al., ‘From “Fordism” to “Toyotism”? The Social Organisation of the Labour Process in the Japanese Automobile Industry’, Politics and Society, 14 (2) (1985) pp. 115–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. A. Toffler, Powershift, Knowledge, Wealth and Violence at the Edge of the 21st Century (New York: Bantam Books, 1992) p. 102 and p. 239.

    Google Scholar 

  7. W. C. Kester, Japanese Takeovers, the Global Contest for Corporate Control (Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press, 1991) especially Chapter 3, ‘Japanese Corporate Governance’.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Note, however, the discussion by other writers on the subject of Japanese assembler—supplier relationships in the automobile industry. Womack et al. seem to describe a rather stylised picture of market price minus system. See for example B. Asanuma, ‘The Organization of Parts Purchases in the Japanese Automotive Industry’, in Japanese Economic Studies (Summer 1985) pp. 32–53.

    Google Scholar 

  9. A good example of such advocacy is J. MacDonald and J. Piggot, Global Quality, The New Management Culture (London: Mercury, 1990).

    Google Scholar 

  10. For a discussion and critique, see P. N. Dale, The Myth of Japanese Uniqueness (London: Routledge, 1988) pp. 105–6;

    Google Scholar 

  11. see also K. van Wolferen, The Enigma of Japanese Power, People and Politics in a Stateless Nation (New York: Vintage Books, 1990) pp. 165–7.

    Google Scholar 

  12. For a deeper analysis of cultural and psychological factors in Japanese industrial organisation, see A. Hoogvelt and M. Yuasa, ‘Going Lean or Going Native? The Social Regulation of “Lean” Production Systems’, Review of International Political Economy 1(2) (1994) pp. 281–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. UNCTC, Transnational Corporations, fourth report, ‘Trends and Prospects’ (New York: UN, 1988) p. 42.

    Google Scholar 

  14. My discussion on the emulation of Japanese practices in Britain owes much to the thorough PhD thesis of one of my PhD students, Masae Yuasa, ‘Autonomy or Dependency? The Reality and Discourse of Social Relations of Japanese Production Systems in UK Manufacturing Industry during the 1980s’ (University of Sheffield, January 1995).

    Google Scholar 

  15. J. Tidd, Flexible Manufacturing Technologies and International Competitiveness (London: Pinter, 1991).

    Google Scholar 

  16. N. Oliver and B. Wilkinson, The Japanization of British Industry, New Developments in the 1990s (Oxford: Blackwells, 1992).

    Google Scholar 

  17. Commision of the European Communities, Directorate General Science, Research and Development, What are Anthropocentric Production Systems? Why are they a Strategic Issue for Europe? (Brussels: Report EUR 13968 EN), 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Labour Research Department, Human Resource Management Survey, Bargaining Report (London: February 1995).

    Google Scholar 

  19. T. Elger and C. Smith (eds), Global Japanization: The Transnational Transformation of the Labour Process (London: Routledge, 1994) p. 32.

    Google Scholar 

  20. For a comprehensive review of the diverse approaches loosely federated under the label Regulation School, see R. Jessop, ‘Regulation Theories in Retrospect and Prospect’, Economy and Society, 19 (2) (May 1990) pp. 153–216. For a critical review of regulation theories in comparison with other contemporary crisis and transformation theories, see P. Hirst and J. Zeitlin, ‘Flexible Specialization versus post-Fordism: Theory, Evidence and Policy Implications’, Economy and Society, 20 (1) (February 1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. A. Lipietz, ‘New Tendencies in the International Division of Labor: Regimes of Accumulation and Modes of Regulation’, in A. Scott and M. Storper et al., Production, Work, Territory (London: Allen & Unwin, 1986) pp. 16–39, p. 19.

    Google Scholar 

  22. M. Aglietta, A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: The US Experience (London: Verso, 1979);

    Google Scholar 

  23. and A. Lipietz, Mirages and Miracles (London: Verso, 1987).

    Google Scholar 

  24. For a very informative array of case studies of these new flexible systems across the western world, see T. Elger and C. Smith, Global Japanization?, op. cit., note 29 (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  25. S. Gill, ‘Theorizing the Interregnum: The Double Movement and Global Politics in the 1990s’, in R. Cox et al., The International Political Economy of the Future (London: Zed Press, 1995) pp. 51–77.

    Google Scholar 

  26. K. Ohmae, Triad Power, the Coming Shape of Global Competition (New York: The Free Press and Collier Macmillan, 1985) pp. xvi–xvii.

    Google Scholar 

  27. M. Hergert and D. Morris, ‘Trends in International Collaborative Agreements’, in F. Contractor and P. Lorange (eds), Cooperative Strategies in International Business (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1988) pp. 99–110.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Cited in P. Lorange and J. Roos, Strategic Alliances, Formation, Implementation, and Evolution (Oxford: Blackwell, 1992), pp. 13–14.

    Google Scholar 

  29. R. Jaikumar and D. M. Upton, ‘The Coordination of Global Manufacturing’, in S. P. Bradley, J. A. Hausman, and R. L. Nolan (eds), Globalization, Technology, Competition: The Fusion of Computers and Telecommunications in the 1990s (Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School, 1994) pp. 169–84.

    Google Scholar 

  30. M. J. Piore and C. F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984).

    Google Scholar 

  31. P. Hirst and J. Zeitlin, ‘Flexible Specialisation versus post-Fordism: Theory, Evidence and Policy Implications’, Economy and Society, 20, no. 1 (February 1991) pp. 1–55.

    Google Scholar 

  32. See, for example, B. Jessop, ‘Regulation Theories in Retrospect and Prospect’, Economy and Society, 19, no. 2 (May 1990) pp. 153–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Also R. Boyer, ‘Technical Change and the Theory of “Regulation”’ in G. Dosi, C. Freeman et al. (eds), Technical Change and Economic Theory (London & New York: Pinter, 1988).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 1997 Ankie Hoogvelt

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hoogvelt, A. (1997). From Fordist to Flexible Production. In: Globalisation and the Postcolonial World. Palgrave, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-25671-6_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics