Advertisement

Democratisation and its Aftermath: Transition and Continuity in South Korea

  • Tat Yan Kong
Part of the St Antony’s Series book series

Abstract

The mass demonstrations which culminated in Roh Tae Woo’s Democratic Declaration of 29 June 1987 put an end to 26 years of military-based authoritarian rule. During the summer of 1987, South Korea (hereinafter Korea) appeared to be on the brink of major political and economic upheaval. Democratisation triggered off an unprecedented wave of labour unrest and a united democratic opposition seemed destined for victory in the forthcoming December presidential elections. Instead, the opposition fragmented and lost allowing Roh to hang on to power. The ruling party of the authoritarian era eventually merged with two of the opposition parties. In economic development, there was a continuation of the policy of gradual opening first initiated in the early 1980s. The aftermath of Korean democratisation contrasted sharply with the leadership and economic changes that followed the democratisation of Latin America and Eastern Europe in the 1980s. This article will explain why post-democratisation Korea followed a more graduated path of political and economic reform paying particular attention to the legacy of authoritarian industrialisation. It will then go on to assess the impact of societal activation on the economic policy agenda and the potential for Korea to combine a democratic polity with market-conforming intervention on the postwar Japanese pattern.

Keywords

Middle Class Korean Peninsula Democratic Liberal Party Unit Labour Cost Opposition Parti 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. 1.
    For example, see Alice Amsden, Asia’s Next Giant. South Korea and Late-Industrialization (New York: Oxford University Press, 1989).Google Scholar
  2. Robert Wade, Governing the Market (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990) whilst focusing on Taiwan also identifies Korea as a ‘governed market’ political economy of a similar type.Google Scholar
  3. 4.
    Won-mo Dong, ‘The Democrat-isation of South Korea: What Role does the Middle Class Play?’ in James Cotton (ed.), Korea under Roh Tae Woo (Sydney: George Allen and Unwin, 1993) pp. 74–91.Google Scholar
  4. 5.
    James Cotton, ‘From Authoritarianism to Democracy in South Korea’ in Political Studies 37 (1989) applies the modernisationist argument to the Korean case.Google Scholar
  5. 6.
    Gary Wynia, The Politics of Latin American Development (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1984) pp. 57–8;Google Scholar
  6. Guillermo O’Donnell and Philippe C. Schmitter, Transitions from Authoritarian Rule. Tentative Conclusions About Uncertain Democracies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1986) pp. 51–2.Google Scholar
  7. 8.
    See Dae Jung Kim, Mass Participatory Economy: A Democratic Alternative for Korea (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University-University Press of America, 1985).Google Scholar
  8. 9.
    Hak-kyu Sohn, Authoritarianism and Opposition in South Korea (London: Routledge, 1989) pp. 132–6 notes the support for labour reform by tradtitionally conservative civic and religious leaders by 1977.Google Scholar
  9. 11.
    Asia Monitor Resource Centre, ‘Min-ju No-jo: South Korea’s New Trades Unions’ in Asia Labour Monitor (Hong Kong: AMRC, 1987) pp. 63–5.Google Scholar
  10. 12.
    The Daewoo Motor strike of 1985 demonstrated the militancy of skilled blue-collar workers when it came to wage demands. Asia Watch Committee, Human Rights in Korea (Washington DC: Asia Watch Report, 1986) pp. 258–9.Google Scholar
  11. 14.
    Chi Ha Kim, Cry of the People and Other Poems (Hayama: Autumn Press, 1974).Google Scholar
  12. 16.
    Jung En Woo, Race to the Swift: State and Finance in Korean Industrialisation (New York: Columbia University Press: 1991) pp. 198–200.Google Scholar
  13. 19.
    Roh Tae Woo, ‘Joint Declaration on Creating a New Era: Launching a New National Political Party’ (Speech 22 January 1990) in Roh Tae Woo, Korea: A Nation Transformed. Selected Speeches (Oxford: Pergamon, 1990) pp. 171–5.Google Scholar
  14. 20.
    Bruce Cumings, ‘The Abortive Abertura: South Korea in the Light of Latin American Experience’ in New Left Review 173 (1989) p. 25.Google Scholar
  15. 21.
    The following section draws from my discussion ‘From Relative Autonomy to Consensual Development: The Case of South Korea’ in Political Studies, 43 (December 1995).Google Scholar
  16. 22.
    Eric A. Nordlinger, On the Autonomy of the Democratic State (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1981) argues that public officials can successfully diverge from societal preferences even in well established liberal democracies (US, Britain, Scandinavia).Google Scholar
  17. 23.
    Government of the Republic of Korea, Summary Draft of the Fifth Five Year Economic and Social Development Plan (Seoul: Economic Planning Board, 1981).Google Scholar
  18. 24.
    Alice H. Amsden and Yoon-Dae Euh, ‘Republic of Korea’s Financial Reform: What are the Lessons?’, UNCTAD Discussion Paper 30 (April 1990) pp. 13–14.Google Scholar
  19. 28.
    For example, Nam Duck Woo, ‘Economic Response to Globalisation Challenge’ in The Korea Economic Daily (4 January 1995) argued excessive bureaucratic impetus and concern with market failure were holding back liberalisation. Such a statement was particularly significant in view of Nam having been once closely identified with President Park’s interventionist policies.Google Scholar
  20. 29.
    Kap-Yun Lee, ‘Democratisation, Party Failure, and the Emergence of the Unification National Party’ in Korea and World Affairs, 18 (1994) pp. 749–71 attributes the rise and decline of the UNP to personality and popular protest against the incompetence of ruling politicians.Google Scholar
  21. 32.
    George E. Ogle, South Korea: Dissent within the Economic Miracle (London: Zed Books, 1990).Google Scholar
  22. 33.
    Mario F. Bognanno, ‘Korea’s Industrial Relations at Turning Point’ KDI Working Paper 8816 (Seoul: Korea Development Institute, 1988) pp. 33–4, 75–82.Google Scholar
  23. 34.
    Keun Lee and Chung H. Lee, ‘Sustaining Economic Development in South Korea: Lessons from Japan’ in The Pacific Review, 5 (1992) pp. 20–2.Google Scholar
  24. 35.
    Presidential Commission on Economic Restructuring, Realigning National Priorities (Seoul: 1988) pp. 101–48.Google Scholar
  25. 36.
    For the seminal work on state/business relations in postwar Japan, see Chalmers Johnson, MITI and the Japanese Miracle (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1982).Google Scholar
  26. 37.
    On Japan see T. J. Pempel and Keiichi Tsunekawa, ‘Corporatism without Labour: The Japanese Anomaly’ in Philippe Schmitter and Gerhard Lehmbruch (eds), Trends towards Corporatist Intermediation (Beverly Hills: Sage, 1979) andGoogle Scholar
  27. Karel van Wolferen, The Enigma of Japanese Power (London: Macmillan, 1989).Google Scholar
  28. 38.
    Donald S. MacDonald, ‘South Korea’s Politics since Liberation’ in Donald N. Clark (ed.), Korea Briefing 1993 (Boulder, CI: Westview, 1993) pp. 17–18.Google Scholar
  29. 42.
    Frederic C. Deyo (ed), The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca: Cornell University Press 1987).Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited 1997

Authors and Affiliations

  • Tat Yan Kong

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations