Skip to main content
  • 14 Accesses

Abstract

The economies of the Soviet Successor States (SSS) are in transition from command-administrative systems in which only limited markets existed, and in which money and financial phenomena played only a passive role, to market systems where the money supply and interest rates are expected to exert an active influence on the economy. The advent of macroeconomics in these transitional economies presents new problems for policy-makers in influencing the direction of their economies. One of the most important new policy variables for policy-makers in these emerging states is inflation. How the policy-makers deal with this problem is crucial to the activities of foreign investors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 74.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. This should not, however, be played down too much since it will be an important clause when these markets are developed. I am only stressing the fact that it may have been included as a means of mimicking Western central bank laws and had little to do with the Kazakhstan government’s concern for the securities market.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Though excluded from the present analysis, the Estonian law on central banking Zakon ESSR o bankakh exhibits the problem of failing to separate the central from the commercial banks in the application of such monetary policy instruments as the setting of the discount rate. This is evident from art. 7, sect. 4, which states that: ‘the Bank of Estonia will consult on the acceptance of decisions as stated in articles 18, 19, 28, 35 and 49 (each of which deal with discounting, reserve requirements and general monetary policy) with the commercial banks and their union associations’. Fortunately, none of the laws analysed here have the problem so explicitly stated.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Employees of Promstroibank, Moscow, informed the author in Jun. 1991 (six months after the commercialisation of the special banks) that they still received a credit plan from the government.

    Google Scholar 

  4. This point is difficult to prove and can only be backed by anecdotal evidence. It will take more than a privatisation decree to break the bonds between the former employees of a once integrated network of banks.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Data from David Johnson of PlanEcon, Jan. 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  6. That is, with a nominal GNP estimate for 1991 of 1667 billion roubles (PlanEcon estimate, Jan. 1992).

    Google Scholar 

  7. Jan. to Apr. 1991 was used for the comparison, as Apr. 1990 data for Sberbank were not available.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 1996 Patrick Artisien-Maksimenko and Yuri Adjubei

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lewarne, S. (1996). The Financial Context for Foreign Investment. In: Artisien-Maksimenko, P., Adjubei, Y. (eds) Foreign Investment in Russia and Other Soviet Successor States. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-24892-6_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics