Advertisement

In Praise of the Classics

  • Deepak Lal
Chapter

Abstract

‘As civilized human beings, we are the inheritors, neither of an enquiry about ourselves and the world, nor of an accumulating body of information, but of a conversation, begun in the primeval forests and made more articulate in the course of centuries. It is a conversation which goes on both in public and within each of ourselves. Of course there is argument and enquiry and information, but wherever these are profitable they are to be recognized as passages in this conversation, and perhaps they are not the most captivating of the passages. It is the ability to participate in this conversation, and not the ability to reason cogently, to make discoveries about the world, or to contrive a better world, which distinguishes the human being from the animal and the civilized man from the barbarian. Indeed, it seems not improbable that it was the engagement in this conversation (where talk is without a conclusion) that gave us our present appearance, man being descended from a race of apes who sat in talk so long and so late that they wore our their tails.’ — M. Oakeshott, The Voice of Poetry in the Conversation of Mankind (London: Bowes & Bowes, 1959) p. 11

Keywords

Political Economy Growth Theory Oxford Economic Paper Positive Economic Primeval Forest 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Achinstein, P. (ed.) (1983) The Concept of Evidence (Oxford: Oxford University Press)Google Scholar
  2. Arrow, K. J. (1962): “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing”, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 29.Google Scholar
  3. Atkinson, A. B. and J. E. Stiglitz (1980) Lectures on Public Economics (London: McGraw-Hill).Google Scholar
  4. Bacon, R. and W. Eltis (1976) Britain’s Economic Problems: Too Few Producers (London: Macmillan).Google Scholar
  5. Bhagwati, J. N. (1979) Anatomy and Consequences of Trade Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research).Google Scholar
  6. Birdsall, N. (1988) “Economic Approaches to Population Growth”, in H. Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan (eds.), Handbook of Development Economics (Amsterdam: North-Holland).Google Scholar
  7. Blaug, M. (1980) The Methodology of Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  8. Caldwell, B. (1982) Beyond Positivism in Economics (London: Allen & Unwin).Google Scholar
  9. de Marchi, N. (ed.) (1988) The Popperian Legacy in Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  10. Elster, J. (1983) Explaining Technical Change (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  11. Eltis, W. (1984) The Classical Theory of Economic Growth (London: Macmillan).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Fisher, I. (1930) The Theory of Interest (New York: Macmillan Co.).Google Scholar
  13. Flew, A. (1985) Thinking about Social Thinking — The Philosophy of the Social Sciences (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).Google Scholar
  14. Friedman, M. (1953) “The Methodology of Positive Economics”, in his Essays in Positive Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
  15. Hacking, I. (1981) “Lakatos’ Philosophy of Science”, in Hacking (ed.), Scientific Revolutions (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  16. Hacking, I. (1989) “Economic Methodology in a Nutshell”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(2) (Spring).Google Scholar
  17. Hausman, Carl R. (1989) Metaphor and Art (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  18. Hausman, D. C. (ed.), (1984) The Philosophy of Economics — An Anthology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  19. Hayek, F. (1948) “The Use of Knowledge in Society”, in his Individualism and Economic Order (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul).Google Scholar
  20. Hayek, F. (1960) The Constitution of Liberty (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul).Google Scholar
  21. Henderson, P. D. (1986) Innocence and Design — The Influence of Economic Ideas on Policy (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).Google Scholar
  22. Hicks, J. R. (1965) Capital and Growth (Oxford: Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
  23. Hicks, J. R. (1975) “The Scope and Status of Welfare Economics”, Oxford Economic Papers, Nov.Google Scholar
  24. Hicks, J. R. (1979) Causality in Economics (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).Google Scholar
  25. Hutchinson, T. (1938) The Significance and Basic Postulates of Economic Theory (London: Macmillan).Google Scholar
  26. Hutchinson, T. (1977) Knowledge and Ignorance in Economics (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).Google Scholar
  27. Hutchinson, T. and M. Blaug (1978) On Revolution and Progress in Economic Knowledge (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  28. Kaldor, N. (1957) “A Model of Economic Growth”, Economic Journal, vol. 67.Google Scholar
  29. Keynes, J. M. (1926) The End of Laissez-Faire (London: Hogarth Press).Google Scholar
  30. Keynes, J. N. (1890) The Scope and Method of Political Economy (London: Macmillan).Google Scholar
  31. Klamer, A., D. M. McCloskey and R. M. Solow (eds.) (1988) The Consequences of Economic Rhetoric (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
  32. Krueger, A. O. (1978) Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research).Google Scholar
  33. Krueger, A. O (1983) Trade and Employment in Developing Countries 3 — Synthesis and Conclusion (Chicago: National Bureau Economic Research).Google Scholar
  34. Lal, D. (1983) The Poverty of “Development Economics” (London: Institute of Economic Affairs; American edition, Cambridge Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1985).Google Scholar
  35. Lal, D. (1987a) “The Political Economy of Economic Liberalization”, World Bank Review, vol. 1, January.Google Scholar
  36. Lal, D. (1987b) “Markets, Mandarins and Mathematicians”, CATO Journal, vol. 7, no. 1, Spring/Summer.Google Scholar
  37. Lal, D. (1990) Political Economy and Public Policy, Occasional Paper #19, International Center for Economic Growth, San Francisco, ICS Press.Google Scholar
  38. Lal, D. and S. van Wijnbergen (1985) “Government Deficits, the Real Interest Rate and LDC Debt: On Global Crowding Out”, European Economic Review, vol. 29, no. 1.Google Scholar
  39. Lal, D. and H. Myint (1991) The Political Economy of Poverty, Equity and Growth, processed (London: University College).Google Scholar
  40. Lewis, W. A. (1955) The Theory of Economic Growth (London: Allen & Unwin).Google Scholar
  41. Lipsey, R. E. (1966) An Introduction to Positive Economics, 2nd ed. (London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson).Google Scholar
  42. Lipton, M. (1984) “Comment on P. Bauer, ‘Remembrance of Studies Past: Retracing First Steps”, in G. M. Meier and D. Seers (eds), Pioneers in Development (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  43. Little, I. M. D. (1982) Economic Development: Theory, Policy and International Relations (New York: Basic Books).Google Scholar
  44. Little, I. M. D., M. F. Scott and T. Scitovsky (1970) Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  45. Lucas, R. E. (1988) “On the Mechanics of Economic Development”, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 22.Google Scholar
  46. McCloskey, D. N. (1985) The Rhetoric of Economics (Madison, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin Press).Google Scholar
  47. McCloskey, D. N. (1988) “The Consequences of Rhetoric”, in Kramer, McCloskey and Solow (1988).Google Scholar
  48. Machlup, F. (1982) “Operationalism and Pure Theory in Economics”, in his Methodology of Economics and other Social Sciences (New York: Academic Press).Google Scholar
  49. Meier, Gerald M. (1989) Leading Issues on Economic Development (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  50. Mill, J. S. (1843) A System of Logic (London: J. W. Parker).Google Scholar
  51. Mises, L. von (1962) The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Sciences (Princeton, van Nostrand).Google Scholar
  52. Myint, H. (1948) Theories of Welfare Economics (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
  53. Myint, H. (1958) “The ‘Classical” Theory of International Trade and the Underdeveloped Countries”, Economic Journal, vol. 68, JuneGoogle Scholar
  54. Myint, H. (1972) South-East Asia’s Economy: Development Policies in the 1970s (London: Penguin).Google Scholar
  55. Myint, H. (1985) “Organizational Dualism and Economic Development”, Asian Development Review, March–April.Google Scholar
  56. Myint, H. (1987) “Neoclassical Development Analysis: Its Strengths and Limitations”, in Gerald. M. Meier (ed.), Pioneers in Development, 2nd series (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  57. Newbery, D. G. M. and N. H. Stern (eds.) (1987) The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  58. Popper, K. (1959) The Logic of Scientific Discovery (New York: Basic Books).Google Scholar
  59. Putnam, H. (1981) “The ‘Corroboration’ of Theories”, in Hacking (ed.), Scientific Revolutions (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  60. Rae, J. (1834) Statement of Some New Principles of Political Economy (Boston: Hilliard, Gray).Google Scholar
  61. Redman, D. (1991) Economics and the Philosophy of Science (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  62. Robbins, L. (1935) An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science (London: Macmillan).Google Scholar
  63. Robbins, L. (1938) “Live and Dead Issues in the Methodology of Economics”, Economica, vol. 5.Google Scholar
  64. Robbins, L. (1952) The Theory of Economic Policy in English Classical Political Economy (London: Macmillan).Google Scholar
  65. Robbins, L. (1968) The Theory of Economic Development in the History of Economic Thought (London: Macmillan).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Robbins, L. (1976) Political Economy: Past and Present, A Review of Leading Theories of Economic Policy (London: Macmillan).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Romer, P. (1986) “Increasing Returns and Long Term Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94.Google Scholar
  68. Romer, P. (1989) “Capital Accumulation in the Theory of Long-Run Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94.Google Scholar
  69. Ryan, A. (ed.) (1973) The Philosophy of Social Explanation (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  70. Samuelson, P. (1952) “Economic Theory and Mathematics: An Appraisal”, American Economic Review, 42 (May): 56–66.Google Scholar
  71. Samuelson, P. (1963) “Discussion”, American Economic Review, 53 (May): 231–36.Google Scholar
  72. Samuelson, P. (1983) Foundations of Economic Analysis, enlarged edition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
  73. Sargent, T. (1982) “Four Big Inflations”, in R. Hall (ed.), Inflation, Causes and Effects (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
  74. Scott, M. F. (1989) A New View of Economic Growth (Oxford: Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
  75. Skocpol, T. (1979) States and Social Revolutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Solow, R. M. (1985) “Economic History and Economics”, American Economic Review (May).Google Scholar
  77. Sosa, E. (ed.) (1975) Causation and Conditionals (London: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
  78. Stern, N. (1991) “The Determinants of Growth”, Economic Journal, vol. 101, January.Google Scholar
  79. Stewart, I. M. T. (1979) Reasoning and Method in Economics — An Introduction to Economic Methodology (London and New York: McGraw-Hill).Google Scholar
  80. Stove, D. C. (1985) “Karl Popper and the Jazz Age”, Encounter (June).Google Scholar
  81. Uzawa, H. (1965) “Optimum Technical Change in an Aggregative Model of Economic Growth”, International Economic Review, vol. 6.Google Scholar
  82. Wrigley, E. A. (1988) Continuity, Chance and Change: The Character of the Industrial Revolution in England (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Gerald M. Meier 1994

Authors and Affiliations

  • Deepak Lal

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations