Skip to main content

Tiny increments of economic change

  • Chapter
The Origin of Economic Ideas

Abstract

The time has come to say farewell to the labour theory of value. It is about to be cast out and will soon become an object of derision, its acceptance a mark of perversity or subversion. By one of those curious coincidences in the development of ideas, Marx was engaged in installing it as the centre-piece of his economic doctrine while Jevons, Menger and Walras were exorcising it in favour of something that would be as unlike Marx’s doctrine as unlike could be.1 While Marx taught the inevitability of revolution and called in a voice of thunder for the expropriation of the expropriators, Jevons, Menger and Walras laid bare the mechanism by which economic molecules placidly pursued their maximising course through tiny increments of economic change.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Labour Defended against the Claims of Capital; or the Unproductiveness of Capital proved with reference to the Present Combinations amongst Journeymen. By a Labourer (1825). Graham Wallas, in his Life of Francis Place (London: Longmans, 1898) records that Hodgskin read Ricardo’s Principles in 1820 and may claim to have originated ‘Ricardian Socialism’.

    Google Scholar 

  2. See, e.g., Report to the County of Lanark (1821) (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1970) p. 207.

    Google Scholar 

  3. An Inquiry Into the Principles of the Distribution of Wealth Most Conducive to Human Happiness (London: Longman, Hurst etc, 1824).

    Google Scholar 

  4. For an enthralling account of the lives and ideas of these people see Edmund Wilson, To the Finland Station (London: Fontana Library, 1960).

    Google Scholar 

  5. ‘On some neglected British economists I’, Economic Journal, vol. XIII, Sep 1903, p. 335 et seq.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Ibid. p. 359.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Natural Elements of Political Economy (London: Longman, Brown, Green, and Longmans, 1855). The contributions of Gossen and Jennings are reviewed in W. Stark, The Ideal Foundations of Economic Thought (Kegan Paul, 1943).

    Google Scholar 

  8. Ibid. p. 46.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Ibid. pp. 98–9.

    Google Scholar 

  10. The Theory of Political Economy (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1970) p. 62.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Letters and Journal ed. by his wife (London: Macmillan, 1886) p. 323. Another hostile review was by Marshall, in the Academy, 1 Apr 1872. This is reprinted in A. C. Pigou (ed.) Memorials of Alfred Marshall (London: Macmillan, 1925).

    Google Scholar 

  12. Elements of Pure Economics, translated by William Jaffé (London: Allen & Unwin, 1954) p. 44.

    Google Scholar 

  13. The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money (London: Macmillan, 1936) p. 32.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Capital (Moscow, Foreign Languages Publishing House, 1961) pp. 14–16.

    Google Scholar 

  15. See Alfred Cobban, A History of Modern France (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1961) vol. II, p. 141.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See F. B. Smith, The Making of the Second Reforn Bill (Cambridge University Press, 1966) pp. 151–3.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Ibid. p. 168.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Ibid. pp. 232–3.

    Google Scholar 

  19. R. D. Collison Black and Rosamond Könekamp, Papers and Correspondence of William Stanley Jevons (London: Macmillan, 1972), vol. I, p. 208.

    Google Scholar 

  20. John Stuart Mill, ‘Utilitarianism’, Max Lerner (ed.), The Essential Works of John Stuart Mill (New York: Bantam Books, 1961) p. 194.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See Leslie Stephen, The English Utilitarians (London School of Economics Series of Reprints of Scarce Works on Political Economy no. 9, 1961) p. 194.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Jeremy Bentham, An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation (1789). Mary Warnock (ed.), Utilitarianism (London: Fontana, 1962) p. 33.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Ibid. pp. 33–5.

    Google Scholar 

  24. In Jeremy Bentham’s Economic Writings (London: Allen & Unwin for The Royal Economic Society, 1954), vol. III.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Ibid. p. 434.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Ibid. pp. 421–2.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Ibid. p. 442.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Ibid. p. 443.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Introductory Lectures on Political Economy (London: B. Fellowes, 1831). Quesnay, too, observed ‘this magic’ and attributed it to God. See above, p. 75.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Non-mathematicians might like to consult the brilliantly lucid explanation of calculus in Chapters viii and x to xii of W. W. Sawyer, Mathematician’s Delight (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1943). The Encyclopaedia Britannica also gives a clear introduction, as does P. J. Hilton, Differential Calculus (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1958).

    Google Scholar 

  31. The Theory of Political Economy (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1970) p. 77.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Ibid. p. 82–3.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Ibid. p. 101.

    Google Scholar 

  34. J. M. Keynes, Essays in Biography (London: Mercury Books, 1961) p. 284.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (The Free Press, Glencoe, Illinois, 1950) p. 119.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Ibid. p. 56.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Ibid. p. 161.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Ibid. pp. 164–5.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Ibid. p 171.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Ibid. pp. 121–3.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Ibid. p. 132.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Ibid. p. 146.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Ibid. p. 156.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Ibid. pp. 173–4.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Ibid. p. 97.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Professor of political economy first at King’s College, London, then at Oxford. See J. M. Keynes, Essays in Biography, vol. X, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes (London: Macmillan, 1973).

    Google Scholar 

  47. Giornale degli Economisti, vol. LI, 1915. The paper ‘On the Theory of the Budget of the Consumer’, is reprinted in American Economic Association, Readings in Price Theory (London: Allen & Unwin, 1953).

    Google Scholar 

  48. Ibid. p. 27.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Ibid. p. 28.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Philip Henry Wicksteed, The Alphabet of Economic Science (Macmillan, 1888) and An Essay on the Co-ordination of the Laws of Distribution (Macmillan, 1894); Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics (Macmillan, 1890); John Bates Clark, Capital and its Earnings (American Economic Association, 1888), The Possibility of a Scientific Law of Wages (American Economic Association, 1889) and ‘Distribution as Determined by a Law of Rent’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. V, 1890–91.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Most notably by Nikolai Bukharin (1880–1938), Economic Theory of the Leisure Class (London: Martin Lawrence, 1927).

    Google Scholar 

  52. The Economic Journal vol. XXXVI, 1926. Reprinted in American Economic Association Readings in Price Theory (London: Allen & Unwin, 1953).

    Google Scholar 

  53. Edward Hastings Chamberlin, The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, A Re-orientation of the Theory of Value (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1933). Joan Robinson, The Economics of Imperfect Competition (London: Macmillan, 1933).

    Google Scholar 

  54. Chamberlin, op. cit. p. 178; Robinson, op. cit. p. 284. This, in the conventional usage, is known as exploitation, the term here being conveniently gelded of all political content. It was Pigou who so defined it (Economics of Welfare, Macmillan 1924, pp. 527 and 754). but both Chamberlin and Joan Robinson squeeze it even drier of content than had Pigou. According to Chamberlin. in monopolistic competition all factors are necessarily exploited: ‘it would be impossible for employers to avoid the charge of “exploitation” without going into bankruptcy’ (op. cit. p. 183). Joan Robinson explains that, ‘paradoxical as it may seem,… the removal of exploitation is not always beneficial to the workers concerned’ (op. cit. p. 283).

    Google Scholar 

  55. C. H. Herford, Philip Henry Wicksteed, His Life and Work (London: Dent, 1931) p. 201.

    Google Scholar 

  56. L.L. Price, A Short History of Political Economy in England (London: Methuen, 1937) pp. 267–8. The first edition was published in 1891, so Price, who was Reader in Economic History at Oxford, can speak of these events at first hand.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Knut Wicksell, Lectures in Political Economy (1901) (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1934), p. 28.

    Google Scholar 

  58. D. H. Robertson, ‘Wage-Grumbles’ (1931), American Economic Association, Readings in the Theory of Income Distribution (London: Allen & Unwin, 1950), p. 221. Marshall hurt and puzzled his successors by concluding. ‘This doctrine has sometimes been put forward as a theory of wages. But there is no valid ground for any such pretension. The doctrine that the earnings of a worker tend to be equal to the net product of his work, has by itself no real meaning; since in order to estimate net product, we have to take for granted all the expenses of production of the commodity on which he works, other than his own wages.’ Principles of Economics, op. cit. p. 518. In modern parlance, we should say that workers and machines form parts of socio-technical systems. The removal or duplication of particular parts is likely to produce absurd results.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 1989 Guy Routh

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Routh, G. (1989). Tiny increments of economic change. In: The Origin of Economic Ideas. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-20169-3_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics