Conceptual Issues in the New Economic Anthropology: Moving Beyond the Polemic of Neo-classical and Marxist Economic Theory

  • Willie L. Baber

Abstract

I have been concerned about the limitations of neo-classicism, and the advantages of a Marxist1 dimension in the analysis of social change, primarily because of an unrelenting and uncritical expansion, in the social sciences, of various forms of neo-classical theory and its postulates.2 None of us is surprised to find sociological analogues of neo-classical economic theory, or postulates, generated in the works of Homans (1958, 1967), Belshaw (1965, 1967), Barth (1966, 1967 and 1981), Schneider (1974), or Prattis (1973) to name a few often-cited examples. However, the ever expanding use of neoclassical economic theory is also augmented by some Marxists (Godelier, 1972, 1977; Sahlins, 1972; Hindess and Hirst, 1975) who would correctly acknowledge Marx’s critical incorporation of the classical political economy of Ricardo, yet unwittingly insist on trying to refute important neo-classically derived propositions about economic behaviour. I believe that this trend should be questioned. Marx did not contest the validity of market value, nor supply and demand, which forms the basis of what we may refer to as neoclassicism.

Keywords

Europe Income Stratification Expense Posit 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Bibliography

  1. Max Adler, ‘The Theory and Method of Marxism’, in Austro-Marxism, Tom Bottomore and Patrick Goode (eds), pp. 57–101 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1978).Google Scholar
  2. J. C. Alexander, Positivism: Presuppositions and Current Controversies (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1982).Google Scholar
  3. L. Althusser, and E. Balibar, Reading Capital (London: New Left Books, 1970).Google Scholar
  4. S. Aronowitz, The Crisis of Historical Materialism (New York: Praeger, 1981).Google Scholar
  5. Talal Asad, ‘Market Model, Class Structure and Consent: A Reconsideration of Swat Political Organization’, Man (N.S.) 7, 1972, 74–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. W. L. Baber, ‘Social Change, and the Peasant Community: Horowitz’s Morne-Paysan Reinterpreted, Ethnology 21, 1982, 227–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. F. Barth, ‘Models of Social Organization’, Occasional Paper No. 23 (London: Royal Anthropological Institute, 1966).Google Scholar
  8. F. Barth, ‘Economic Spheres in Darfur’, in Themes in Economic Anthropology, Raymond Firth (ed.), pp. 149–74 (London: Tavistock, 1967).Google Scholar
  9. F. Barth, Process and Form in Social Life: Selected Essays of Fredrik Barth, vol. 1, International Library of Anthropology (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1981).Google Scholar
  10. C. S. Belshaw, Traditional Exchange and Modern Markets (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1965).Google Scholar
  11. C. S. Belshaw, ‘Anthropology and Economic Theory’, in Social Organization: Essays Presented to Raymond Firth, Maurice Freedman (ed.), pp. 25–42 (Chicago: Aldine, 1967).Google Scholar
  12. L. Bernard-Henri, Barbarism with a Human Face (New York: Harper & Row, 1978).Google Scholar
  13. F. Braudel, ‘History and the Social Sciences: The Long Term’, Social Science International, 9, 1970, 145–74.Google Scholar
  14. R. Brenner, ‘The Origins of Capitalist Development: A Critique of Neo-Smithian Marxism’, New Left Review, 104, 1977, 25–93.Google Scholar
  15. F. Cancian, ‘Maximization as Norm, Strategy, and Theory: A Comment on Programmatic Statements in Economic Anthropology’, American Anthropologist, 68, 1966, 465–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. A. Chayanov, The Theory of Peasant Economy, D. Thorner et al. (eds) (Illinois: Irwin, 1966).Google Scholar
  17. J. Clammer (ed.), The New Economic Anthropology (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1978).Google Scholar
  18. G. A. Collier, Fields of Tzotzil: The Ecological Bases of Tradition in Highland Chiapas (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1975a).Google Scholar
  19. G. A. Collier, ‘Are Marginal Farmlands Marginal to Their Farmers?’ in Formal Methods in Economic Anthropology, Stuart Plattner (ed.), pp. 149–58 (Washington, D.C.: American Anthropological Association, 1975b).Google Scholar
  20. Scott Cook, ‘The Obsolete “Anti-market” Mentality: A Critique of the Substantive Approach to Economic Anthropology’, American Anthropologist, 63, 1966, 1–25.Google Scholar
  21. Scott Cook, ‘The “Anti-market” Mentality Re-examined: A Further Critique of the Substantive Approach to Economic Anthropology’, American Anthropologist, 63, 1966, 1–25.Google Scholar
  22. R. G. Cooper, ‘Dynamic Tensions: Symbiosis and Contradiction in Hmong Social Relations’, in The New Economic Anthropology, John Clammer (ed.), pp. 138–75 (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1978)Google Scholar
  23. W. G. Davis, Social Relations in a Philippine Market (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973).Google Scholar
  24. D. Donham, ‘Beyond the Domestic Mode of Production’, Man, (N.S.) 16, 1981, 515–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. G. Dupré and P. P. Rey, ‘Reflections on the Relevance of a Theory of the History of Exchange’, in Relations of Production: Marxist Approaches to Economic Anthropology, David Seddon (ed.), pp. 171–208 (London: Frank Cass, 1973).Google Scholar
  26. R. Firth, ‘Social Organization and Social Change’, Presidential Address, from Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, 84, 1954, 1–20.Google Scholar
  27. R. Firth, ‘The Sceptical Anthropologist? Social Anthropology and Marxist Views on Society’, in Marxist Analyses and Social Anthropology, Maurice Bloch (ed.), pp. 29–60 (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1975).Google Scholar
  28. A. Foster-Carter, ‘Can We Articulate “Articulation”?’ in The New Economic Anthropology, John Clammer (ed.), pp. 210–49 (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1978).Google Scholar
  29. M. Friedman, Essays in Positive Economics (Chicago: University Press, 1953).Google Scholar
  30. M. Godelier, Rationality and Irrationality in Economics (London: New Left Books, 1972).Google Scholar
  31. M. Godelier, Perspectives in Marxist Anthropology (Cambridge: University Press, 1977).Google Scholar
  32. A. Gouldner, The Coming Crisis of Western Sociology (London: Heinemann, 1972).Google Scholar
  33. J. Habermas, Knowledge and Human Interests (London: Heinemann, 1972).Google Scholar
  34. R. H. Halperin, ‘New and Old in Economic Anthropology’, American Anthropologist, 24, 1982, 339–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. A. Heath, ‘The Rational Model of Man’, Archives Européennes de Sociologie, 15, 1974, 184–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. R. Hilferding, ‘The Materialist Conception of History’, in Modern Interpretations of Marx, Tom Bottomore (ed.), pp. 125–37 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1981).Google Scholar
  37. B. Hindess and Paul Q. Hirst, Precapitalist Modes of Production (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1975).Google Scholar
  38. G. C. Homans, ‘Social Behavior as Exchange’, American Journal of Sociology, 63, 1958, 597–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. G. C. Homans, ‘Review of Barth, 1966’, American Anthropologist, 55, 1967, 17–41.Google Scholar
  40. Makoto Itoh, ‘Joint Production: The Issues After Steedman’, in The Value Controversy, Ian Steedman et al. (eds), pp. 163–72 (London: Verso Editions and NLB, 1981).Google Scholar
  41. J. N. Keynes, The Scope and Method of Political Economy (London: Macmillan, 1891).Google Scholar
  42. K. Korsch, Marxism and Philosophy (London: New Left Books, 1970).Google Scholar
  43. T. S. Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962).Google Scholar
  44. E. LeClair and H. Schneider, Economic Anthropology: Readings in Theory and Analysis (New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston, 1968).Google Scholar
  45. G. Lukacs, History and Class Consciousness (London: Merlin Press, 1971).Google Scholar
  46. A. Marshall, ‘The Present Position of Economics’, in Memorials of Alfred Marshall, A. C. Pigou (ed.), pp. 164–81 (London: Macmillian, 1925).Google Scholar
  47. Karl Marx, Capital vols I, II and III (New York: International Publishers,1967).Google Scholar
  48. K. Marx and F. Engels, Werke vols 1–41 (Berlin: Dietz-Verlag, 1954–67).Google Scholar
  49. P. McDowell, ‘Guatemalan Stratification and Peasant Marketing Arrangements: A Different View’, Man (N.S.) 11, 1976, 273–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Sidney W. Mintz, ‘Internal Market Systems as Mechanisms of Social Articulation’, Proceedings of the American Ethnological Society (Seattle: University of Washington Press, 1959).Google Scholar
  51. Sidney W. Mintz, ‘The Caribbean as a Socio-cultural Area’, Cahiers d’Histoire Mondiale, 9, 1966, 912–37.Google Scholar
  52. E. Nagel, ‘Assumptions in Economic Theory’, American Economic Review, 53, 1953, 211–19.Google Scholar
  53. M. Nash, Primitive and Peasant Economic Systems (San Francisco: Chandler, 1966).Google Scholar
  54. R. Paine, ‘Second Thoughts About Barth’s Models’, Royal Anthropological Institute, No. 7, 1974.Google Scholar
  55. J. I. Prattis, ‘Strategizing Man’, Man (N.S.) 8, 1973, 46–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Pierre Phillipe Rey, Les Alliances des Classes (Paris: Maspéro, 1973).Google Scholar
  57. D. Ricardo, Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, P. Sraffa (ed.) (London: Cambridge University Press, 1951).Google Scholar
  58. Lionel Robbins, An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science (London: Macmillan, 1962).Google Scholar
  59. William Roseberry, ‘Rent, Differentiation and the Development of Capital-ism Among Peasants’, American Anthropologist, 78, 1976, 45–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. R. S. Rudner, Philosophy of Social Science (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1966).Google Scholar
  61. P. J. Runkel and J. E. McGrath, Research on Human Behavior: A Systematic Guide to Method (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1972).Google Scholar
  62. Marshall Sahlins, Stone Age Economics (Chicago: University Press, 1972).Google Scholar
  63. P. A. Samuelson, ‘Understanding the Marxian Notion of Exploitation: A Summary of the So-called Transformation Problem Between Marxian Values and Comparative Prices’, Journal of Economic Literature, 9, 1971, 399–431.Google Scholar
  64. H. K. Schneider, Economic Man: The Anthropology of Economics (New York: Free Press, 1974).Google Scholar
  65. David Seddon (ed.), Relations of Production: Marxist Approaches to Economic Anthropology (London: Frank Cass, 1978).Google Scholar
  66. G. W. Skinner, ‘Marketing and Social Structure in Rural China’, Parts I and II, Journal of Asian Studies, 24, 1964, 2–43, 195–228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. A. Smith in The Wealth of Nations, R. H. Campbell and A S Skinner (eds) (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976).Google Scholar
  68. Carol Smith, ‘Economics of Marketing Systems: Models from Economic Geography’, Annual Review of Anthropology, 3, 1974, 167–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Carol Smith, ‘Examining Stratification Systems Through Peasant Marketing Arrangements’, Man (N.S.), 10, 1975, 95–122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Carol Smith, ‘Is There a New Economic Anthropology?’ Reviews in Anthropology, 9, 1982, 63–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Ian Steedman, Marx After Sraffa (London: New Left Books, 1977).Google Scholar
  72. I. Steedman, P. Sweezy et al., The Value Controversy (London: Verso Editions and NLB, 1981).Google Scholar
  73. E. Terray, Marxism and ‘Primitive’ Societies (London: Monthly Review Press, 1972).Google Scholar
  74. I. Wallerstein, The Modern World System (New York: Academic Press, 1974).Google Scholar
  75. I. Wallerstein, ‘Three Paths of National Development in Sixteenth-century Europe’,Studies in Comparative International Development, 7, 1972, 95–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. A. Wellmer, Critical Theory of Society (New York: Herder and Herder,1971).Google Scholar

Copyright information

© John Clammer 1987

Authors and Affiliations

  • Willie L. Baber

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations