Skip to main content

On a Certain Ambiguity in the Conception of Stationary Equilibrium

  • Chapter
Economic Science and Political Economy

Abstract

The idea of an equilibrium of forces is one which is common to many sciences, but there are few in which it plays a more important part than in theoretical economics. It has been implicit in our discussions since the time of the Physiocrats,1 and as the methods of economics have become more and more self-conscious it has become, in one shape or other, one of the main instruments of theoretical analysis. We describe the various forces we have to study by reference to their place in our conception of equilibrium. We measure their variations by reference to equilibrating norms. It is not too much to say that in so far as we pretend to enunciate economic laws at all it is the assumption that, within some limits, an equilibrium of some sort is conceivable that is the justification of our procedure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. See Joseph Schumpeter, Epochen der Dogmen- und Methodengeschichte (Tübingen, 1914), pp. 45–8, for a very interesting discussion of the Physiocratic contribution viewed in this aspect.

    Google Scholar 

  2. The argument of this paper was first developed in lectures on the history of theory which I delivered at New College [Oxford] in the winter 1928–29. At that time I thought that the contrast which I drew between static states according to suppositions concerning the supply schedules of the factors of production, although, of course, obvious to anyone familiar with mathematical economics, had not been made by any “literary economist.” Since then, however, I have discovered a footnote in Professor [F.H.] Knight’s Risk, Uncertainty and Profit [Boston, 1921] (p. 143) in which this is done, and, as I had read that admirable work many times, I suppose I must have been unconsciously influenced by Professor Knight’s comment. Professor Knight’s note is, however, very brief, and I therefore venture to hope that my historical exegesis and contemporary applications may not be altogether otiose.

    Google Scholar 

  3. On the significance of the Tableau Economique, see August Oncken, Oeuvres Economiques et Philosophiques de François Quesnay, fondateur du système physiocratique (Berner Beiträge zur Geschichte der Nationalokonomie No. 3; Frankfurt and Paris, 1888), pp. 386–402

    Google Scholar 

  4. also E. Cannan, A Review of Economic Theory (London, 1929), pp. 25–34

    Google Scholar 

  5. See, e.g., The Collected Works of David Ricardo, ed. J.R. McCulloch (London, 1852), pp. 59, 104, 120.

    Google Scholar 

  6. There is an interesting passage in the Letters of David Ricardo to Thomas Robert Malthus 1810–1823, ed. James Bonar (Oxford, 1887), p. 188, in which the distinction between stationariness and stagnation is discussed.

    Google Scholar 

  7. R. Torrens, An Essay on the External Corn Trade (London, 1820), p. 68.

    Google Scholar 

  8. On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, ed. J.R. McCulloch (London, 1852), p. 55.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Principles of Political Economy, ed. W.J. Ashley (London, 1909), pp. 248–75.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Memorials of Alfred Marshall, ed. A.C. Pigou (London, 1925), p. 415.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Principles of Economics, 8th edn (London, 1920), p. 369. For an interesting discussion of the contrast between Marshall’s “statical method” and Clark’s “static analysis” see Redvers Opie, “Die Quasirente in Marshalls Lehrgebäude,” Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, vol. 60 (1928), pp. 251–79. I suspect Mr. Opie of the opinion that the aversion from heroic abstraction was a virtue in Marshall in that it made his constructions more realistic. Personally I should be inclined to urge that in certain connections (increasing returns, for example) it was responsible for a good deal of theoretical confusion. This is not to say that Clark’s static state is superior to Marshall’s statical method, but rather that, as suggested above, the stationary state itself is superior to the more limited conception.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See, e.g., [F.Y.] Edgeworth’s review of Böhm-Bawerk’s The Positive Theory of Capital, Economic Journal, vol. 2 (June 1892), pp. 328–37

    Google Scholar 

  13. (reprinted in Papers relating to Political Economy [London, 1925], Vol. 3, pp. 22–30)

    Google Scholar 

  14. E. von Böhm-Bawerk, “Der letzte Masstab des Guterwertes,” Gesammelte Schriften, ed. F.X. Weiss (Vienna and Leipzig, 1924), pp. 404–70

    Google Scholar 

  15. David I. Green, “Pain-cost and opportunity-cost,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 8 (January 1894), pp. 218–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. H.J. Davenport, Value and Distribution: a critical and constructive study (Chicago, 1908)

    Google Scholar 

  17. P.H. Wicksteed, The Common Sense of Political Economy (London, 1910), Chapter IX.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Mr. [H.D.] Henderson’s Supply and Demand (London and Cambridge, 1922) may be regarded as indicating the definite abandonment of the old absolute conception of real costs.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Professor Pigou’s treatment of the real costs of war (The Political Economy of War [London, 1921], Chapter III) also follows the Austrian conception. But Mr. Henderson does not show very clearly how, if the supply of capital and labour are to be taken as variable, the resistances are to be worked into the opportunity cost concept. This, I think, has been more satisfactorily worked out by Professor Knight (Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Chapter III).

    Google Scholar 

  20. Thomas N. Carver, The Distribution of Wealth (New York, 1904).

    Google Scholar 

  21. M.H. Dobb, Wages (London and Cambridge, 1928), Chapters IV and V.

    Google Scholar 

  22. E.g. Adolphe Landry, whose L’Intérêt du Capital (Paris, 1904) is in many ways the best treatment of this important subject.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 1997 Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Robbins, L. (1997). On a Certain Ambiguity in the Conception of Stationary Equilibrium. In: Howson, S. (eds) Economic Science and Political Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-12761-0_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics