Advertisement

R

Chapter

Keywords

Interest Rate Monetary Policy Risk Aversion Central Bank Real Exchange Rate 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Bibliography

  1. Artis, M J. 1961. Liquidity and the attack on quantity theory. Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Statistics 23: 343–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Artis, M.J. and Lewis, M.K. 1984. How unstable is the demand for money in the UK? Economica 51: 473–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Cairncross, A. 1985. One hundred issues of’the Quarterly Bulletin. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 25: 381–7.Google Scholar
  4. Cobham, D. 1991. The money supply process. In Surveys in Monetary Economics, ed. C. Green and D. Llewellyn, vol. II, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  5. Coppock, DJ. and Gibson, N.J. 1963. The volume of deposits and the cash and liquid assets ratios. Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies 31: 203–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Crouch, R.L. 1963. A re-examination of open-market operations. Oxford Economic Papers 15: 81–94.Google Scholar
  7. Crouch, R.L. 1964. The inadequacy of new orthodox methods of monetary control. Economic Journal 74: 916–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Dacey, W.M. 1956. The floating debt problem. Lloyds Bank Review 40, April: 24–38.Google Scholar
  9. Gurley, J.G. and Shaw, E.S. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  10. Johnson, H.G. 1962. Monetary theory and policy. American Economic Review 52: 335–84.Google Scholar
  11. King, W.T.C. 1956. Should liquidity ratios be prescribed? The Banker 106, April: 186–97.Google Scholar
  12. Laidler, D. 1989. Radcliffe, the quantity theory and monetarism. In Money, Trade and Payments: Essays in honour of D.J. Coppock, ed. D. Cobham, R. Harrington and G. Zis, Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Macmillan Committee. 1931. Report of the Committee on Finance and Industry. London: HMSO, Cmnd. 3897.Google Scholar
  14. Radcliffe Committee. 1959. Report of the Committee on the Working of the Monetary System. London: HMSO, Cmnd. 827.Google Scholar
  15. Radcliffe Committee. 1960a. Principal Memoranda of Evidence 3 vols, London: HMSO.Google Scholar
  16. Radcliffe Committee. 1960b. Minutes of Evidence. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
  17. Roosa, R.V. 1959. The Radcliffe Report. Lloyds Bank Review 54, October: 1–13.Google Scholar
  18. Sayers, R.S. 1955. The determination of the volume of bank deposits: England 1955–56. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, 8:179–88.Google Scholar
  19. Sayers, R.S. 1960. Monetary thought and monetary policy in England. Economic Journal 70: 710–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Tobin, J. and Brainard, W.C. 1963. Financial intermediaries and the effectiveness of monetary policy. American Economic Review, (Papers and Proceedings) 53: 383–400.Google Scholar
  21. Altaian, E.I. 1973. Predicting railroad bankruptcies in America. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4(1): 184–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Carlos, A. and Lewis, F. The profitability of early Canadian railroads: evidence from the Grand Trunk and Great Western Railway Companies. In Strategic Factors in 19th Century American Economic History: A Volume to Honor Robert W. Fogel Chicago: University of Chicago Press, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  23. David, L.E. etal. 1972. American Economic Growth: An Economist’s History of the United States. New York: Harper and Row, ch. 13.Google Scholar
  24. Engerman, S.L. 1972. Some economic issues relating to railroad subsidies and the evaluation of land grunts. Journal of Economic History 32(3): 443–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Fishlow, A. 1965. American Railroads and the Transformation of the Ante-Bellum Economy. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  26. Fogel, R.W. 1960. The Union Pacific Railroad: A Case in Premature Enterprise. Baltimore MD: Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
  27. Fournier, L.T. 1935. Railway Nationalization in Canada: The Problem of the Canadian National Railways. Toronto: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  28. Gates, P.W. 1934. The Illinois Central and Its Colonization Work. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. George, P.J. 1968. Rates of return in railway investment and implications for government subsidization of the Canadian Pacific Railway: some preliminary results. Canadian Journal of Economics 1(4): 740–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Goodrich, C. 1960. Government Promotion of American Canals and Railroads, 1800–1890. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  31. Kirkland, E.C. 1948. Men, Cities, and Transportation: A Study in New England History, 1820–1900. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Lewis, F. and MacKinnon, M. 1987. Government loan guarantees and failure of the Canadian Northern Railway. Journal of Economic History 41 (1): 175–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Mercer, L J. 1982. Railroads and Land Grant Policy: A Study in Government Intervention. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  34. Stevens, G.R. 1962. Canadian National Railways, Volume 2: Towards the Inevitable, 1896–1922. Toronto: Clarke, Irwin.Google Scholar
  35. Taylor, G.R. and Nue, I.D. 1956. The American Railroad Network, 1861–1890. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Banz, R. 1981. The relationship between return and market value of common stocks. Journal of Financial Economics 9(1), March: 3–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Basu, S. 1977. Investment performance of common stocks in relation to their price-earnings ratios: a test of the efficient markets hypothesis. Journal of Finance 32(2), June: 663–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Black, F., Jensen, M. and Scholes, M. 1972. The capital asset pricing model: some empirical tests. In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, ed. M. Jensen, New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
  39. Chen, N.F. 1983. Some empirical tests of the theory of arbitrage pricing. Journal of Finance 38(5), December: 1393–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Chen, N.F., Roll, R. and Ross, S. 1986. Economic forces and the stock market. Journal of Business 59(3), July: 383–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Fama, E. 1975. Short term interest rates as predictors of inflation. American Economic Review 65(3), June: 269–82.Google Scholar
  42. Fama, E. 1984a. The information in the term structure. Journal of Financial Economics 13(3), December: 509–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Fama, E. 1984b. Term premiums in bond returns. Journal of Financial Economics 13(4), December: 529–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Fama, E. and Bliss, R. 1987. The information in long-maturity forward rates. American Economic Review 17(4), September: 680–92.Google Scholar
  45. Fisher, I. 1930. The Theory of Interest, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  46. Hess, P. and Bicksler, J. 1975. Capital asset prices versus time series models as predictors of inflation. Journal of Financial Economics 2(4), December: 341–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Hicks, J.R. 1946. Value and Capital, 2nd edn, London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  48. Hirshleifer, J. 1972. Liquidity, uncertainty, and the accumulation of information. In Essays in Honour of G.L.S. Shackle, ed. C.F. Carter and J.L. Ford, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  49. Ibbotson Associates, Inc. 1990. Stocks, Bonds, Bills and Inflation 1990 Yearbook: Market Results for 1926–1989. Chicago: Ibbotson Associates, Inc.Google Scholar
  50. Keim, D. 1983. Size-related anomalies and stock-market seasonality: further empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economies 12(1), June: 13–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Keim, D. 1985. Dividend yields and stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 14(3), September: 474–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Lintner, J. 1965a. Security prices, risk and the maximal gains from diversification. Journal of Finance 2(5), December: 587–616.Google Scholar
  53. Lintner, J. 1965b. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47(1), February: 13–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Litzenberger, R. and Ramaswamy, K. 1979. The effect of personal taxes and dividends on capital asset prices: theory and empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 7(2), June: 163–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Markowitz, H. 1952. Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance 7(1), March: 77–91.Google Scholar
  56. Markowitz, H. 1959. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Mossin, J. 1966. Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica 34(4), October: 768–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Nelson, C. and Schwert, G.W. 1977. Short-term interest rates as predictors of inflation: on testing the hypothesis that the real rate is constant. American Economic Review 67(3), June: 477–86.Google Scholar
  59. Reinganum, M. 1981. Misspecification of capital asset pricing: empirical anomalies based on earnings yields and market values. Journal of Financial Economics 9(1), March: 19–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Roll, R. and Ross, S. 1980. An empirical investigation of the arbitrage pricing theory. Journal of Finance 35(5), December: 1073–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Ross, S. 1976. The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13(3), December: 343–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Sharpe, W. 1964. Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19(3), September: 425–42.Google Scholar
  63. Tobin, J. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior toward risk. Review of Economic Studies 25(1), February: 65–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Treynor, J. 1965. How to rate management of investment funds. Harvard Business Review 43(1), January–February: 63–75.Google Scholar
  65. Woodward, S. 1983. The liquidity premium and the solidity premium. American Economic Review 73(3), June: 348–61.Google Scholar
  66. Blanchard, OJ. 1979. Speculative bubbles, crashes and rational expectations. Economics Letters 3: 387–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Blanchard, O.J. and Fischer, S. 1989. Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  68. Brock, W.A. 1982. Asset prices in a production economy. In The Economics of Information and Uncertainty, ed. J. McCall, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  69. Cutler, D.M., Poterba, J.M. and Summers, L.H. 1990. Speculative dynamics and the role of feedback traders. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceeding 80: 63–8.Google Scholar
  70. DeLong, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H. and Waldmann, R.J. 1989. The size and incidence of the losses from noise trading. Journal of Financed. 681–96.Google Scholar
  71. DeLong, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H. and Waldmann, R.J. 1990. Noise trader risk in financial markets. Journal of Political Economy 98: 703–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Dornbusch, R. 1976. Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84:1161–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Flood, R.P. and Garber, P.M. 1980. Market fundamentals versus price level bubbles: the first tests. Journal of Political Economy 88: 745–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Froot, K. and Obstfeld, M. 1989. Intrinsic bubbles: the case of stock prices. NBER working paper no. 3091, Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
  75. Garber, P.M. 1990. Famous first bubbles. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4, Spring: 35–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Meese, R.A. 1986. Testing for bubbles in exchange markets: a case of sparkling rates? Journal of Political Economy 94: 345–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Miller, M.H. and Weller, P.A. 1990. Currency bubbles which affect fundamentals: a qualitative treatment. Economic Journal, Conference Supplement, 100: 170–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. 1983. Speculative hyper inflations in maximizing models: can we rule them out? Journal of Political Economy 91: 675–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Tirole, J. 1982. On the possibility of speculation under rational expectations. Econometrica 50:1163–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Tirole, J. 1985. Asset bubbles and overlapping generations. Econometrica 53:1499–528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Weil, P. 1987. Confidence and the real value of money in overlapping generation models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 102:1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  82. West, K. 1987. A specification test for speculative bubbles. Quarterly Journal of Economics 102: 553–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. West, K. 1988. Bubbles, fads, and stock price volatility tests: a partial evaluation. Journal of Finance 43: 639–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Ahmed, S. 1987. Wage stickiness and the non-neutrality of money: a cross-industry analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 20, July: 25–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Altug, S. 1989. Time-to-build and aggregate fluctuations: some new evidence. International Economic Review 30(4), November: 889–920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. Barro, R.J. 1976. Rational expectations and the role of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 2, January: 1–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. Barro, R.J. 1977. Unanticipated money growth and unemployment in the United States. American Economic Review 67, March: 101–55.Google Scholar
  88. Barro, R.J. 1978. Unanticipated money, output and the price level in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 86, August: 549–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Barro, R.J. 1980. A capital market in an equilibrium business cycle model. Econometrica 48, September: 1393–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Barro, R.J. 1986. Comments on Eichenbaum and Singleton. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 1, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  91. Barro, R.J. and Hercowitz, Z. 1980. Money stock revisions and unanticipated money growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 6, April: 257–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Barro, R.J. and Rush, M. 1980. Unanticipated money and economic activity. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  93. Bils, M. 1985. Real wages over the business cycle: evidence from panel data. Journal of Political Economy 93, August: 666–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. Blanchard, O.J. and Kiyotaki, N. 1987. Monopolistic competition and the effects of aggregate demand. American Economic Review 77, September: 647–66.Google Scholar
  95. Boschen, J. and Grossman, H.I. 1982. Tests of equilibrium macroeconomics using contemporaneous monetary data. Journal of Monetary Economics 10, November: 309–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. Carlton, D. 1986. The rigidity of prices. American Economic Review 76, September: 637–58.Google Scholar
  97. Edwards, M. 1981. Informational equilibrium in a monetary theory of the business cycle. Unpublished working paper, University of Rochester.Google Scholar
  98. Eichenbaum, M. and Singleton, K. 1986. Do equilibrium real business cycle theories explain post-war U.S. fluctuations? NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 1, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press; erratum Vol. 2 (1987).Google Scholar
  99. Fischer, S. 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85, February: 191–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  100. Fischer, S. 1980. On activist monetary policy with rational expectations. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  101. Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A.J. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  102. Goodfriend, M. 1987. Interest rate smoothing and price level trend-statioriarity. Journal of Monetary Economics 19, May: 335–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  103. Gray, J. 1976. Wage indexation: a macroeconomic approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 2, April: 221–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  104. Haberler, G. 1937. Prosperity and Depression. Geneva: League of Nations.Google Scholar
  105. Hall, R.J. 1980. Comments on chapters 6 and 7. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  106. Hansen, G. 1985. Indivisible labor and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 16, November: 309–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  107. Haraf, W. 1983. Tests of a rational expectations structural neutrality model with persistent effects of monetary disturbances. Journal of Monetary Economics 11, January: 103–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  108. Hicks, J.R. 1933. Equilibrium and the cycle. Reprinted in J.R. Hicks, Money, Interest and Wages: Collected Essays in Economic Theory, vol. 2, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
  109. Hodrick, RJ. and Prescott, E.C. 1980. Post-war U.S. business cycles: an empirical investigation. Working paper no. 451, revised, Carnegie-Mellon University.Google Scholar
  110. King, R.G. 1981. Monetary information and monetary neutrality. Journal of Monetary Economics 7, March: 195–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  111. King, R.G. and Plosser, C.I. 1984. Money, credit, and prices in a real business cycle. American Economic Review 74, June: 363–80.Google Scholar
  112. King, R.G., Plosser, C.I. and Rebelo, S.T. 1988. Production growth and business cycles: the basic neoclassical model. Journal of Monetary Economics 21, March/May: 195–232.Google Scholar
  113. King, R.G. and Rebelo, S. 1986. Business cycles with endogenous growth. Unpublished working paper. University of Rochester, March.Google Scholar
  114. King, R.G. and Trehan B. 1984. Money: endogeneity and neutrality. Journal of Monetary Economics 14, November: 385–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  115. Kretzmer, P.E. 1989. The cross-industry effects of unanticipated money in an equilibrium business cycle model. Journal of Monetary Economics 22, March: 275–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  116. Kydland, F. and Prescott, E.C. 1982. Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50, November: 1345–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  117. Leiderman, L. 1983. The response of real wages to unanticipated money growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 11, January: 73–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  118. Long, J.B. and Plosser, C.I. 1983. Real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy 91, February: 39–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  119. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1972a. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4, April: 103–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  120. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1972b. Econometric testing of the Natural Rate Hypothesis. In The Econometrics of Price Determination, ed. O. Eckstein, Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.Google Scholar
  121. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1973. Some international evidence on output-inflation tradeoffs. American Economic Review 63, June: 326–34.Google Scholar
  122. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1975. An equilibrium model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 83, December: 1113–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  123. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1977. Understanding business cycles. In Stabilization of the Domestic and International Economy, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 5, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  124. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1980. Methods and problems in business cycle theory. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 12(2), November: 696–715.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  125. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1987. Models of Business Cycles. New York: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  126. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1988. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22, July: 3–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  127. McCallum, B.T. 1980. Rational expectations and macroeconomic stabilization policy: an overview. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 12(2), November: 716–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  128. McCallum, B.T. 1982. Macroeconomics after a decade of rational expectations: some critical issues. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 68, November/December: 3–12.Google Scholar
  129. McCallum, B.T. 1986. On ‘real’ and ‘sticky price’ theories of the business cycle. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 18, November: 397–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  130. Mankiw, N.G. 1985. Small menu costs and large business cycles: a macroeconomic model of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, May: 529–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  131. Merrick, J J. Jr. 1983. Financial market efficiency, the decomposition of ‘anticipated’ versus ‘unanticipated’ money growth, and further tests of the relation between money, and real output. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 15, May: 222–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  132. Mishkin, F.S. 1982. Does anticipated money matter? An econometric investigation. Journal of Political Economy 90, February: 22–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  133. Mitchell, W.C. 1951. What Happens During Business Cycles. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  134. Muth, J.F. 1961. Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica 29, July: 315–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  135. Nelson, CR. and Plosser, C.I. 1982. Trends and random walks in macroeconomic times series: some evidence and implications. Journal of Monetary Economics 10, September: 139–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  136. Phelps, E.S. 1967. Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time. Economica 34, August: 254–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  137. Phelps, E.S. and Taylor, J.B. 1977. Stabilizing powers of monetary policy under rational expectations. Journal of Political Economy 85, February: 163–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  138. Prescott, E.C. 1986. Theory ahead of business-cycle measurement. In Real Business Cycles, Real Exchange Rates and Actual Policies. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 25, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  139. Rogerson, R. 1988. Indivisible labor, lotteries and equilibrium. Journal of Monetary Economics 21, January: 3–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  140. Rotemberg, J. 1982. Sticky prices in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 90, December: 1187–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  141. Sargent, T.J. 1973. Rational expectations, the real rate of interest, and the natural rate of unemployment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 429–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  142. Sargent, T.J. 1976. A classical macroeconomic model for the United States. Journal of Political Economy 84, April: 207–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  143. Sargent, T.J. 1979. Granger causality and the natural rate hypothesis. Journal of Political Economy 87, April: 213–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  144. Sargent, T.J. 1981. Interpreting economic time series. Journal of Political Economy 89, April: 213–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  145. Sargent, T.J. and Wallace, N. 1975. Rational expectations, the optimal monetary instrument and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 83, April: 241–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  146. Sims, C.H. 1980. Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica 48, January: 1–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  147. Taylor, J.B. 1979. Staggered wage setting in a macro model. American Economic Review 69, May: 108–113.Google Scholar
  148. Taylor, J.B. 1980. Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88, February: 1–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  149. Tinbergen, J. 1939: Statistical Testing of Business Cycle Theories: Business Cycles in the United States of America1919–1932. Geneva: League of Nations.Google Scholar
  150. Barro, RJ. 1979. On the determination of the public debt. Journal of Political Economy 87(5), October: 940–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  151. Brock, W.A. 1982. Asset prices in a production economy. In Economics of Information and Uncertainty, ed. J.J. McCall, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1–43.Google Scholar
  152. Brock, W.A. and Mirman, L. 1972. Optimal economic growth under uncertainty: the discounted case. Journal of Economic Theory 4(3), June: 479–513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  153. Friedman, M. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  154. Grandmont, J.M. 1985. On endogenous competitive business cycles. Econometrica 53(5): 995–1045.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  155. Hansen, L.P. and Sargent, T.J. 1980. Formulating and estimating dynamic linear rational expectations models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 2(1): 7–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  156. Hansen, L.P. and Singleton, K.J. 1982. Generalized instrumental variables estimation of nonlinear rational expectation models. Econometrica 50(5), September: 1269–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  157. Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. 1982. Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50(6): 1345–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  158. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: a critique. In The Phillips Curve and the Labor Market, ed. K. Brunner and A. Meltzer, Vol. 1 of Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, a supplementary series to the Journal of Monetary Economics, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  159. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1978. Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46(6): 1429–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  160. Lucas, R.E., Jr. and Prescott, E.C. 1971. Investment under uncertainty. Econometrica 39(5): 659–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  161. Lucas, R.E., Jr. and Stokey, N. 1983. Optimal fiscal and monetary policy in an economy without capital. Journal of Monetary Economics 12(1), July: 55–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  162. Muth, J.F. 1960. Optimal properties of exponentially weighted forecasts. Journal of the American Statistical Association 55(290): 299–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  163. Muth, J.F. 1961. Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica 29(3): 315–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  164. Nerlove, M. 1967. Distributed lags and unobserved components in economic time series. In W. Fellner et al., Ten Economic Studies in the Tradition of Irving Fisher, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  165. Novales, A. 1984. A stochastic monetary equilibrium model of the interest rate. Discussion paper, State University of New York at Stony Brook.Google Scholar
  166. Romer, P.M. 1983. Externalities and increasing returns in dynamic competitive analysis. Working paper No. 8319, Department of Economics, University of Rochester.Google Scholar
  167. Samuelson, P.A. 1958. An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of’money. Journal of Political Economy 66(6): 467–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  168. Sargent, T.J. 1984. Autoregressions, expectations, and advice. American Economic Review 74(2), May: 408–15.Google Scholar
  169. Sargent, T.J. and Wallace, N. 1976. Rational expectations and the theory of economic policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 2(2): 169–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  170. Sims, C.A. 1972. Money, income, and causality. American Economic Review 62(4): 540–52.Google Scholar
  171. Sims, C.A. 1982. Policy analysis with econometric models. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 107–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  172. Sims, C.A. 1985. Solving nonlinear stochastic equilibrium models backwards. Manuscript, University of Minnesota, Economic Research Center.Google Scholar
  173. Townsend, R.M. 1980. Models of money with spatially separated agents. In Models of Monetary Economies, ed. J.H. Kareken and N. Wallace, Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 265–305.Google Scholar
  174. Wallace, N. 1981a. A Modigliani-Miller theorem for open market operations. American Economic Review 71(3): 267–74.Google Scholar
  175. Wallace, N. 1981b. A hybrid fiat-commodity monetary system. Journal of Economic Theory 25(3): 421–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  176. Wallace, N. 1983. A legal restrictions theory of the demand for ‘money’ and the role of monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 7(1): 1–7.Google Scholar
  177. Whittle, P. 1963. Prediction and Regulation by Linear Least-Square Methods. 2nd edn revised, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1983.Google Scholar
  178. Aoki, A. and Canzoneri, M. 1979. Reduced forms of rational expectations models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 93: 59–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  179. Blanchard, O.J. 1979. Backward and forward solutions for economies with rational expectations. American Economic Review 69:114–18.Google Scholar
  180. Blanchard, O.J. and Kahn, CM. 1980. The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations. Econometrica 48: 1305–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  181. Blume, L., Bray, M.M. and Easley, D. 1982. Introduction to the stability of rational expectations equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 313–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  182. Bray, M.M. 1982. Learning estimation, and the stability of rational expectations. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 318–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  183. Bray, M.M. 1983. Convergence to rational expectations equilibrium. In Individual Forecasting and Aggregate Outcomes, ed. R. Frydman and E.S. Phelps, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  184. Bray, M.M. and Kreps, D. 1986. Rational learning and rational expectations. In Essays in Honour of K.J. Arrow, ed. W. Heller, R. Starr and D. Starrett, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  185. Bray, M.M. and Savin, N.E. 1986. Rational expectations equilibria, learning and model specification. Econometrica 57: 1129–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  186. Broze, L., Gourieroux, C. and Szafarz, A. 1985. Solutions of linear rational expectations models. Econometric Theory 1: 341–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  187. Deaton, A. 1986. Life-cycle models of consumption: is the evidence consistent with the theory? Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University, Mimeo.Google Scholar
  188. Durlauf, S.N. and Phillips, P.C.B. 1988. Trends versus random walks in time series analysis. Econometrica 56: 1333–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  189. Eichenbaum, M.S. 1983. A rational expectations equilibrium model of finished goods and employment. Journal of Monetary Economics 12:259–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  190. Engle, R.F., Hendry, D.F. and Richard, J.-F. 1983. Exogeneity. Econometrica 50: 227–304.Google Scholar
  191. Evans, G. 1985. Expectational stability and multiple solutions in linear rational expectations models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99: 1217–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  192. Evans, G. and Honkapohja, S. 1986. A complete characterization of ARMA solutions to linear rational expectations models. Review of Economic Studies 53: 227–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  193. Fair, R.C. and Taylor, J.B. 1983. Solution and maximum likelihood estimation of dynamic nonlinear rational expectations models. Econometrica 51, July: 1169–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  194. Fourgeaud, C, Gourieroux, C. and Pradel, J. 1986. Learning procedures and convergence to rationality. Econometrica 54(4): 845–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  195. Frydman, R. 1982. Towards an understanding of market processes: individual expectations, learning and convergence to rational expectations equilibrium. American Economic Review 72: 652–68.Google Scholar
  196. Futia, C.A. 1981. Rational expectations in stationary linear models. Econometrica 49: 171–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  197. Gourieroux, C, Laffont, J.J. and Monfort, A. 1982. Rational expectations in linear models: analysis of solutions. Econometrica 50: 409–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  198. Hansen, L.P. 1982. Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica 50: 1029–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  199. Hansen, L.P. and Sargent, T.J. 1980. Formulating and estimating dynamic linear rational expectations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 2: 7–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  200. Hansen, J.P. and Singleton, K.J. 1982. Generalized instrumental variable estimation of nonlinear rational expectations models. Econometrica 50:1269–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  201. Kennan, J. 1979. The estimation of partial adjustment models with rational expectations. Econometrica 47: 1441–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  202. Kohlberg, E. and Mertens, J.-F. 1986. On the strategic stability of equilibria. Econometrica 57: 1003–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  203. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1972. Econometric testing of the natural rate hypothesis. In Econometrics of Price Determination Conference, ed. O. Eckstein, Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.Google Scholar
  204. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1975. An equilibrium model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 83:1113–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  205. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: a critique. In The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, Vol. 1, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  206. Marcet, A. and Sargent, TJ. 1989. Convergence of least squares learning mechanisms in self referential linear stochastic models. Journal of Economic Theory 48: 337–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  207. McCallum, B.T. 1983. On non-uniqueness in rational expectations models: an attempt at perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics 11:139–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  208. Muth, J.F. 1961. Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica 29: 315–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  209. Nelson, C.R. and Plosser, C. 1982. Trends and random walk in macroeconomic time series: some evidence and implications. Journal of Monetary Economics 10: 139–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  210. Nelson, C.R. and Kang, H. 1981. Spurious periodicity in inappropriately detrended time series. Econometrica 49: 741–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  211. Nelson, C.R. and Kang, H. 1983. Pitfalls in the use of time as an explanatory variable in regression. NBER Technical Working Paper No. 30.Google Scholar
  212. Radner, R. 1982. Equilibrium under uncertainty. In Handbook of Mathematical Economics, Vol. II, ed. K.J. Arrow and M.D. Intriligator, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  213. Saracoglu, R. and Sargent, T.J. 1978. Seasonality and portfolio balance under rational expectations. Journal of Monetary Economics 4:511–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  214. Sargent, T.J. 1979. Macroeconomic Theory. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  215. Sargent, T.J. 1981. Interpreting economic time series. Journal of Political Economy 89: 403–10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  216. Selten, R. 1965. Spiel theoretische Behandlungeines Oligopomodells mit Nachfragetragheit. Zeitschrift fur die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft 122: 301–24.Google Scholar
  217. Selten, R. 1975. A re-examination of the perfectness concept for equilibrium points in extensive games. International Journal of Game Theory 4: 25–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  218. Sims, C.A. 1982. Policy analysis with econometric models. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity No. 1: 107–52.Google Scholar
  219. Taylor, J.B. 1977. Conditions for unique solutions in stochastic macroeconomic models with rational expectations. Econometrica 45:1337–85.Google Scholar
  220. Townsend, R.M. 1978. Market anticipations, rational expectations and Bayesian analysis. International Economic Review 19: 481–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  221. Townsend, R.M. 1983. Forecasting the forecasts of others. Journal of Political Economy 91: 545–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  222. Whiteman, C.H. 1983. Linear Rational Expectations Models. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
  223. Admati, A.R. 1985. A noisy rational expectations equilibrium for multi-asset securities markets. Econometrica 53(3): 629–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  224. Admati, A.R. and Pfleiderer, P. 1986. A monopolistic market for information. Journal of Economic Theory 39(2): 400–438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  225. Admati, A.R. and Pfleiderer, P. 1990. Direct and indirect sale of information. Econometrica 49(4): 901–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  226. Allen, B. 1982. Strict rational expectations equilibria with diffuseness. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 20–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  227. Bray, M. 1981. Futures trading, rational expectations and the efficient markets hypothesis. Econometrica 49(3): 578–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  228. Bray, M. 1982. Learning, estimation and the stability of rational expectations. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 318–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  229. Bray, M. 1985. Rational expectations, information and asset markets: an introduction. Oxford Economic Papers 37: 161–95.Google Scholar
  230. Danthine, J.P. 1978. Information, futures prices and stabilizing speculation. Journal of Economic Theory 17(1): 79–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  231. Diamond, D.W. and Verrecchia, R.E. 1981. Information aggregation in a noisy rational expectations economy. Journal of Financial Economics 9(3): 221–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  232. Gould, J.P. and Verrecchia, R.E. 1985. The information content of specialist pricing. Journal of Political Economy 93(1): 66–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  233. Green, J. 1977. The non-existence of informational equilibria. Review of Economic Studies 44: 451–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  234. Grinblatt, M.S. and Ross, S.A. 1985. Market power in a securities market with endogenous information. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100(4): 1143–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  235. Grossman, S.J. 1976. On the efficiency of competitive stock markets where traders have diverse information. Journal of Finance 31: 573–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  236. Grossman, S.J. 1977. The existence of futures markets, noisy rational expectations, and informational externalities. Review of Economic Studies 44: 431–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  237. Grossman, S.J. and Stiglitz, J.E. 1980. On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. American Economic Review 70: 393–408.Google Scholar
  238. Hellwig, M.R. 1980. On the aggregation of information in competitive markets. Journal of Economic Theory 22: 477–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  239. Jordan, J.S. and Radner, R. 1982. Rational expectations in microeconomic models: an overview. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 201–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  240. Kreps, D. 1977. A note on fulfilled expectations equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory 14: 32–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  241. Kyle, A.S. 1985. Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53(5): 1315–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  242. Kyle, A.S. 1989. Informed speculation with imperfect competition. Review of Economic Studies 56(3): 317–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  243. Muth, J.F. 1961. Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica 29, July: 315–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  244. Radner, R. 1979. Rational expectations equilibrium, generic existence and the information revealed by prices. Econometrica 47: 655–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  245. Verrecchia, R.E. 1982. Information acquisition in a noisy rational expectations economy. Econometrica 50(6): 1415–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  246. American Economie Association. 1951. Reading? in Monetary Theory. Philadelphia: Blakiston.Google Scholar
  247. Barro, R.J. 1974. Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy 82, November–December: 1095–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  248. Barro, R.J. and Grossman, H.I. 1976. Money, Employment and Inflation. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  249. Fischer, S. 1981. Is there a real-balance effect in equilibrium? Journal of Monetary Economics 8, July: 25–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  250. Gurley, J.G. and Shaw, E.S. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  251. Haberler, G. von 1941. Prosperity and Depression: A Theoretical Analysis of Cyclical Movements. 3rd edn, Geneva: League of Nations; Lake Success, New York: United Nations, 1946.Google Scholar
  252. Hicks, J.R. 1937. Mr Keynes and the ‘classics’: a suggested interpretation. Econometrica 5, April, 147–59. Reprinted in Reading? in the Theory of Income Distribution, Philadelphia: Blakiston for the American Economic Association, 1946.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  253. Jonson, P.D. 1976. Money and economic activity in the open economy: the United Kingdom, 1880–1970. Journal of Political Economy 84, October: 979–1012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  254. Kalecki, M. 1944. Professor Pigou on ‘The classical stationary state’: a comment. Economic Journal 54, April: 131–2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  255. Keynes, J.M. 1923. A Tract on Monetary Reform. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  256. Keynes, J.M. 1930.Treatise on Money. Vol. I: The Pure Theory of Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  257. Keynes, J.M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  258. Laidler, D. and Bentley, B. 1983. A small macro-model of the post-war United States. Manchester School 51, December: 317–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  259. Leontief, W. 1936. The fundamental assumption of Mr Keynes monetary theory of unemployment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 51, November: 192–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  260. Mayer, T. 1959. The empirical significance of the real balance effect. Quarterly Journal of Economics 73, May: 275–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  261. McCallum, B.T. 1983. The liquidity trap and the Pigou effect: a dynamic analysis with rational expectations. Economica 50, November: 395–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  262. Mishan, E.J. 1958. A fallacy in the interpretation of the cash balance effect. Economica 25, May: 106–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  263. Modigliani, F. 1944. Liquidity preference and the theory of interest and money. Econometrica 12, January: 45–88. Reprinted in American Economic Association (1951): 186–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  264. Patinkin, D. 1948. Price flexibility and full employment. American Economic Review 38, September: 543–64.Google Scholar
  265. Reprinted with revisions and additions in American Economic Association (1951): 252–83; revised version reprinted in Patinkin 1972b.Google Scholar
  266. Patinkin, D. 1956. Money, Interest, and Prices. Evanston, Ill.: Row, Peterson.Google Scholar
  267. Patinkin, D. 1965. Money, Interest, and Prices. 2nd edn, New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  268. Patinkin, D. 1967. On the Nature of the Monetary Mechanism. Stockholm: Almqvist and Wicksell. Reprinted in Patinkin (1972b): 143–67.Google Scholar
  269. Pantinkin, D. 1969. Money and wealth: a review article. Journal of Economic Literature 7 December: 1140–60.Google Scholar
  270. Patinkin, D. 1972a. Money and wealth. In Patinkin (1972b): 168–94.Google Scholar
  271. Patinkin, D. 1972b. Studies in Monetary Economics. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  272. Patinkin, D. 1976. Keynes Monetary Thought: A Study of Its Development. Durham, North Carolina: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
  273. Pesek, B.P. and Saving, T.R. 1967. Money, Wealth and Economic Theory. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  274. Phelps, E.S. 1972. Money, public expenditure and labor supply. Journal of Economic Theory 5, August: 69–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  275. Pigou, A.C. 1943. The classical stationary state. Economic Journal 53, December: 343–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  276. Pigou, A.C. 1947. Economic progress in a stable environment. Economica 14, August: 180–88. Reprinted in American Economic Association (1951): 241–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  277. Scitovsky, T. 1941. Capital accumulation, employment and price rigidity. Review of Economic Studies 8, February: 69–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  278. Sweeney, R.J. 1988. Wealth Effects and Monetary Theory. New York: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  279. Tanner, J.E. 1970. Empirical evidence on the short-run real balance effect in Canada. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 2, November: 473–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  280. Tobin, J. 1975. Keynesian models of recession and depression. American Economic Review 65, May: 195–202.Google Scholar
  281. Balasko, Y. and Shell, K. 1983. Lump-sum taxation: the static economy. In General Equilibrium and Growth: The Legacy of Lionel McKenzie, ed. R. Becker, M. Boldrin, R. Jones and W. Thomson, New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  282. Balasko, Y. and Shell, K. 1986. Lump-sum taxes and transfers: public debt in the overlapping generations model. In Essays in Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow, Volume II: Equilibrium Analysis, ed. W. Heller, R. Starr and D. Starrett, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  283. Chamley, C. and Polemarchakis, H. 1984. Assets, general equilibrium, and the neutrality of money. Review of Economic Studies 51:129–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  284. Champ, B., Smith, B.D. and Williamson, S.D. 1991. Currency elasticity and banking panics: theory and evidence. Discussion paper 91–14, Center for Analytic Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.Google Scholar
  285. Fetter, F.W. 1965. The Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy, 1797–1875. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  286. Friedman, M. 1960. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham University Press.Google Scholar
  287. Gale, D. 1973. Pure exchange equilibrium of dynamic economic models. Journal of Economic Theory 6: 12–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  288. Highfield, R., O’Hara, M. and Smith, B.D. 1991. Irrelevance of open market operations with a privately owned central bank. Manuscript, Cornell University, Ithaca.Google Scholar
  289. Mints, L.W. 1945. A History of Banking Theory in Great Britain and the United States. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
  290. Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review 48: 261–97.Google Scholar
  291. Sargent, T.J. 1982. The ends of four big inflations. In Inflation: Causes and Effects, ed. R. Hall, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  292. Sargent, T.J. and Smith, B.D. 1987a. Irrelevance of open market operations in some economies with government currency being dominated in rate of return. American Economic Review 11: 78–92.Google Scholar
  293. Sargent, T.J. and Smith, B.D. 1987b. The irrelevance of government foreign exchange operations. In Economic Effects of the Government Budget, ed. E. Helpman, A. Razin and E. Sadka, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  294. Sargent, T.J. and Smith, B.D. 1988. The timing of tax collections and the structure of irrelevance theorems in a cash-in-advance model. Manuscript, Hoover Institution, Stanford.Google Scholar
  295. Sargent, T.J. and Wallace, N. 1982. The real-bills doctrine versus the quantity theory: a reconsideration. Journal of Political Economy 90:1212–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  296. Smith, A. 1776. The Wealth of Nations. London; reprinted, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976.Google Scholar
  297. Smith, B.D. 1985a. American colonial monetary regimes: the failure of the quantity theory and some evidence in favour of an alternate view. Canadian Journal of Economics 18: 531–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  298. Smith, B.D. 1985b. Some colonial evidence on two theories of money: Maryland and the Carolinas. Journal of Political Economy 93:1178–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  299. Smith, B.D. 1988. Legal restrictions, ‘sunspots’ and Peel’s Bank Act: the real-bills doctrine versus the quantity theory reconsidered. Journal of Political Economy 96: 3–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  300. Smith, B.D. 1991. Efficiency and determinacy of equilibrium under inflation targeting. Manuscript, Cornell University, Ithaca.Google Scholar
  301. Sosin, J.M. 1964. Imperial regulation of colonial paper money, 1764–1773. Pennsylvania Magazine of History and Biography: 174–98.Google Scholar
  302. Stiglitz, J.E. 1969. A re-examination of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem. American Economic Review 59: 784—93.Google Scholar
  303. Timberlake, R.H. 1978. The Origins of Central Banking in the United States. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  304. Tobin, J. 1963. Commercial banks as creators of ‘money’. In Banking and Monetary Studies, ed. D. Carson, Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.Google Scholar
  305. Wallace, N. 1981. A Modigliani-Miller Theorem for open market operations. American Economic Review 71: 267–74.Google Scholar
  306. Cantillon, R. 1755. Essai sur la nature du commerce en général. Trans. H. Higgs, London: Macmillan, 1931.Google Scholar
  307. Deane, P. 1979. Inflation in History. In Perspectives on Inflation, Models and Policies, ed. D. Heathfield, London: Longman, 1979.Google Scholar
  308. Fullarton, J. 1844. On the Regulation of Currencies. London: John Murray.Google Scholar
  309. Green, R. 1991. Classical Theories of Money, Output and Inflation: A Study in Historical Economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  310. Heathfield, D. (ed.) 1979. Perspectives on Inflation: Models and Policies. London: Longman.Google Scholar
  311. Hobson, J. A. 1913. Gold, Prices and Wages, with an Examination of the Quantity Theory. London: Methuen; reprinted Clifton, N.J.: Kelley, 1973.Google Scholar
  312. Hume, D. 1752. Essays, Literary, Moral and Political. London: Ward, Lock & Co.Google Scholar
  313. Law, J. 1705. Money and Trade Considered. Edinburgh: Anderson.Google Scholar
  314. Marshall, A. 1923. Money, Credit and Commerce. London: Macmillan; New York: Augustus Kelley, 1965.Google Scholar
  315. Marx, K. 1859. A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1970.Google Scholar
  316. Marx, K. 1867–94. Capital. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1971; New York, International Publishers, 1967.Google Scholar
  317. Marx, K. 1972. Grundrisse. Harmondsworth: Penguin.Google Scholar
  318. Morgan, E.V. 1965. The Theory and Practice of Central Banking, 1797–1913. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  319. Petty, W. 1899. The Economic Writings of Sir William Petty. Ed. C.H. Hull, New York: Augustus Kelley, 1963.Google Scholar
  320. Ricardo, D. 1923. Economic Essays. Ed. E.C.K. Gonner, London: Frank Cass & Co.Google Scholar
  321. Ricardo, D. 1951–73. The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo. Ed. P. Sraffa, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  322. Rist, C. 1940. History of Monetary and Credit Theory from John Law to the Present Day. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  323. Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Roudedge, 1890; New York, Modern Library, 1937.Google Scholar
  324. Steuart, J. 1767. An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Oeconomy. Edinburgh: Oliver & Boyd, 1966.Google Scholar
  325. Thornton, H. 1802. A Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain. London. Ed. with an introduction by F.A. von Hayek, London: George Allen & Unwin, 1939; reprinted, New York: Augustus Kelley, 1962.Google Scholar
  326. Tooke, T. 1838–57. A History of Prices and of the State of the Circulation from 1792 to 1856. London: P.S. King, 1928.Google Scholar
  327. Tooke, T. 1844. An Inquiry into the Currency Principle. 2nd edn, Series of Reprints of Scarce Works of Political Economy 15, London: London School of Economics and Political Science, 1959Google Scholar
  328. Andersen, P.S. 1990. Developments in external and internal balances. Bank for International Settlements Economic Papers 29, October.Google Scholar
  329. Balassa, B. 1964. The purchasing-power parity doctrine: a reappraisal. Journal of Political Economy 72, December: 584–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  330. Branson, W.H. 1983. Macroeconomic determinants of real exchange risk. In Managing Foreign Exchange Risk, ed. R.J. Herring: Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  331. Dixit, A.K. and Norman, V. 1980. Theory of International Trade: A Dual, General Equilibrium Approach. Welwyn: James Nesbitt.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  332. Dornbusch, R. 1976. Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84: 1116–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  333. Edwards, S. 1989. Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation and Adjustment. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  334. Fisher, P.G., Tanna, S.K., Turner, D.S., Wallis, K.F. and Whidey, J.D. 1990. Econometric evaluation of the exchange rate in models of the UK economy. Economic Journal 100(403): 1230–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  335. Frankel, J. A. 1979. On the Mark: a theory of floating exchange rates based on real interest differentials. American Economic Review 69: 610–22.Google Scholar
  336. Kravis, I., Heston, A. and Summers, R. 1978. International Comparisons of Real Product and Purchasing Power. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
  337. Neary, P. 1988. Determinants of the equilibrium real exchange rate. American Economic Review 78(1), March: 210–15.Google Scholar
  338. Blanchard, OJ. and Summers, L.H. 1984. Perspectives on high world real interest rates. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 273–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  339. Boschen, J.F. and Newman, J.L. 1987. The effects of expected inflation on real returns in the Argentine index bond market. Economics Letters 25:13 7–42.Google Scholar
  340. Boschen, J.F. and Newman, J.L. 1989. Monetary effects on the real interest rate in an open economy: evidence from the Argentine index bond market. Journal of International Money and Finance 8: 201–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  341. Cochrane, J.H. 1989. The return of the liquidity effect: a study of the short-run relation between money growth and interest rates. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 7: 77–83.Google Scholar
  342. Fama, E.F. 1975. Short-term interest rates as predictors of inflation. American Economic Review 65: 269–82.Google Scholar
  343. Fama, E.F. and Gibbons, M.R. 1982. Inflation, real returns and capital investment. Journal of Monetary Economics 9: 297–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  344. Fried, J. and Howitt, P. 1983. The effects of inflation on real interest rates. American Economic Review 73: 968–80.Google Scholar
  345. Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58: 1–7.Google Scholar
  346. Grossman, S. and Weiss, L. 1983. A transactions-based model of the monetary transmission mechanism. American Economic Review 73: 1–17.Google Scholar
  347. Huizinga, J. and Mishkin, F.S. 1986. Monetary policy regime shifts and the unusual behavior of real interest rates. In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 24, ed. K. Brunner and A. Meltzer, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  348. Litterman, R.B. and Weiss, L. 1985. Money, real interest rates, and output: a reinterpretation of postwar US data. Econometrica 53: 129–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  349. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1990. Liquidity and interest rates. Journal of Economic Theory 50: 237–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  350. McCallum, B.T. 1984. On low-frequency estimates of long-run relations in macroeconomics. Journal of Monetary Economics 14: 3–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  351. Mishkin, F.S. 1981. The real interest rate: an empirical investigation. In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 15, ed. K. Brunner and A. Meltzer, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  352. Mishkin, F.S. 1983. A Rational Expectations Approach to Macroeconometrics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  353. Mishkin, F.S. 1984. The real interest rate: a multicountry empirical study. Canadian Journal of Economics 17: 283–311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  354. Mundell, R. 1963. Inflation and real interest. Journal of Political Economy 71: 280–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  355. Reichenstein, W. 1987. The impact of money on short-term interest rates. Economic Inquiry 25: 67–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  356. Shiller, R.J. 1980. Can the Fed control real interest rates? In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  357. Sidrauski, M. 1967. Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy. American Economic Review 57: 534—44.Google Scholar
  358. Summers, L.H. 1983. The maladjustment of nominal interest rates: a study of the Fisher effect. In Macroeconomics, Prices, and Quantities: Essays in Memory of Arthur M. Okun ed. J. Tobin, Washington: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  359. Tobin, J. 1965. Money and economic growth. Econometrica 33: 671–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  360. Wilcox, J.A. 1983. Why real interest rates were so low in the 1970s. American Economic Review 73: 44–53.Google Scholar
  361. Froude, J.A. 1856–70. History of England. London.Google Scholar
  362. Macaulay, T.B. 1848, 1855, 1861. The History of England from the Accession of James the Second. London: Longman.Google Scholar
  363. Ruding, R. 1840. Annals of Coinage. 3rd edn, London: Nichols, Son and Bentley.Google Scholar
  364. United States. Annual Reports of the Director of the Mint. (Reports state annual recoinages of every important country.)Google Scholar
  365. Backus, D.K. and Driffill, E.J. 1985a. Inflation and reputation. American Economic Review 75(3): 530–38.Google Scholar
  366. Backus, D.K. and Driffill, E.J. 1985b. Rational expectations and policy credibility following a change in regime. Review of Economic Studies LII: 211–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  367. Baxter, M. 1985. The role of expectations in stabilization policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 15: 343–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  368. Bruno, M., Telia, G. di, Dornbusch, R. and Fischer, S. 1988. Inflation Stabilization: The Experience of Israel, Argentina, Brazil Bolivia, and Mexico. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  369. Buiter, W.H. and Miller, M.H. 1981. Monetary policy and international competitiveness: the problems of adjustment. In The Money Supply and the Exchange Rate, ed. W.A. Eltis and P.J.N. Sinclair, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  370. Calvo, G. 1988. Servicing the public debt: the role of expectations. American Economic Review 78(4): 647–61.Google Scholar
  371. Goldfeld, S.M. and Quandt, R.E. 1973. A Markov model for switching regressions. Journal of Econometrics 1: 3–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  372. Hamilton, J.D. 1988. Rational expectations econometric analysis of changes in regime: an investigation of the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12: 385–423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  373. Hamilton, J.D. 1989. A new approach to the economic analysis of non-stationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica 57(2): 357–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  374. Hamilton, J.D. 1990. Analysis of time series subject to changes in regime. Journal of Econometrics 45: 39–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  375. Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E. 1977. Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85:473–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  376. Leiderman, L. and Blejer, M.I. 1987. The term structure of interest rates during a financial reform: Argentina 1977–81. Journal of Development Economics 25(2): 285–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  377. Lucas, R.E. 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: a critique. In The Phillips Curve and Labour Markets, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Vol. 1 of the Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
  378. Mankiw, N.G., Miron, J.A. and Weil, D.N. 1987. The adjustment of expectations to a change in regime: a study of the founding of the Federal Reserve. American Economic Review 77(5): 358–74.Google Scholar
  379. Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. 1990. Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics. Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  380. Quandt, R.E. 1988. The Econometrics of Disequilibrium. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  381. Sargent, T.J. 1986. Rational Expectations and Inflation. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
  382. Weber, A. 1991. Reputation and credibility in the European monetary system. Economic Policy 12: 57–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  383. Amel, D.F. and Jacowski, MJ. 1989. Trends in banking structure since the mid-1970s. Federal Reserve Bulletin 75: 120–33.Google Scholar
  384. Liang, N. and Rhoades, S. 1988. Geographic diversification and risk in banking. Journal of Economics and Business 40: 271–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  385. Rhoades, S.A. 1985. Mergers and acquisitions by commercial banks, 1960–82. Staff Study 142, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
  386. Rhoades, S.A. and Burke, J. 1990. Economic and political foundations of section 7 enforcement in the 1980s. The Antitrust Bulletin 35: 373–446.Google Scholar
  387. Rose, P.S. 1989. The Interstate Banking Revolution: Benefits, Risks and Tradeoffs for Bankers and Consumers. New York: Quorum Books.Google Scholar
  388. Savage, D.T. 1987. Interstate banking developments. Federal Reserve Bulletin 73: 79–92.Google Scholar
  389. The 1991 Handbook of World Stock and Commodity Exchanges. 1991. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  390. Anders, G. and Torres, C. 1991. Computers bypass Wall Street middlemen and stir controversy. Wall Street Journal, 28 August: A1, A4.Google Scholar
  391. Campbell, T.S. 1988. Money and Capital Markets. Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresman.Google Scholar
  392. Code, W.R. 1971. The spatial dynamics of financial intermediaries:an interpretation of the distribution of financial decision-making in Canada. Ph.D. dissertation, University of California at Berkeley.Google Scholar
  393. Elliott, J.R., Jr. 1955. Regional exchanges. Barrons, 27 June: 3, 27–8.Google Scholar
  394. Hamilton, J.L. 1979. Marketplace fragmentation, competition, and the efficiency of the stock exchange. Journal of Finance 34: 171–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  395. Kamm, J.O. 1942. The Decentralization of Securities Exchanges. Boston: Meador.Google Scholar
  396. Mulhem, J.J. 1983. The national stock market: taking shape. In Contemporary Developments in Financial Institutions and Markets, ed. T.M. Havrilesky and R.S. Schweitzer, Arlington Heights, Illinois: Harlan Davidson.Google Scholar
  397. National Bureau of Economic Research. 1975. Regional stock exchanges in a central market system. Explorations in Economic Research 2(3).Google Scholar
  398. Perry, G.E. 1981. The regional stock exchanges: their contributions to market liquidity and economic viability. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.Google Scholar
  399. Power, W. 1991. Regional exchanges consider a new option: merging. Wall Street Journal 8, February: C1, C17.Google Scholar
  400. Teweles, RJ. and Bradley, E.S. 1987. The Stock Market. 5th edn, New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
  401. Thomas, W. A. 1973. The Provincial Stock Exchanges. London: Frank Cass.Google Scholar
  402. Walter, J.E. 1957. The Role of Regional Securities Exchanges. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  403. Benveniste, L., Boyd, J.H. and Greenbaum, S.I. 1988. Bank Capital Regulation. Working Paper, Banking Research Center, Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois.Google Scholar
  404. Boyd, J.H. and Rolnick, A.J. 1988. A case for reforming federal deposit insurance. Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.Google Scholar
  405. Bureau of National Affairs. 1991. FDIC seeks right to limit dividend payments by banks with weak capital. Banking Report 56: 501–2.Google Scholar
  406. Chan, Y., Greenbaum, S.I. and Thakor, A.V. 1991. Is fairly priced deposit insurance possible? Working Paper 152, Banking Research Center, Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois.Google Scholar
  407. Chase, S.B. Jr. and Waage, D.L. 1983. Corporate separateness as a tool of bank regulation. Washington DC: Samuel Chase & Company.Google Scholar
  408. Diamond, D.W. and Dybvig, P.H. 1983. Bank runs, deposit insurance and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91: 401–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  409. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. 1950. Annual Report. Washington DC: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.Google Scholar
  410. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. 1984. The First Fifty Years: A History of the FDIC1933–1983. Washington DC: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.Google Scholar
  411. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. 1989. Annual Report. Washington DC: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.Google Scholar
  412. Fischer, G.C. 1961. Bank Holding Companies. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  413. Fischer G.C. 1968. American Banking Structures. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  414. Golembe, C.H. 1991. Too-big-to-fail and all that. Golembe Reports 1991/4. Washington DC: CHG Consulting.Google Scholar
  415. Golembe, C.H. and Holland, D.S. 1986. Federal Regulation of Banking1986–87. Washington DC: Golembe.Google Scholar
  416. Kareken, J.H. 1985. Ensuring financial stability. In The Search for Financial Stability: The Past Fifty Years. San Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.Google Scholar
  417. Kareken, J.H. 1991. Commercial banking in the United States. Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, Minnesota.Google Scholar
  418. Kareken, J.H. and Wallace, N. 1978. Deposit insurance and bank regulation: a partial equilibrium analysis. Journal of Business 51: 413–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  419. Pierce, J.L. 1991. Can banks be insulated from nonbank affiliates? In Governing Banking’s Future: Markets vs. Regulation, ed. C. England, Boston: Kluwer.Google Scholar
  420. Simons, H. 1936. Rules versus authorities in monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 54, February: 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  421. Wallace, N. 1988. Another attempt to explain an illiquid banking system: the Diamond and Dybvig model with sequential service taken seriously. Quarterly Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 12(4): 3–16.Google Scholar
  422. Wallace, N. 1990. A banking model in which partial suspension is best. Quarterly Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 14(4), Fall: 11–23.Google Scholar
  423. Wells, D.S. and Scruggs, L.S. 1984. An historical review of insurance of bank deposits. Department of Economics, Fogelman College of Business and Economics, Memphis State University, Memphis, Tennessee.Google Scholar
  424. Committee on Banking Regulations and Supervisory Practices (CBRSP). 1975. Report to the Governors on the Supervision of Banks’ Foreign Establishments, September.Google Scholar
  425. Committee on Banking Regulations and Supervisory Practices (CBRSP). 1983. Principles for the Supervision of Banks’ Foreign Establishments, May.Google Scholar
  426. Committee on Banking Regulations and Supervisory Practices (CBRSP). 1988. International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards, July.Google Scholar
  427. Committee on Banking Regulations and Supervisory Practices (CBRSP). 1990. Supplement to the Concordat: the ensuring of adequate information flows between banking supervisory authorities, April.Google Scholar
  428. Cooke, P. 1981. Developments in co-operation among bank supervisory authorities. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 21(2), June: 234–44.Google Scholar
  429. Dale, R. 1984. The Regulation of International Banking. Cambridge: Woodhead-Faulkner.Google Scholar
  430. US Foreign Bank Supervision Enforcement Act of 1991. Congressional Record, 26 November.Google Scholar
  431. Bebchuk, L.A. 1986. The case for facilitating compering tender offers: a last(?) reply. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 2(2): 253–71.Google Scholar
  432. The Business Roundtable v. SEC. 1990. 905 F.2d 406.Google Scholar
  433. CTS Corporation v Dynamics Corporation of America. 1987. 481 U.S. 69.Google Scholar
  434. Dertouzos, M.L., Lester, R.K. and Solow, R.M. 1989. Made in America. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  435. Edgar v. MITE Corporation, 1982. 457 U.S. 624.Google Scholar
  436. Grossman, S.J. and Hart, O.D. 1988. One share-one vote and the market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics 20: 175–202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  437. Herzel, L. 1990. Corporate governance through statistical eyes. Journal of Financial Economics 27: 581–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  438. Herzel, L. and Shepro, R.W. 1990. Bidders & Targets. Cambridge, Mass. and Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  439. Jahera, J.S., Jr and Pugh, W. 1991. State takeover legislation: the case of Delaware. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 7: 410–28.Google Scholar
  440. Jensen, M.C. 1989. Eclipse of the public corporation. Harvard Business Review 67: 61–74.Google Scholar
  441. Lorsch, J.W. with Maclver, E. 1989. Pawns or Potentates. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
  442. Roell, A. 1987. Regulation of takeovers. Discussion paper, no. 3, FMG, London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
  443. Schwartz, A. 1986. Search theory and the tender offer auction. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 2: 229–53.Google Scholar
  444. Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. 1991. Takeovers in the 60s and the 80s: evidence and implications. Strategic Management Journal, December; also forthcoming in Fundamental Issues in Strategy, ed. R. Rumelt, D. Shendel and D. Teece, Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1992.Google Scholar
  445. Unocal Corporation v. Mesa Petroleum Company. 1985. 473 A.2d 946.Google Scholar
  446. Chandler, L.V. 1971. American Monetary Policy1928–1941. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
  447. Degen, R.A. 1987. The American Monetary System. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
  448. Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A.J. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  449. Kaufman, G.G. 1980. The U.S. Financial System: Money, Markets, and Institutions. 4th edn, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1989.Google Scholar
  450. Mayer, T., Duesenberry, J.S. and Aliber, R.Z. 1981. Money, Banking, and the Economy. 3rd edn, New York: W.W. Norton, 1987.Google Scholar
  451. Studenski, P. and Krooss, H.E. 1952. Financial History of the United States. 2nd edn, New York: McGraw-Hill, 1963.Google Scholar
  452. Ayling, D.E. 1982. An investigation into the underwriting of excess of loss reinsurance. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis, University of Aston in Birmingham.Google Scholar
  453. Ayling, D.E. 1983. How do you rate protection? ReActions Journal of Reinsurance, March: 59–61.Google Scholar
  454. Ayling, D.E. 1983. Catastrophe cover: a behavioural look at an actuarial problem. The Review, June: 28–33.Google Scholar
  455. Ayling, D.E. 1984. Underwriting Decisions Under Uncertainty: The Catastrophe Market. Aldershot: Gower Publishing Company.Google Scholar
  456. Ayling, D.E. 1986. The appliance of science: principles of risk management and premium calculation for insurance and reinsurance. Re Actions Journal of Reinsurance, April: 279–81.Google Scholar
  457. Ayling, D.E. 1990. Tests of a heuristic pricing system in the market for uncertainty. In Applied Economic Psychology in the 1990s, ed. S.E. Lea, P. Wesley and B.M. Young, Washington: Singer Press.Google Scholar
  458. Benktander, G. 1971. Some aspects of reinsurance profits and loadings. ASTIN Bulletin 3: 272–81.Google Scholar
  459. Berliner, B. 1974. Some thoughts on (re)insurance loadings under a ruin criterion. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal: 74–80.Google Scholar
  460. Carter, R.L. 1979. Reinsurance. 2nd edn, Brentwood: Kluwer Publishing, 1983.Google Scholar
  461. Golding, C.E. 1965. The Law and Practice of Reinsurance. Brentford, Middlesex: Buckley Press Ltd.Google Scholar
  462. Nitzan, S. and Rosen, U. 1977. A note on reinsurance and the technology of risk. Journal of Risk and Insurance, September: 403–9.Google Scholar
  463. Ratcliffe, G.C. 1974. The decision-making process in reinsurance. Reinsurance, June : 98–102.Google Scholar
  464. Reinarz, R.C. 1968. A Reference Book of Property and Liability Reinsurance. Sisterdale, Texas: Mission Publishing Company.Google Scholar
  465. Rubin, H.W. 1970. An anatomy of non-proportional reinsurance. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Georgia State University.Google Scholar
  466. Stone, J.M. 1975. A theory of capacity and the insurance of catastrophe risks (Parts I and II). Journal of Risk and Insurance 40: 231–43 (Part I), 339–55 (Part II).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  467. Tuma, J. 1946. Excess of Loss Reinsurance. Chartered Insurance Institute Library, Aldermanbury, London.Google Scholar
  468. Vajda, S. ed. 1955. Non-proportional Reinsurance. Brussels: S.A. Arithbel.Google Scholar
  469. Keynes, J.M. 1919. The Economic Consequences of the Peace. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  470. Keynes, J.M. 1929. The German transfer problem. Reprinted in American Economic Association, Readings in the Theory of International Trade, Philadelphia and Toronto: Blakiston.Google Scholar
  471. Kindleberger, C.P. 1984. A Financial History of Western Europe. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  472. Mantoux, E. 1952. The Carthaginian Peace. New York: Scribners.Google Scholar
  473. Metzler, L.A. 1949. The transfer problem reconsidered; and Classified Bibliography: IIIA. In American Economic Association, Readings in the Theory of International Trade, Philadelphia and Toronto: Blakiston.Google Scholar
  474. Moulton, H.G. and Pasvolsky, L. 1932. War Debts and World Prosperity. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
  475. Ohlin, B. 1949. The reparation problem: a discussion. In American Economic Association, Readings in the Theory of International Trade, Philadelphia and Toronto: Blakiston.Google Scholar
  476. Pigou, A.C. 1932. The effect of reparations on the ratio of international exchange. Economic Journal 42, December: 532–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  477. Abreu, D. 1988. On the theory of infinitely repeated games with discounting. Econometrica 56, March: 383–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  478. Blackburn, K. and Christensen. 1989. Monetary policy and policy credibility: theories and evidence. Journal of Economic Literature 27, March 1–45.Google Scholar
  479. Friedman, J.W. 1971. A noncooperative equilibrium for supergames. Review of Economic Studies 38, January: 861–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  480. Hayek, F.A. von. 1948. The meaning of competition. In Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  481. Klein, B. and Leffler, K.B. 1981. The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance. Journal of Political Economy 89, August: 625–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  482. Kreps, D.M. 1990. A Course in Microeconomic Theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  483. Kreps, D., Milgrom, P., Roberts, J. and Wilson, R. 1982. Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Economic Theory 27, August: 245–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  484. Kreps, D. and Wilson, R. 1982. Sequential equilibrium. Econometrica 50, July: 863–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  485. Macaulay, S. 1963. Non-contractual relations in business: a preliminary study. American Soc. Rev. 28, February: 55–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  486. Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of Economics. 8th edn, New York: Macmillan, 1949.Google Scholar
  487. Rogoff, K. 1987. Reputational constraints on monetary policy. In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 26: 141–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  488. Bethel, J. 1990. Project forecasting, job mobility, and capital rationing. Harvard Business School, June.Google Scholar
  489. Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D. and Welch, I, 1992. A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades. Journal of Political Economy, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  490. Boot, A. 1991. Why hang on to losers: divestitures and takeovers. Working paper no. 93, Kellogg Graduate School of Management, April.Google Scholar
  491. Brennan, M.J. 1990. Latent assets. Journal of Finance 45 (3), July: 709–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  492. Chaney, P.K., Devinney, T.M. and Winer, R.S. 1991. The impact of new product introductions on the market value of firms. Journal of Business 64(4): 573–610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  493. DeMarzo, P. and Duffie, D. 1991. Corporate incentives for hedging and hedge accounting. Preliminary draft, Stanford University and Kellogg School, July.Google Scholar
  494. Diamond, D.W. 1989. Reputation acquisition in debt markets. Journal of Political Economy 97(4), August: 828–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  495. Dybvig, P.H. and Zender, J.F. 1991. Capital structure and dividend irrelevance with asymmetric information. Review of Financial Studies 4(1): 201–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  496. Hagerty, K., Ofer, A. and Siegel, D. 1990. Managerial compensation and incentives to engage in far-sighted behavior. Presented at AFA Meetings, Washington, DC December (October 1990 version).Google Scholar
  497. Hansen, G.S. and Hill, C.W.L. 1991. Are institutional investors myopic? A time-series study of four technology-driven industries. Strategic Management Journal 12: 1–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  498. Harris, M. and Raviv, A. 1985. A sequential signalling model of convertible debt call policy. Journal of Finance 40:1263–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  499. Hirshleifer, D. and Chordia, T. 1991. Resolution preference and project choice. UCLA AGSM Working paper no. 21–90, March.Google Scholar
  500. Hirshleifer, D. and Thakor, A.V. Forthcoming. Managerial conservatism, project choice, and debt. Review of Financial Studies.Google Scholar
  501. Holmstrom, B. 1982. Managerial incentive problems — a dynamic perspective. In Essays in Economics and Management in Honour of Lars Wahlbeck. Swedish School of Economics, Helsingors.Google Scholar
  502. Holmstrom, B. and Ricart Costa, J. 1986. Managerial incentives and capital management. Quarterly Journal of Economics 101 (4), November: 835–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  503. Kanodia, C, Bushman, R. and Dickhaut, J. 1989. Escalation errors and the sunk cost effect: an explanation based on reputation and information asymmetries. Journal of Accounting Research 27(1): 59–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  504. Lang, M. and McNichols, M. 1991. Institutional investment, corporate earnings, and managerial incentives. Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, October.Google Scholar
  505. McConnell, J.J. and Muscarella, C.J. 1985. Corporate capital expenditure decisions and the market value of the firm. Journal of Financial Economics 14: 399–422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  506. Meulbroek, L.K., Mitchell, M.L., Mulherin, J.H., Netter, J.M. and Poulsen, A.B. 1990. Shark repellents and managerial myopia: an empirical test. Journal of Political Economy 95(5), part 1: 1108–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  507. Morck, R., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. 1990. Do managerial objectives drive bad acquisitions? Journal of Finance 45(1), March: 31–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  508. Narayanan, M.P. 1985. Managerial incentives for short term results. Journal of Finance 40(5), December: 1469–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  509. Pound, J. 1987. The effects of antitakeover amendments on takeover activity: some direct evidence. Journal of Law and Economics 30: 353–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  510. Scharfstein, D.S. and Stein, J.C. 1990. Herd behavior and investment. American Economic Review 80(3): 465–79.Google Scholar
  511. Stein, J. 1988. Takeover threats and managerial myopia. Journal of Political Economy 96(1): 61–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  512. Stein, J. 1989. Efficient capital markets, inefficient firms: a model of myopic corporate behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(4), November: 655–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  513. Thakor, A.V. 1990. Information, investment, and price reactions. Indiana University, Graduate School of Business Working paper no. 442, October.Google Scholar
  514. Titman, S. and Trueman, B. 1986. Information quality and the valuation of new issues. Journal of Accounting and Economics 8: 159–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  515. Trueman, B. 1986. The relationship between the level of capital expenditures and firm value. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 21(2): 115–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  516. Trueman, B. 1992. Analyst forecasts and herding behavior. Manuscript, Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley, February.Google Scholar
  517. Woolridge, J.R. 1988. Competitive decline and corporate restructuring: is a myopic stock market to blame? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 1: 26–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  518. Zwiebel, J. 1990. Corporate conservatism, herd behavior and relative compensation. MIT Department of Economics. Mimeo, October.Google Scholar
  519. Bulow, J. and Rogoff, K. 1988. The buyback boondoggle. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 675–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  520. Dooley, M., Folkerts-Landau, D., Haas, R.D., Symansky, S. and Tryon, R.W. 1990. Debt Reduction and Economic Activities, Occasional Paper No. 68, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  521. Eichengreen, B. 1989. Resolving debt crisis: an historical perspective. In Latin American Debt: Perspectives and Solution, ed. S. Edwards and F. Larrain, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  522. Eichengreen, B. and Portes, R. 1986. Debt and default in the 1930s: causes and consequences. European Economic Review 30, June: 599–640CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  523. El-Erian, M.A. 1990. Mexico’s commercial bank financing package. Finance and Development 27(3): 26–7.Google Scholar
  524. Feldstein, M. et al. 1987. Restoring growth in the debt-laden Third World: a task force report to the Trilateral Commission. Triangle Papers Report 33, New York: Trilateral Commission, April.Google Scholar
  525. Folkerts-Landau, D. 1985. The changing role of international bank lending in development finance. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers (Washington) 43(2), June: 317–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  526. Folkerts-Landau, D. and Rodriguez, C.A. 1989. Mexican debt exchange: lessons and issues. In Analytical Issues in Debt, ed. J.A. Frenkel, M.P. Dooley and P. Wickham, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  527. International Monetary Fund, International Capital Markets: Developments and Prospects, various issues 1986–91.Google Scholar
  528. Sachs, J. 1988. Comprehensive debt retirement: the Bolivian example. Brookings Papers on Economic Activities 2: 705–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  529. Eichengreen, B. 1985. The Gold Standard in Theory and History. New York and London: Methuen.Google Scholar
  530. Emerson, M. 1990. One Market, One Money. European Economy, No. 44, Brussels: Commission of the European Communities, October.Google Scholar
  531. International Monetary Fund, Committee on Reform of the International Monetary System and Related Issues. 1964. International Monetary Reform. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  532. Mundeil, R. 1989. Trade balance patterns as global general equilibrium: the seventeenth approach to the balance of payments. Rivista di Politica Economica 17(6): 9–60.Google Scholar
  533. Nederlandsche Bank. 1964. Annual Report. Amsterdam.Google Scholar
  534. Nurkse, R. 1944. International Currency Experience. Geneva: League of Nations.Google Scholar
  535. Polak, J. 1972. Reform of the International Monetary System — a sketch of its scope and content (7 March, 1971). In The International Monetary Fund 1972–78, ed. M.G. de Vries, Vol. III: 3–15, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1985.Google Scholar
  536. Solomon, R. 1982. The International Monetary System, 1945–1981. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  537. Triffin, R. 1960. Gold and the Dollar Crisis. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  538. Black, F. 1975. Bank funds management in an efficient market. Journal of Financial Economics 2: 323–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  539. Diamond, D. 1984. Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies 52: 393–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  540. Diamond, D. and Dybvig, P. 1983. Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91: 401–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  541. Fama, E. 1980. Banking in the theory of finance. Journal of Monetary Economics 6: 39–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  542. Fama, E. 1985. What’s different about banks? Journal of Monetary Economics 15: 29–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  543. Freeman, S. 1987. Reserve requirements and optimal seigniorage. Journal of Monetary Economics 19: 307–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  544. Friedman, M. 1960. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham University Press.Google Scholar
  545. Gorton, G. 1985. Bank suspension and convertibility. Journal of Monetary Economics 15: 177–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  546. Horrigan, B. 1988. Are reserve requirements relevant for economic stabilization? Journal of Monetary Economics 21: 97–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  547. Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review 48:261–97.Google Scholar
  548. Romer, D. 1985. Financial intermediation, reserve requirements, and inside money. Journal of Monetary Economics 16: 175–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  549. Slovin, M., Sushka, M. and Bendeck, Y. 1990. The market valuation effects of reserve regulation. Journal of Monetary Economics 25: 3–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  550. Sushka, M. 1976. The antebellum money market and the economic impact of the bank war. Journal of Economic History 36: 809–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  551. White, L. 1984. Free Banking in Britain. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  552. Saft, S. 1991. The basics of FIRREA and the Resolution Trust Corporation. Real Estate Finance Journal 6(3): 48–55.Google Scholar
  553. Stanton, T. and Petersen, J. 1990. The Resolution Trust Corporation and the assets of failed thrifts. Government Finance Review 6(2): 7–11.Google Scholar
  554. Dasgupta, P., Hammond, P. and Maskin, E. 1979. The implementation of social choice rules: some general results on incentive compatibility. Review of Economic Studies 46:185–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  555. Gibbard, A. 1973. Manipulation of voting schemes: a general result. Econometrica 41: 587–601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  556. Harris, M. and Townsend, R.M. 1981. Resource allocation under asymmetric information. Econometrica 49(1): 33–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  557. Holmstrom, B. 1977. On incentives and control in organizations. PhD dissertation, Stanford University.Google Scholar
  558. Myerson, R.B. 1979. Incentive-compatibility and the bargaining problem. Econometrica 47:61–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  559. Myerson, R.B. 1981. Optimal auction design. Mathematics of Operations Research 6: 58–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  560. Myerson, R.B. 1982. Optimal coordination mechanisms in generalized principal-agent problems. Journal of Mathematical Economics 10: 67–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  561. Myerson, R.B. 1985. Bayesian equilibrium and incentive compatibility: an introduction. In Social Goals and Social Organization, ed. L. Hurwicz, D. Schmeidler and H. Sonnenschein, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  562. Myerson, R.B. 1986. Multistage games with communication. Econometrica 54: 323–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  563. Rosenthal, R. 1978. Arbitration of two-party disputes under uncertainty. Review of Economic Studies 45: 595–604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  564. Bouman, F.J.A. 1977. Indigenous savings and credit societies in the Third World. A Message. Savings and Development 1(4): 181–219.Google Scholar
  565. Campbell, CD. and Chang, S.A. 1962. Kyes and Mujins — financial intermediaries in South Korea. Economic Development and Cultural Change 11(1), October: 55–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  566. Drake, P.J. 1980. Money, Finance and Development. Oxford: Martin Robertson, ch. 6.Google Scholar
  567. Gamba, C. 1958. Poverty and some socio-economic aspects of hoarding, saving and borrowing in Malaya. Malayan Economic Review III(2), October: 33–62.Google Scholar
  568. Geertz, C. 1962. The rotating credit association: a ‘middle rung’ in development. Economic Development and Cultural Change 10(3), April: 241–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  569. Booth, W.C. 1988. The Company We Keep: An Ethics of Fiction. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  570. Brooks, P. 1985. Reading for the Plot: Design and Intention in Narrative. New York: Vintage.Google Scholar
  571. Fama, E.F. and Miller, M.M. 1972. The Theory of Finance. New York: Holt, Reinhart.Google Scholar
  572. Johnson, M. 1990. Business Buzzwords: The Tough New Jargon of Modern Business. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  573. Klamer, A. 1984. Conversations With Economists: New Classical Economists And Opponents Speak Out on the Current Controversy in Macroeconomics. Totowa: Rowman & Allanheld.Google Scholar
  574. McCloskey, D.N. 1985. The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
  575. McCloskey, D.N. 1990. If You We So Smart: The Narrative of Economic Expertise. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  576. Abel, A.B. 1986. Capital accumulation and uncertain lifetimes with adverse selection. Econometrica 54(5), September: 1079–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  577. Bailey, M.J. 1971. National Income and the Price Level. 2nd edn, New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  578. Barro, R.J. 1974. Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy 82(6), November–December: 1095–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  579. Barsky, R.B., Mankiw, G.N. and Zeldes, S.P. 1986. Ricardian consumers with Keynesian propensities. American Economic Review 76(4), September: 676–91.Google Scholar
  580. Buchanan, J.M. 1958. Public Principles of Public Debt. Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
  581. Buchanan, J.M. 1976. Barro on the Ricardian equivalence theorem. Journal of Political Economy 84(2), April: 337–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  582. Carmichael, J. 1982. On Barro’s theorem and debt neutrality: the irrelevance of net wealth. American Economic Review 72(1), March: 202–13.Google Scholar
  583. Chan, L.K.C. 1983. Uncertainty and the neutrality of government financing policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 11, May: 351–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  584. Drazen, A. 1978. Government debt, human capital and bequests in a lifecycle model. Journal of Political Economy 86, June: 337–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  585. Feldstein, M.S. 1976. Perceived wealth in bonds and social security: a comment. Journal of Political Economy 84(2), April: 331–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  586. Patinkin, D. 1965. Money, Interest and Prices. 2nd edn, New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  587. Ricardo, D. 1817. The Prindples of Political Economy and Taxation. London: M. Dent & Sons, 1911; reprinted, 1960.Google Scholar
  588. Tobin, J. 1980. Asset Accumulation and Economic Activity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  589. Weil, P. 1987. Love thy children: reflections on the Barro debt neutrality theorem. Journal of Monetary Economics 19(3), May: 377–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  590. Bhagat, S. 1983. The effect of pre-emptive right amendments on shareholder wealth. Journal of Financial Economics 12: 287–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  591. Government Statistical Service. 1991. Financial Statistics No. 349, May 1991, London: HMSO.Google Scholar
  592. Hansen, R.S. and Pinkerton, J.M. 1982. Direct equity financing: a resolution of a paradox. Journal of Finance 37: 651–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  593. Heinkel, R. and Schwartz, E.S. 1986. Rights versus underwritten offerings: an asymmetric information approach. Journal of Finance 41: 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  594. Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Finance Economics 3: 305–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  595. Marsh, P. 1979. Equity rights issues and the efficiency of the UK Stock Market. Journal of Finance 34: 839–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  596. Smith, C. 1977. Alternative methods for raising capital: rights versus underwritten offerings. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 273–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  597. Anscombe, F. and Aumann, R. 1963. A definition of subjective probability. Annals of Mathematical Statistics 34: 199–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  598. Arrow, K. 1964. The role of securities in the optimal allocation of risk-bearing. Review of Economic Studies 31: 91–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  599. Bawa, V. 1982. Stochastic dominance: a research bibliography. Management Science 28: 698–712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  600. Borch, K. 1969. A note on uncertainty and indifference curves. Review of Economic Studies 36: 1–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  601. Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of General Equilibrium. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  602. Diamond, P. and Stiglitz, J. 1974. Increases in risk and in risk aversion. Journal of Economic Theory 8: 337–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  603. Ekern, S. 1980. Increasing n’th degree risk. Economic Letters 6: 329–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  604. Epstein, L. and Tanny, S. 1980. Increasing generalized correlation: a definition and some economic consequences. Canadian Journal of Economics 13: 16–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  605. Feldstein, M. 1969. Mean-variance analysis in the theory of liquidity preference and portfolio selection. Review of Economic Studies 36: 5–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  606. Fishburn, P. 1982. Simplest cases of n’th degree stochastic dominance. Operations Research Letters 1: 89–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  607. Fishburn, P. and Vickson, R.G. 1978. Theoretical foundations of stochastic dominance. In Whitmore and Findlay (1978).Google Scholar
  608. Hadar, J. and Russell, W. 1969. Rules for ordering uncertain prospects. American Economic Review 59: 25–34.Google Scholar
  609. Hanoch, G. and Levy, H. 1969. The efficiency analysis of choices involving risk. Review of Economic Studies 36: 335–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  610. Hansen, L., Holt, C. and Peled, D. 1978. A note on first degree stochastic dominance. Economics Letters 1: 315–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  611. Hicks, J. 1962. Liquidity. Economic Journal 72: 787–802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  612. Hirshleifer, J. 1965. Investment decision under uncertainty: choice-theoretic approaches. Quarterly Journal of Economics 79: 509–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  613. Hirshleifer, J. 1966. Investment decision under uncertainty: applications of the state-preference approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 252–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  614. Huang, C, Kira, D. and Vertinsky, I., 1978. Stochastic dominance for multi-attribute utility functions. Review of Economic Studies 45: 611–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  615. Kami, E. 1985. Decision Making Under Uncertainty: The Case of State Dependent Preferences. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  616. Knight, F. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co.Google Scholar
  617. Lehmann, E. 1955. Ordered families of distributions. Annals of Mathematical Statistics 26: 399–419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  618. Levhari, D., Parousch, J. and Peleg, B. 1975. Efficiency analysis for multivariate distributions. Review of Economic Studies 42: 87–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  619. Levy, H. and Parousch, J. 1974. Toward multivariate efficiency criteria. Journal of Economic Theory 7,129–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  620. Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47, February: 13–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  621. Machina, M. 1987. The Economic Theory of Individual Behavior Toward Risk: Theory, Evidence and New Directions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  622. Markowitz, H. 1952. Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance 7: 77–91.Google Scholar
  623. Markowitz, H. 1959. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investment. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  624. Marshall, A. and Olkin, I.1979. Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and Its Applications. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  625. Meyer, J. 1987. Two moment decision models and expected utility maximization. American Economic Review 11: 421–30.Google Scholar
  626. Mossin, J. 1966. Equilibrium in a capital asset market Econometrica 34: 768–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  627. Pratt, J. 1964. Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica 32:122–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  628. Pratt, J., Raiffa, H. and Sehlaifer, R. 1964. The foundations of decision under uncertainty: an elementary exposition. Journal of the American Statistical Association 59: 353–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  629. Raiffa, H. 1968. Derision Analysis: Introductory Lectures on Choice Under Uncertainty. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
  630. Rothschild, M. and Stiglitz, J. 1970. Increasing risk: I. A definition. Journal of Economic Theory 2: 225–43. Reprinted in Diamond and Rothschild (1978).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  631. Rothschild, M. and Stiglitz, J. 1971. Increasing risk: II. Its economic consequences. Journal of Economic Theory 3: 66–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  632. Rothschild, M. and Stiglitz, J. 1972. Addendum to ‘Increasing risk: I. A definition’. Journal of Economic Theory 5: 306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  633. Russell, W. and Seo, T. 1978. Ordering uncertain prospects: the multivariate utility functions case. Review of Economic Studies 45: 605–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  634. Samuelson, P. 1967. General proof that diversification pays. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 2:1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  635. Savage, L. 1954. The Foundations of Statistics. New York: John Wiley and Sons. Revised and enlarged edition, New York: Dover Publications, 1972.Google Scholar
  636. Sharpe, W. 1964. Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19: 425–42.Google Scholar
  637. Sherman, S. 1951. On a theorem of Hardy, Littlewood, Polya, and Blackwell. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 37: 826–31. (See also ‘Errata’, Proceeding? of the National Academy of Sciences 38: 382.)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  638. Strassen, V. 1965. The existence of probability measures with given marginals. Annals of Mathematical Statistics 36: 423–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  639. Tesfatsion, L. 1976. Stochastic dominance and the maximization of expected utility. Review of Economic Studies 43: 301–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  640. Tobin, J. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior toward risk. Review of Economic Studies 25: 65–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  641. Treynor, J.L. 1961. Toward a Theory of Market Value of Risky Assets. Unpublished.Google Scholar
  642. Whitmore, G. 1970. Third-degree stochastic dominance. American Economic Review 60: 457–9.Google Scholar
  643. Whitmore, G. and Findlay, M. 1978. Stochastic Dominance: An Approach to Decision Making Under Risk. Lexington, Mass.: Heath.Google Scholar
  644. Yaari, M. 1969. Some remarks on measures of risk aversion and on their uses. Journal of Economic Theory 1:315–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  645. Keeney, R.L. and Raiffa, H. 1976. Derisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Tradeoffs. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  646. Tverski, A. and Kahneman, D. 1981. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211: 453–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  647. von Neumann, J. and Morgensten, O. 1953. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  648. Travis, C.C. (ed.). 1988. Carcinogenic Risk Assessment. New York: Plenum.Google Scholar
  649. Atomic Energy Commission. 1975. Reactor safety study: an assessment of accident risks in US commercial power plants. WASH 1400, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
  650. Primack, J. 1975. An introduction to the issues. Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists 31:15–19.Google Scholar
  651. Brealey, R. and Myers, S.C. 1988. Principles of Corporate Finance. 3rd edn, New York: McGraw Hill; or other standard textbook.Google Scholar
  652. Resendiz-Carrillo, D. and Lave, L.B. 1987. Optimizing spillway capacity with an estimated distribution of floods. Water Resources Research 23: 2043–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  653. National Research Council. 1988. Health Risks of Radon and Other Internally Deposited Alpha-Emitters, BEIRIV. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
  654. Lave, L.B. and Freeburg, L. 1973. Health effects of electricity generation from coal, oil and nuclear fuel. Nuclear Safety 14.Google Scholar
  655. Sagan, L.A. 1972. Health costs of nuclear power. Science 177: 487–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  656. Sagan, L.A. 1974. Health costs associated with mining, transport, and combustion of coal in the steam-electric industry. Nature 250:107–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  657. Risk analysis in insurance Google Scholar
  658. Arthur Williams Jr., C. and Heins, R.M. 1989. Risk Management and Insurance. New York: McGraw-Hill. Or other standard textbook.Google Scholar
  659. Highway risks Google Scholar
  660. Graham, J.D. 1988. Preventing Automobile Injury. Dover, Mass.: Auburn House.Google Scholar
  661. Schwing, R.C. and Kamarud, D.B. 1988. The distribution of risk: vehicle occupant fatalities and time of week. Risk Analysis 8: 127–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  662. Aczél, J. and Pales, Zs. 1988. The behavior of means under equal increments of their variables. American Mathematical Monthly 95: 856–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  663. Arrow, K.J. 1965. Aspects of the Theory of Risk-Bearing. Helsinki: Yrjo Jahnssonin Saatio.Google Scholar
  664. Bell, D.E. 1988a. The value of pre-decision sidebets for utility maximizers. Management Sdence 34: 797–800.Google Scholar
  665. Bell, D.E. 1988b. One-switch utility functions and a measure of risk. Management Science 34: 1416–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  666. Bell, D.E. 1991a. Contextual uncertainty conditions for utility functions. Manuscript, Harvard University.Google Scholar
  667. Bell, D.E. 1991b. Risk, return, and utility. Manuscript, Harvard University.Google Scholar
  668. Borch, K. 1962. Equilibrium in a reinsurance market. Econometrica 30: 424–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  669. Fishburn, P.C. 1988. Nonlinear Preference and Utility Theory.Google Scholar
  670. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Fishburn, P.C. and Porter, R.B. 1976. Optimal portfolios with one safe and one risky asset: effects of changes in rate of return and risk. Management Science 22: 1064–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  671. Fuchs, V. and Zeckhauser, R. 1987. Valuing health — a ‘priceless’ commodity. American Economic Review 11: 263–7.Google Scholar
  672. Hadar, J. and Seo, T.K. 1990. Ross’s measure of risk aversion and portfolio selection. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 3: 93–9.Google Scholar
  673. Hardy, G.H., Littlewood, J.E. and Polya, G. 1934. Inequalities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  674. Hart, O.D. 1975. Some negative results on the existence of comparative statics results in portfolio theory. Review of Economic Studies 42: 615–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  675. Hoehn, L. and Niven, I. 1985. Averages on the move. Mathematics Magazine 58: 151–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  676. Kahneman, D., Slovic, P. and Tversky, A. (eds) 1982. Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  677. Kihlstrom, R.E., Romer, D. and Williams, S. 1981. Risk aversion with random initial wealth. Econometrica 49: 911–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  678. Kimball, M.S. 1990. Precautionary saving in the small and in the large. Econometrica 58: 53–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  679. Kimball, M.S. 1991. Standard risk aversion. Manuscript, University of Michigan.Google Scholar
  680. LaValle, I.H. 1968. On cash equivalents and information evaluation in decisions under uncertainty. Journal of the American Statistical Association 63: 252–96.Google Scholar
  681. Machina, M.J. 1989. Dynamic consistency and non-expected utility models of choice under uncertainty. Journal of Economic Literature 21: 1622–68.Google Scholar
  682. Meyer, R.F. 1970. On the relationship among the utility of assets, the utility of consumption, and investment strategy in an uncertain, but time-invariant, world. OR 69: Proceedings of the Fifth International Conference on Operational Research: 627–48.Google Scholar
  683. Meyer, R.F. and Pratt, J.W. 1968. The consistent assessment and fairing of preference functions. IEEE Transactions on Systems Science and Cybernetics SSC-4: 270–78. Nachman, D.C. 1980. Preservation of’more risk averse’ under expectations. Unpublished working paper, Columbia University.Google Scholar
  684. Pratt, J.W. 1964. Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica 32:122–36; correction, 44: 420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  685. Pratt, J.W. 1987. Multiattribute utility and derived utility. In Toward Interactive and Intelligent Derision Support Systems (Proceedings of the Seventh International Conference on Multiple Criteria Decision Making, Kyoto, Japan, 1986), ed. Y. Sawaragi, K. Inoue and H. Nakayama.Google Scholar
  686. Pratt, J.W. 1988. Aversion to one risk in the presence of others. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 1: 395–413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  687. Pratt, J.W. 1989a. Utility functions, interest rates, and the demand for bonds. In Studies in the Economics of Uncertainty: In Honor of Josef Hadar ed. Thomas B. Fomby and T. Kun Seo, New York: Springer-Verlag New York Inc.Google Scholar
  688. Pratt, J.W. 1989b. Some results on repeated risktaking. In Probability, Statistics, and Mathematics: Papers in Honor of Samuel Karlin ed. T.W. Anderson, K.B. Athreya and D.L. Iglehart, New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  689. Pratt, J.W. 1990. The logic of partial-risk aversion: paradox lost. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 3: 105–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  690. Pratt, J.W. and Zeckhauser, R. 1987. Proper risk aversion. Econometrica55:143–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  691. Pratt, J.W. and Zeckhauser, R. 1989. The impact of risk sharing on efficient decision. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 2: 219–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  692. Raiffa, H. and Schlaifer, R. 1961. Applied Statistical Decision Theory. Boston: Harvard Graduate School of Business Administration.Google Scholar
  693. Rosing, J. 1970. The formation of groups for cooperative decision making under uncertainty. Econometrica 38: 430–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  694. Ross, S.A. 1981. Some stronger measures of risk aversion in the small and the large with applications. Econometrica 49: 621–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  695. Samuelson, P.A. 1989. The VAf law and repeated risktaking. In Probability, Statistics, and Mathematics: Papers in Honor of Samuel Karlin, ed. T.W. Anderson, K.B. Athreya and D.L. Iglehart, New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  696. Schelling, T. 1984. The life you save may be your own. In Choice and Consequence, ed. T. Schelling, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  697. Schlaifer, R. 1971. Computer Programs for Elementary Derision Analysis. Boston: Division of Research, Harvard University Graduate School of Business Administration.Google Scholar
  698. Wallace, D.L. 1974. An analysis of some problems in risk-sharing and group decision theory. Thesis, Harvard Business School.Google Scholar
  699. Wilson, R.B. 1968. The theory of syndicates. Econometrica 36: 119–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  700. Price Waterhouse. 1991. Bank Capital Adequacy and Capital Convergence. London: Price Waterhouse.Google Scholar
  701. Copeland, T., Koller, T. and Murrin, J. 1990. Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Valuation of Companies. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
  702. Kane, E.J. 1985. The Gathering Crisis in Federal Deposit Insurance: Origins, Evolution, and Possible Reforms. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  703. Kane, E.J. 1989. The S&L Insurance Mess: How Did It Happen? Washington DC: The Urban Institute Press.Google Scholar
  704. Musumeci, J.J. and Sinkey, J.F., Jr. 1990. The international debt crisis and bank loan-loss-reserve decisions: the signalling content of partially anticipated events. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 22, August: 370–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  705. Sinkey, J.F., Jr. 1992. Commercial Bank Financial Management in the Financial-Services Industry. 4th edn, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  706. Smith, C.W, Jr., Smithson, C.W. and Wilford, D.S. 1990. Managing Financial Risk. New York: Harper Business.Google Scholar
  707. Black, F. 1972. Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. Journal of Business 45: 444–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  708. Black, F. and Scholes, M. 1973. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy 81: 637–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  709. Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47: 13–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  710. Rubinstein, M. 1976. The valuation of uncertain income streams and the pricing of options. Bell Journal of Economics 7: 407–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  711. Sharpe, W.F. 1964. Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of’risk. Journal of Finance 19: 425–42.Google Scholar
  712. Constantinides, G. 1990. Habit formation: a resolution of the equity premium puzzle. Journal of Political Economy 98, June: 519–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  713. Epstein, L.G. and Zin, S.E. 1991. Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: an empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy 99, April: 263–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  714. Grossman, S.J. and Laroque, G. 1990. Asset pricing and optimal portfolio choice in the presence of illiquid durable consumption goods. Econometrica 58, January: 25–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  715. Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47, February: 13–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  716. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1978. Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46, November: 1429–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  717. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1982. Interest rates and currency prices in a two-country world. Journal of Monetary Economics 10, November: 335–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  718. Markowitz, H. 1952. Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance 7, March: 77–91.Google Scholar
  719. Mehra, R. and Prescott, E.C. 1985. The equity premium: a puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics 15, March: 145–61. Reitz, T.A. 1988. The equity premium: a solution? Journal of Monetary Economics 22, June: 117–31.Google Scholar
  720. Roll, R. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s test. Part I: On past and potential testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics 4, March: 129–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  721. Sharpe, W.F. 1964. Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19, September: 425–42.Google Scholar
  722. Zeldes, S.P. 1989. Consumption and liquidity constraints: an empirical investigation. Journal of Political Economy 97, April: 305–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  723. Baykov, A. 1948. The Development of the Soviet Economic System — An Essay on the Experience of Planning in the U.S.S.R. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press and New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  724. Brabant, J.M. van. 1977. East European Cooperation — The Role of Money and Finance. New York: Praeger, 103–16.Google Scholar
  725. Brabant, J.M. van. 1987 Adjustment, Structural Change, and Economic Efficiency — Aspects of Monetary Cooperation in Eastern Europe. New York and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 278–85.Google Scholar
  726. Nove, A. 1969. An Economic History of the U.S.S.R. London: Allen Lane, Pengu in Press .Google Scholar
  727. Glasky, J.H. 1989. A quiet revolution in private placements. Journal of Accountancy, September: 68–74.Google Scholar
  728. Moody’s Investors Service. 1990. Two-tiered private market to evolve under proposed 144A. Moody s Special Comment, New York, 6 April. Securities and Exchange Commission. 1991. Staff Report on Rule 144A. Washington, DC, 30 September.Google Scholar
  729. Standard and Poor’s Corporation. 1990. Creditweek. 30 April. Travelers Securities Department. 1992. Private Placements. In Insurance Company Investment Management Handbook, ed. E.A. Mennis and S. Ryals, New York: New York Institute of Finance.Google Scholar
  730. Barro, R.J. 1979. On the determination of the public debt. Journal of Political Economy 87: 940–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  731. Barro, RJ. and Gordon, D.B. 1983. Rules, discretion, and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 12:101–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  732. Blackburn, K. and Christensen, M. 1989. Monetary policy and policy credibility: theories and evidence. Journal of Economic Literaturell: 1–45.Google Scholar
  733. Bordo, M.D. and Kydland, F.E. 1992. The gold standard as a rule. Working paper 9205, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.Google Scholar
  734. Carlson, J.B. 1988. Rules versus discretion: making a monetary rule operational. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review 24(3): 2–13.Google Scholar
  735. Chari, V.V. 1988. Time consistency and optimal policy design. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 12(4) : 17–31.Google Scholar
  736. Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, P.J. 1989. Sustainable plans and debt. Staff Report 125, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, P.J. 1990. Sustainable plans. Journal of Political Economy 98: 783–802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  737. Friedman, M. 1948. A monetary and fiscal framework for economic stability. American Economic Review 38: 245–64.Google Scholar
  738. Friedman, M. 1960. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham University Press.Google Scholar
  739. Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. 1977. Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85: 473–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  740. Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. 1980. Dynamic optimal taxation, rational expectations and optimal control. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 2: 79–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  741. Lucas, R.E., Jr. and Stokey, N.L. 1983. Optimal fiscal and monetary policy in an economy without capital. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 55–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  742. Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. 1990. Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics. Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  743. Prescott, E.C. 1977. Should control theory be used for economic stabilization? In Optimal Policies, Control Theory and Technology Exports, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 7:13–38, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  744. Ramsey, F. 1927. A contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal 37: 47–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  745. Simons, H.C. 1936. Rules versus authorities in monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 44:1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited 1992

Authors and Affiliations

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations