N

  • Peter Newman
  • Murray Milgate
  • John Eatwell

Keywords

Europe Palladium Gasoline Excavation Arena 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Bibliography

  1. Cramer, J.S. 1981. The volume of transactions and of payments in the United Kingdom, 1968–1977. Oxford Economic Papers 33: 234–55.Google Scholar
  2. Currie, M. and Steedman, I. 1990. Wrestling with Time: Problems in Economic Theory. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  3. Eisner, R. 1986. How Real is the Federal Deficit? New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  4. Goldsmith, R. 1985. Comparative National Balance Sheets: A Study of Twenty Countries. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  5. Goodhart, C.A.E. 1983. Monetary Theory and Practice: The UK Experience. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  6. Mendelson, M. 1962. The optimum of grossness in flow-of-funds accounts. In The Flow of Funds Approach to Social Accounting: Appraisal, Analysis, and Applications. Princeton: Princeton University Press for the NBER.Google Scholar
  7. Patterson, K.D. and Stephenson, M.J. 1988. Stock-flow consistent accounting: a macroeconomic perspective. Economic Journal 98: 787–800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Patterson, K.D. 1990. Stock flow consistent income for industrial and commercial companies. Review of Income and Wealth 33: 289–308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Ruggles, N.D. 1987. Financial accounts and balance sheets: issues for the revision of the SNA. Review of Income and Wealth 33: 39–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Shiller, R.J. 1990. Market Volatility. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  11. Statistics Canada. 1989. A Guide to the Financial Flow and National Balance Sheet Accounts. Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services.Google Scholar
  12. United Nations. 1968. A System of National Accounts. Series F, no. 2, Rev. 3, New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
  13. United Nations. 1975. Guidelines on National and Sectoral Balance Sheets and Reconciliation Accounts of the SNA. Series M, no. 60, New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
  14. United Nations. 1977. Guidelines on Statistics of Tangible Assets. Series M, no. 68, New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
  15. Dickson, P.G.M. 1967. The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit, 1688–1756. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  16. Gordon, B. 1976. Political Economy in Parliament, 1819–1823. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Gordon, B. 1979. Economic Doctrine and Tory Liberalism, 1824–1830. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Hansard, T.C. 1819. Parliamentary Debates. Vol. 40. London.Google Scholar
  19. Hilton, B. 1977. Corn, Cash, Commerce: The Economic Policies of the Tory Governments, 1815–1830. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  20. Kimmel, L.H. 1959. Federal Budget and Fiscal Policy, 1789–1958. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  21. Schumpeter, J. A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Ed. E. Cannan, New York: Random House, 1937.Google Scholar
  23. Cassei, G. 1928. The rate of interest, the bank rate, and the stabilization of prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics 42, August: 511–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Clower, R. 1965. The Keynesian counterrevolution: a theoretical appraisal. In The Theory of Interest Rates, ed. F.H. Hahn and F.P.R. Brechling, London: Macmillan; New York: St Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
  25. Hayek, F.A. 1931. Prices and Production. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul; 2nd edn, New York: A.M. Kelley, 1967.Google Scholar
  26. Humphrey, T.M. 1986. Cumulative process models from Thornton to Wicksell. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, May–June.Google Scholar
  27. Keynes, J.M. 1930. A Treatise on Money. 2 vols, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  28. Keynes, J.M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan; New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
  29. Leijonhufvud, A. 1981. The Wicksell connection. In A. Leijonhufvud, Information and Coordination, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  30. Lindahl, E. 1939. Studies in the Theory of Money and Capital. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston.Google Scholar
  31. Myrdal, G. 1939. Monetary Equilibrium. Edinburgh: William Hodge.Google Scholar
  32. Palander, T. 1941. On the concepts and methods of the Stockholm School. International Economic Papers No. 3, London: Macmillan, 1953.Google Scholar
  33. Robertson, D.H. 1926. Banking Policy and the Price Level. Reprinted, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1949.Google Scholar
  34. Sraffa, P. 1932. Dr Hayek on money and capital. Economic Journal 42, March: 42–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Wicksell, K. 1898. Geldzins und Guterpreise. Jena: Gustav Fischer. Trans, by R.F. Kahn as Interest and Prices, London: Macmillan, 1936; reprinted New York: A.M. Kelley, 1962.Google Scholar
  36. Wicksell, K. 1906. Vorlesungen uber Nationalökonomie. Trans, by E. Classen as Lectures on Political Economy, Vol. II, London: Roudedge & Kegan Paul; reprinted New York: A.M. Kelley, 1967.Google Scholar
  37. Attfield, C.L.F., Demery, D. and Duck, N.W. 1981a. Unanticipated monetary growth, output and the price level: UK 1946–1977. European Economic Review 16:367–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Attfield, C.L.F., Demery, D. and Duck, N.W. 1981b. A quarterly model of unanticipated monetary growth, output and the price level in the UK 1963–1978. Journal of Monetary Economics 8: 331–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Barro, R.J. 1976. Rational expectations and the role of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 2:1–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Barro, R.J. 1977. Unanticipated money growth and unemployment in the United States. American Economic Review 67:101–15.Google Scholar
  41. Barro, R.J. 1978. Unanticipated money, output and the price level in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 86: 549–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Barro, R.J. and Rush, M. 1980. Unanticipated money and economic activity. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press for National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  43. Bean, C.R. 1984. A litde bit more evidence on the natural hypothesis from the U.K. European Economic Review 25: 279–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58:1–17.Google Scholar
  45. Gordon, R.J. 1982. Price inertia and policy ineffectiveness in the United States, 1890–1980. Journal of Political Economy 90, December: 1087–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Gordon, R.J. 1990. What is new-Keynesian economics? Journal of Economic Literature 28:1115–71.Google Scholar
  47. Leiderman, L. 1980. Macroeconometric testing of the rational expectations and structural neutrality hypothesis for the United States. Journal of Monetary Economics 6: 69–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4:103–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1973. Some international evidence on output-inflation trade offs. American Economic Review 63:326–34.Google Scholar
  50. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1975. An equilibrium model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 83:1113–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. McAleer, M. and MacKenzie, C.R. 1991. Keynesian and New Classical models of unemployment revisited. Economic Journal 101, May: 359–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. McCallum, B.T. 1989. Real business cycle models. In Modern Business Cycle Theory, ed. R.J. Barro, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  53. Mishkin, F.S. 1982. Does anticipated monetary policy matter? An econometric investigation. Journal of Political Economy 90, February: 22–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Muth, J.F. 1961. Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica 29:315–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Pesaran, M.H. 1982. A critique of the proposed tests of the natural rate-rational expectations hypothesis. Economic Journal 92, September: 529–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Pesaran, M.H. 1987. The Limits to Rational Expectations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  57. Pesaran, M.H. 1988. On the policy ineffectiveness proposition and a Keynesian alternative: a rejoinder. Economic Journal 98, June: 504–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Phelps, E.S. 1967. Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time. Economica 34: 254–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Phelps, E.S. 1970. The New Microeconomics in employment and inflation theory. In Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory, ed. E.S. Phelps et al., New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  60. Rush, M. and Waldo, D. 1988. On the policy ineffectiveness proposition and a Keynesian alternative. Economic Journal 98, June: 498–503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Sargent, T.J. 1973. Rational expectations, the real rate of interest and the natural rate of unemployment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 429–72; correction of errors, 799–800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Sargent, T.J. 1976. A classical macroeconomic model for the United States. Journal of Political Economy 84, April: 207–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Sargent, T.T. and Wallace, N. 1973. Rational expectations and the dynamics of hyperinflation. International Economic Review 14: 328–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Sargent, T.T. and Wallace, N. 1975. Rational expectations, the optimal monetary instrument and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 83: 241–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Tobin, J. 1970. The wage price mechanism. In The Econometrics of Price Determination Conference, ed. O. Eckstein, Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.Google Scholar
  66. Artis, M.J. and Lewis, M.K. 1990. Money supply and demand. In Current Issues in Monetary Economics, ed. T. Bandyopadhyay and S. Ghatak, London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
  67. Bank of England. 1990. Monetary aggregates in a changing environment: a statistical discussion paper. Bank of England Discussion Paper no. 47.Google Scholar
  68. Barnett, W.A. 1980. Economic monetary aggregates: an application of index number and aggregation theory. Journal of Econometrics 14:11–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Barnett, W.A., Offenbacher, E.K. and Spindt, P.A. 1984. The new Divisia monetary aggregates. Journal of Political Economy 92: 1049–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Boughton, J.M. 1981. Money and its substitutes. Journal of Monetary Economics 8: 375–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Cagan, P. and Schwartz, A.J. 1975. Has the growth of money substitutes hindered monetary policy? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 7:137–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Chetty, V.K. 1969. On measuring the nearness of near-moneys. American Economic Review 59: 270–81.Google Scholar
  73. Chick, V. 1973. The Theory of Monetary Policy. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  74. Donovan, D.J. 1978. Modelling the demand for liquid assets: an application to Canada. IMF Staff Papers 25: 676–704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Ewis, N.A. and Fisher, D. 1984. The translog utility function and the demand for money in the United States. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 16: 34–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Ewis, N.A. and Fisher, D. 1985. Toward a consistent estimate of the demand for monies: an application of the Fourier flexible form. Journal of Macroeconomics 7: 151–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Feige, E.L. 1974. Temporal cross-section specifications of the demand for demand deposits. Journal of Finance 29: 923–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Feige, E.L. and Pearce, D.K. 1977. The substitutability of money and near-monies: a survey of the time-series evidence. Journal of Economic Literature 15: 439–69.Google Scholar
  79. Gurley, J.G. and Shaw, E.S. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  80. Judd, J.P. and Scadding, J.L. 1982. The search for a stable money demand function: a survey of the post-1973 literature. Journal of Economic Literature 20: 993–1023.Google Scholar
  81. Lee, T.H. 1966. Substitutability of non-bank intermediary liabilities for money: the empirical evidence. Journal of Finance 21:441–57.Google Scholar
  82. Mills, T.C. 1983. Composite monetary indicators for the UK. Bank of England Discussion Paper, Technical Series, no. 3.Google Scholar
  83. Radcliffe Committee. 1959. Report of the Committee on the Working of the Monetary System. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
  84. Sayers, R. 1960. Monetary thought and monetary policy in England. Economic Journal 70: 710–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Serletis, A. and Robb, A.L. 1986. Divisia aggregation and substitutability among monetary assets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 18: 430–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. Tobin, J. and Brainard, W.C. 1963. Financial intermediaries and the effectiveness of monetary controls. American Economic Review 53 (Papers and Proceedings): 383–400.Google Scholar
  87. Baumol, W.J. 1952. The transactions demand for cash. Quarterly Journal of Economics 66, November: 545–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. Fischer, S. 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85(1), February: 191–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Friedman, M. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  90. Hansen, A. 1949. Monetary Theory and Fiscal Policy. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  91. Hicks, J. 1937. Mr Keynes and the ‘classics’: a suggested interpretation. Econometrica 5, April: 147–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Lucas, R. 1980. Methods and problems in business cycle theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 12(4), pt 2, November: 696–715.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Lucas, R. and Sargent, T. 1979. After Keynesian macroeconomics. Federal Reserve Bank oí Minneapolis Quarterly Review 3(2), Spring: 1–16.Google Scholar
  94. Metzler, L. 1951. Wealth saving and the rate of interest. Journal of Political Economy 59, April: 93–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  95. Modigliani, F. 1944. Liquidity preference and the theory of interest and money. Econometrica 12, January: 45–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. Modigliani, F. 1980. Collected Papen, Vol. I: Essays in Macroeconomics. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  97. Modigliani, F. and Brumberg, R. 1954. Utility analysis and the consumption function: an interpretation of cross section data. In Post-Keynesian Economics, ed. K.K. Kurihara, New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.Google Scholar
  98. Patinkin, D. 1948. Price flexibility and full employment. American Economic Review 38, September: 543–64.Google Scholar
  99. Patinkin, D. 1956. Money, Interest and Prices. New York: Harper & Row; 2nd edn, 1965.Google Scholar
  100. Phelps, E. 1972. Inflation Policy and Unemployment Theory. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  101. Samuelson, P. 1951. Principles and rules in modern fiscal policy: a neoclassical reformulation. In Money, Trade and Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of John Henry Williams, ed. H.L. Waitzman, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  102. Samuelson, P. 1955. Economics. 3rd edn, New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  103. Taylor, J. 1980. Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88(1), February: 1–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  104. Tobin, J. 1956. The interest-elasticity of transactions demand for cash. Review of Economics and Statistics 38, August: 241–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  105. Tobin, J. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. Review of Economic Studies 25, February: 65–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  106. Arida, P. and Lara-Resende, A. 1986. Inflación inercial y reforma monetaria: Brasil. In Inflación Cero, ed. P. Arida, Bogota: Oveja Negra.Google Scholar
  107. Bacha, E. 1987. La inercia y el conflicto: el Plan Cruzado y sus desafíos. Estudios Económicos, El Colegio de Mexico (October).Google Scholar
  108. Bruno, M., Di Tella, G., Dornbusch, R. and Fischer, S. (eds) 1988. Inflation Stabilization. Cambridge, Mass. and London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  109. Dornbusch, R. 1989. The road to economic recovery. Report of the Twentieth Century Fund Task Force on International Debt. New York: Priority Press.Google Scholar
  110. Jameson, K.P. 1986. Latin American structuralism: a methodological perspective. World Development, February.Google Scholar
  111. Sargent, T. 1986. Rational Expectations and Inflation. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
  112. Simonsen, M.H. 1987. Rational expectations, game theory and inflationary inertia. Paper presented to the Seventh Latin American Meeting of the Econometric Society, São Paulo, August.Google Scholar
  113. Taylor, L. 1983. Structuralist Macroeconomics. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  114. Taylor, L. ed. 1988. Varieties of Stabilization Experience. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  115. Velasco, A. 1991. Monetarism and structuralism: some macroeconomic lessons. In The Latin American Development Debate, ed. P. Meller, Boulder and Oxford: Westview Press.Google Scholar
  116. Wallerstein, I. 1987. Periphery. In The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate and P. Newman, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  117. Bosman, H.W.J. 1986. The Netherlands banking system. Amsterdam: Nederlands Instituut voor het Bank- en Effectenbedrijf.Google Scholar
  118. Buist, M.G. 1974. At Spes Non Frata, Hope & Co. 1770–1815. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.Google Scholar
  119. Jong, A.M. de. 1967. Geschiedenis van de Nederlandse Bank (History of the Netherlands Bank). Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank (Parts I–IV).Google Scholar
  120. Kremers, J.J.M. 1987. Financing budget deficits in The Netherlands. De Economist 135: 340–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  121. Verrijn Stuart, G.M. 1956. Geld, Crediet en Bankwezen, Deel II Bankpolitiek (Money, Credit and the Banking System, Part II Bank Policy). The Hague: NV Uitgeversmaatschappij v/h G. Delwel.Google Scholar
  122. Archibald, G.C. and Lipsey, R.G. 1958. Monetary and value theory: a critique of Lange and Patinkin. Review of Economic Studies 28, October: 50–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  123. Bailey, M.J. 1956. The welfare cost of inflationary finance. Journal of Political Economy 64, April: 93–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  124. Barro, R.J. 1976. Rational expectations and the role of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 2, January: 1–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  125. Barro, R.J. 1978. Unanticipated money, output, and the price level in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 86, August: 549–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  126. Birati, A. and Cukierman, A. 1979. The redistributive effects of inflation and of the introduction of a real tax system in the US bond market. Journal of Public Economics 12, August: 125–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  127. Boianovsky, M. 1991. The use of the term ‘veil of money’ by Irving Fisher — a comment on Patinkin and Steiger. Unpublished note.Google Scholar
  128. Boschen, J.F. and Grossman, H.I. 1982. Tests of equilibrium macroeconomics using contemporaneous monetary data. Journal of Monetary Economics 10, November: 309–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  129. Brock, W.A. 1974. Money and growth: the case of long run perfect foresight. International Economic Review 15, October: 750–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  130. Cecchetti, S.G. 1986. Testing short-run neutrality. Journal of Monetary Economics 17, May: 409–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  131. Feaveryear, A. 1963. The Pound Sterling: A History of English Money, 2nd edn, revised by E.V. Morgan, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  132. Feldstein, M. 1982. Inflation, capital taxation, and monetary policy. In Inflation: Causes and Effects, ed. R.E. Hall, Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 153–67.Google Scholar
  133. Fischer, S. 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85, February: 191–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  134. Fischer, S. 1980. On activist monetary policy with rational expectations. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 211–47.Google Scholar
  135. Fisher, I. 1896. Appreciation and interest. AEA Publications 3(11), August: 331–442; reprinted, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1961.Google Scholar
  136. Fisher, I. 1907. The Rate of Interest. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  137. Fisher, I. 1911. The Purchasing Power of Money: Its Determination and Relation to Credit Interest and Crises. Rev. edn, New York: Macmillan; reprinted, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1963.Google Scholar
  138. Fisher, I. 1923. ‘The business cycle largely a ‘Dance of the Dollar’, Journal of the American Statistical Association 18, December: 1024–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  139. Fisher, I. 1930. The Theory of Interest. New York: Macmillan. Reprinted, New York: Kelley and Millman, 1954.Google Scholar
  140. Friedman, M. 1970. The Counter-Revolution in Monetary Theory. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
  141. Gale, D. 1982. Money: in Equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  142. Gordon, R.J. 1982. Price inertia and policy ineffectiveness in the United States, 1890–1980. Journal of Political Economy 90, December: 1087–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  143. Grandmont, J.-M. 1983. Money and Value: a Reconsideration of Classical and Neoclassical Monetary Theories. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  144. Gurley, J.G. and Shaw, E.S. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  145. Hayek, F.A. von. 1931. Prices and Production. London: George Routledge.Google Scholar
  146. Hayek, F.A. von. 1935. Prices and Production. 2nd edn, London: George Routledge.Google Scholar
  147. Howitt, P. and Patinkin, D. 1980. Utility transformations and money illusion: comments. American Economic Review 70, September: 819–22, 826–8.Google Scholar
  148. Hume, D. 1752. ‘Of Money’, ‘Of Interest’ and ‘Of the Balance of Trade’. As reprinted in D. Hume, Writings on Economics, ed. E. Rotwein, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin Press, 1970: 33–77.Google Scholar
  149. Humphrey, T.M. 1991. Nonneutrality of money in classical monetary thought. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 77, March/April: 3–15.Google Scholar
  150. Keynes, J.M. 1923. A Tract on Monetary Reform. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  151. Klausinger, H. 1990. The early use of the term ‘veil of money’ in Schumpeter’s monetary writings: a comment on Patinkin and Steiger. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92(4): 617–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  152. Kleiman, E. 1984. Alut ha-inflatzya. Rivon Le-kalkalah (Economic Quarterly) 30, January: 859–64 (Hebrew). Translated and issued in May 1989 under title ‘The cost of inflation’, as Working Paper No. 211, Department of Economics, Hebrew University of Jerusalem.Google Scholar
  153. Kuznets, S. 1941. National Income and Its Composition, 1919–1938. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  154. Kuznets, S. 1951. National income and industrial structure. Proceedings of the International Statistical Conference 1947 5: 205–39. As reprinted in S. Kuznets, Economic Change, London: William Heinemann, 1954:145–91.Google Scholar
  155. Laidler, D. 1990. Money as a metaphorical garment before the Great War: a comment on Patinkin and Steiger. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92(4 : 613–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  156. Leontief, W. 1936. The fundamental assumption of Mr. Keynes’ monetary theory of unemployment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 51, November: 192–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  157. Levhari, D. and Patinkin, D. 1968. The role of money in a simple growth model. American Economic Review 58, September: 713–53. As reprinted in Patinkin (1972c): 205–42.Google Scholar
  158. Lothian, J.R. 1985. Equilibrium relationships between money and other economic variables. American Economic Review 75, September: 828–35.Google Scholar
  159. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4, April: 103–24. As reprinted in Lucas (1981): 66–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  160. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1975. An equilibrium model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 83, December: 1113–44. As reprinted in Lucas (1981): 179–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  161. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1980. Two illustrations of the quantity theory of money. American Economic Review 70, December: 1005–14.Google Scholar
  162. Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1981. Studies in Business Cycle Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  163. McCallum, B.T. 1980. Rational expectations and macroeconomic stabilization policy: an overview. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 12, November: 716–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  164. Metzler, L.A. 1951. Wealth, saving and the rate of interest. Journal of Political Economy 59, April: 93–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  165. Mishkin, F.S. 1982. Does anticipated monetary policy matter? An econometric investigation. Journal of Political Economy 90, February: 22–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  166. Mishkin, F.S. 1983. A Rational Expectations Approach to Macroeconometrics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  167. Modigliani, F. 1944. Liquidity preference and the theory of interest and money. Econometrica 12, January: 45–88. As reprinted in American Economic Association, Readings in Monetary Theory, Philadelphia: Blakiston for the American Economic Association, 1951:186–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  168. Mundeil, R.A. 1963. Inflation and real interest. Journal of Political Economy 71, June: 280–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  169. Mundeil, R.A. 1965. A fallacy in the interpretation of macroeconomic equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy 73, February: 61–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  170. Patinkin, D. 1965. Money, Interest, and Prices. 2nd edn, New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  171. Patinkin, D. 1972a. On the short-run non-neutrality of money in the quantity theory. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review No. 100, March: 3–22.Google Scholar
  172. Patinkin, D. 1972b. Money and growth in a Keynesian full-employment model. In Patinkin (1972c): 195–204.Google Scholar
  173. Patinkin, D. 1972c. Studies in Monetary Economics. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  174. Patinkin, D. and Steiger, O. 1989. In search of the ‘veil of money’ and the ‘neutrality of money’: a note on the origin of terms. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 91(1): 131–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  175. Sargent, T.J. 1976. A classical macroeconometric model for the United States. Journal of Political Economy 84, April: 207–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  176. Schumpeter, J.A. 1917/18. Das Sozialprodukt und die Rechenpfennige. Archiv fir Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 44: 627–715. Translated under the title ‘Money and the social product’’, International Economic Papers 6:148–211. London: Macmillan, 1956, for the International Economic Association.Google Scholar
  177. Sidrauski, M. 1967. Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy. American Economic Review 57, May: 534–44.Google Scholar
  178. Solow, R.M. 1956. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, February: 65–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  179. Tobin, J. 1965. Money and economic growth. Econometrica 33, October: 671–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  180. Tobin, J. 1967. The neutrality of money in growth models: a comment. Economica 34, February: 69–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  181. Wicksell, K. 1898. Geldzins und Guterpreise. Trans, by R.F. Kahn as Interest and Prices: A Study of the Causes Regulating the Value of Money, London: Macmillan, 1936.Google Scholar
  182. Altonji, J.G. 1982. The intertemporal substitution model of labour market fluctuations: an empirical analysis. Review of Economic Studies 49(5), Special Issue: 783–824.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  183. Barro, R.J. 1977. Long-term contracting, sticky prices, and monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 3(3), July: 305–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  184. Barro, R.J. 1978. Unanticipated money, output, and the price level in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 86(4), August: 549–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  185. Barro, R.J. and Gordon, D. 1983. Rules, discretion, and reputation. Journal of Monetary Economics 12(1), July: 101–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  186. Barro, RJ. and Hercowitz, Z. 1980. Money stock revisions and unanticipated money growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 6(2), April: 257–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  187. Blanchard, O.J. 1983. The production and inventory behaviour of the American automobile industry. Journal of Political Economy 91(3), June: 365–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  188. Boschen, J.F. and Grossman, H.I. 1982. Tests of equilibrium macroeconomics using contemporaneous monetary data. Journal of Monetary Economics 10(3), November: 309–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  189. Fischer, S. 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85(1), February: 191–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  190. Fischer, S. 1980. On activist monetary policy with rational expectations. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  191. Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58(1), March: 1–17.Google Scholar
  192. Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A.J. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  193. Garber, P.M. and King, R.G. 1983. Deep structural excavation. University of Rochester, Department of Economics, Working Paper 83–14, September.Google Scholar
  194. Hall, R.E. and Mishkin, F.S. 1982. The sensitivity of consumption to transitory income — estimates from panel data on households. Econometrica 50(2), March: 461–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  195. Hansen, L.P. and Singleton, K. 1983. Stochastic consumption, risk aversion, and the temporal behaviour of asset returns. Journal of Political Economy 91(2), April: 249–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  196. Hart, O. and Hölmstrom, B. 1987. The theory of contracts. In Advances in Economic Theory, 5th World Congress, ed. T. Bewley, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  197. King, R.G. and Plosser, C.I. 1984. Money, credit, and prices in a real business cycle model. American Economic Review 74(3), June: 363–80.Google Scholar
  198. Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. 1977. Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85(3), June: 473–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  199. Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. 1982. Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50(6), November: 1345–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  200. Lucas, R.E. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4(2), April: 103–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  201. Lucas, R.E. 1973. Some international evidence on output-inflation tradeoffs. American Economic Review 63(3), September: 326–34.Google Scholar
  202. Lucas, R.E., 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: a critique. In The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. I, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  203. Lucas, R.E. 1977. Understanding business cycles. In Stabilization of the Domestic and International Economy’, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 5, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  204. Lucas, R.E. and Sargent, T.J. 1981. Rational Expectations and Econometric Practice. Minnesota: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
  205. Mankiw, N.G., Rotemberg, J.J. and Summers, L.H. 1985. Intertemporal substitution in macroeconomics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100(1), February: 225–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  206. Mishkin, F.S. 1983. A Rational Expectations Approach to Macroeconometrics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  207. Rogoff, K. 1985. The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100(4), November: 1169–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  208. Sargent, T.J. 1978. Estimation of dynamic labour demand schedules under rational expectations. Journal of Political Economy 86(6), December: 1009–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  209. Sargent, T.J. 1982. Beyond demand and supply curves in macroeconomics. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 72(2), May: 382–9.Google Scholar
  210. Sargent, T.J. and Wallace, N. 1975. ‘Rational’ expectations, the optimal monetary instrument, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 83(2), April: 241–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  211. Sims, C.A. 1980. Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica 48(1), January: 1–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  212. Taylor, J.B. 1980. Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88(1), February: 1–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  213. Black, F. 1970. Banking and interest rates in a world without money: the effects of uncontrolled banking. Journal of Banking Research 1: 8–20.Google Scholar
  214. Cowen, T. and Kroszner, R. 1987. The development of the new monetary economics. Journal of Political Economy 95: 567–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  215. Cowen, T. and Kroszner, R. 1990a. Empirical predictions of the new monetary economics: perspectives on velocity. Journal of Policy Modeling 12: 265–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  216. Cowen, T. and Kroszner, R. 1990b. Mutual fund banking: a market approach. Cato Journal 10: 223–37.Google Scholar
  217. Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  218. Dorn, J.A. 1989. Introduction: alternatives to government fiat money. Cato Journal 9: 277–94.Google Scholar
  219. Dowd, K. 1989. The State and the Monetary System. London and New York: Philip Allan.Google Scholar
  220. Fama, E. 1980. Banking in the theory of finance. Journal of Monetary Economics 6: 39–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  221. Fama, E. 1983. Financial intermediation and price level control. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 7–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  222. Fischer, S. 1983. A framework for monetary and banking analysis. Economic Journal (Supplement) 93: 1–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  223. Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. 1986. Has government any role in money? Journal of Monetary Economics 17: 37–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  224. Goodhart, C.A.E. 1986. The implications of shifting frontiers in financial markets for monetary control. In Shifting Frontiers in Financial Markets, ed. D.E. Fair, Dordrecht: Martinus Nijhoff.Google Scholar
  225. Greenfield, R. and Yeager, L. 1983. A laissez-faire approach to monetary stability. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 15: 302–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  226. Greenfield, R. and Yeager, L. 1986. Competitive payments systems: comment. American Economic Review 76: 848–9.Google Scholar
  227. Hall, R.E. 1982a. Explorations in the Gold Standard and related policies for stabilising the dollar. In Inflation: Causes and Effects, ed. R.E. Hall, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  228. Hall, R.E. 1982b. Monetary trends in the United States and the United Kingdom: a review from the perspective of new developments in monetary economics. Journal of Economic Literature 20:1552–6.Google Scholar
  229. Hall, R.E. 1983. Optional fiduciary monetary systems. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 33–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  230. Hayek, F. 1976. Denationalisation of Money. 2nd edn, London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
  231. Hicks, J.R. 1935. A suggestion for simplifying the theory of money. Economica N.S. 2:1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  232. Hoover, K.D. 1988. Money, prices and finance in the new monetary economics. Oxford Economic Papers 40: 150–67.Google Scholar
  233. Johnson, H.G. 1968. Problems of efficiency in monetary management. Journal of Political Economy 76: 971–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  234. King, R.G. 1983. On the economics of private money. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 127–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  235. Makinen, G.E. and Woodward, G.T. 1986. Some anecdotal evidence relating to the Legal Restrictions Theory of the demand for money. Journal of Political Economy 94: 260–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  236. McCallum, B.T. 1985. Bank deregulation, accounting systems of exchange, and the unit of account. A critical review. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 23: 13–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  237. McCallum, B.T. 1990. Comments on Empirical predictions of the new monetary economics: perspectives on velocity. Journal of Policy Modeling 12: 281–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  238. Meltzer, A. 1989. Eliminating monetary disturbances. Cato Journal 9: 423–8.Google Scholar
  239. Mott, T. 1989. A post Keynesian perspective on a ‘cashless’ competitive payments system. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 11:360–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  240. Niehans, J. 1978. The Theory of Money. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
  241. O’Driscoll, G.P. 1985. Money in a deregulated financial system. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Review, May: 1–12.Google Scholar
  242. Sumner, S. 1990. The forerunners of ‘new monetary economics’ proposals to stabilize the unit of account. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 22:109–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  243. Tobin, J. 1963. Commercial banks as creators of ‘money’. In Banking and Monetary Studies, ed. D. Carson. Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.Google Scholar
  244. Wallace, N. 1983. A legal restrictions theory of the demand for ‘money’ and the role of monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 7:1–7.Google Scholar
  245. Wallace, N. 1988. A suggestion for oversimplifying the theory of money. Economic Journal (Conference Papers) 98:25–36.Google Scholar
  246. White, L.H. 1984. Competitive payments systems and the unit of account. American Economic Review 74: 699–712.Google Scholar
  247. White, L.H. 1986. Competitive payments systems: reply. American Economic Review 76: 850–53.Google Scholar
  248. White, L.H. 1987. Accounting for non-interest bearing currency: a critique of the Legal Restrictions Theory of money. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 19: 448–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  249. White, L.H. 1989a. What kinds of monetary institutions would a free market deliver? Cato Journal 9: 367–91.Google Scholar
  250. White, L.H. 1989b. Competition and Currency. New York and London: New York University Press.Google Scholar
  251. White, L.H. 1990a. Competitive money reform: a review essay. Journal of Monetary Economics 26: 191–202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  252. White, L.H. 1990b. Scottish banking and the Legal Restrictions Theory: a closer look. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 22: 526–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  253. Yeager, L. 1989. A competitive payments system: some objections considered. Journal of Post-Key nesian Economia 11: 370–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  254. Yeager, L. and Greenfield, R. 1989. Can monetary disequilibrium be eliminated? Cato Journal 9: 405–21.Google Scholar
  255. Bernanke, B.S. 1983. Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the great depression. American Economic Review 73: 257–76.Google Scholar
  256. Brunner, K. 1969. Monetary analysis and Federal Reserve policy. In Targets and Indicators of Monetary policy, ed. K. Brunner, San Francisco: Chandler.Google Scholar
  257. Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  258. Gertler, M. 1988. Financial structure and aggregate economic activity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20(2) : 559–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  259. Gramley, L.E. and Chase, S.B., Jr. 1969. Time deposits in monetary analysis. In Targets and Indicators of Monetary policy, ed. K. Brunner, San Francisco: Chandler.Google Scholar
  260. Gurley, J. and Shaw, E.S. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
  261. Tobin, J. 1963. Commercial banks as creators of ‘money’. In Banking and Monetary Studies, ed. D. Carson, Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.Google Scholar
  262. Tobin, J. 1969. A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1:15–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  263. Tobin, J. and Brainard, W.C. 1963. Financial intermediaries and the effectiveness of monetary control. American Economic Review 53:383–400.Google Scholar
  264. New York Stock Exchange. 1980–90. Fact Book. New York: New York Stock Exchange.Google Scholar
  265. Sobel, R. 1967. The Big Board: A History of the New York Stock Market. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  266. Sobel, R. 1975. N.YS.E.: A History of the New York Stock Exchange, 1935–1975. New York: Weybright and Talley.Google Scholar
  267. Black, F. 1986. Noise. Journal of Finance 41, July: 529–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  268. Cutler, D., Poterba, J. and Summers, L. 1989. What moves stock prices? Journal of Portfolio Management 15, Spring: 4–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  269. De Long, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L. and Waldmann, R. 1990. Noise trader risk in financial markets. Journal of Political Economy 98(4), August: 703–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  270. De Long, J.B. and Shleifer, A. 1991. The stock market bubble of 1929: evidence from closed-end mutual funds. Journal of Economic History 51(3), September: 675–700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  271. Fama, E. 1965. The behavior of stock market prices. Journal of Business 38: 34–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  272. Fama, E. and French, K. 1988. Permanent and temporary components of stock market prices. Journal of Political Economy 96, April: 246–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  273. French, K. and Poterba, J. 1989. Are Japanese stock prices too high? Cambridge, Mass.: Massachusetts Institute of Technology xerox.Google Scholar
  274. Friedman, M. 1953. The case for flexible exchange rates. In Essays in Positive Economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  275. Keim, D. 1983. Size-related anomalies and stock market seasonality: further empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 12, June: 13–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  276. Kyle, A.S. 1985. Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53, November: 1315–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  277. Lee, C., Shleifer, A. and Thaler, R. 1991. Investor sentiment and the closed-end fund puzzle. Journal of Finance 46, March: 75–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  278. Lehmann, B. 1990. Fads, martingales, and market efficiency. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(1), February: 1–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  279. Malkiel, B. 1973. A Random Walk Down Wall Street. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
  280. Ross, S. 1987. The interrelations of finance and economics: theoretical perspectives. American Economic Review 77, May: 29–35.Google Scholar
  281. Shiller, R. 1989. Market Volatility. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  282. Maravall, A. and Pierce, D.A. 1983. Preliminary-data error and monetary aggregate targeting. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 1:179–86.Google Scholar
  283. Maravall, A. and Pierce, D.A. 1986. The transmission of data noise into policy noise in monetary control. Econometrica 43: 961–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  284. Morgenstern, O. 1963. On the Accuracy of Economic Observations. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  285. Nelson, C.R. 1972. The prediction performance of the FRB-MIT-Penn model of the US economy. American Economic Review 62: 902–17.Google Scholar
  286. Pierce, D.A. 1977. Relationships — and the lack thereof- between economic time series, with special reference to money and interest rates. Journal of the American Statistical Association 71: 11–22.Google Scholar
  287. Pierce, D.A., Parke, D.W., Cleveland, W.P. and Maravall, A. 1981. Uncertainty in the monetary aggregates: sources, measurement and policy effects. Journal of Finance 36: 507–17.Google Scholar
  288. Abuaf, N. and Jorion, P. 1990. Purchasing power parity in the long run. Journal of Finance 45: 157–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  289. Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. 1989. The message in daily exchange rates: a conditional variance tale. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 7(3): 297–305.Google Scholar
  290. Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. 1990. A multivariate generalized ARCH approach to modeling risk premia in forward foreign exchange rate markets. Journal of International Money and Finance 9: 309–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  291. Baillie, R.T. and McMahon, P. 1989. The Foreign Exchange Market: Theory and Econometric Evidence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  292. Diebold, F.X. and Nason, J.M. 1990. Nonparametric exchange rate prediction. Journal of International Economics 28: 315–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  293. Dornbusch, R. 1976. Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84: 1161–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  294. Frenkel, J.A. 1976. A monetary approach to the exchange rate: doctrinal aspects and empirical evidence. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 78: 200–224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  295. Frankel, J.A. and Froot, K.A. 1987. Using survey data to test standard propositions regarding exchange rate expectations. American Economic Review 77: 133–53.Google Scholar
  296. Hodrick, R.J. 1989. Risk, uncertainty, and exchange rates. Journal of Monetary Economics 23: 433–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  297. Meese, R.A. and Rogoff, R. 1983. Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: do they fit out of sample? Journal of International Economics 14: 3–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  298. Mussa, M.L. 1979. Empirical regularities in the behavior of exchange rates and theories of the foreign exchange market. In Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy 11, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  299. Blanchard, O. 1983. Price asynchronization and price level inertia. In Inflation, Debt, and Indexation, ed. R. Dornbusch and M. Simonsen, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  300. Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58, March: 1–17.Google Scholar
  301. Jackman, R., Layard, R. and Nickell, S. 1991. Unemployment, Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  302. Lucas, R. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4(2), April: 103–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  303. Taylor, J. 1980. Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88(1): 1–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  304. Tobin, J. 1980. Stabilization policy ten years after. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 10th Anniversary Issue: 19–71.Google Scholar
  305. Arrow, K.J. 1959. Towards a theory of price adjustment. In The Allocation of Economic Resources, ed. M. Abramowitz, Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  306. Arrow, K.J. and Debreu, G. 1954. Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica 22: 265–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  307. Arrow, K.J. and Hahn, F.H. 1971. General Competitive Analysis. San-Francisco: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
  308. Barro, R.J. and Grossman, H.I. 1971. A general disequilibrium model of income and employment. American Economic Review 61: 82–93.Google Scholar
  309. Barro, R.J. and Grossman, H.I. 1976. Money, Employment and Inflation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  310. Bénassy, J.-P. 1975a. Neo-Keynesian disequilibrium theory in a monetary economy. Review of Economic Studies 42: 503–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  311. Bénassy, J.-P. 1975b. Disequilibrium exchange in barter and monetary economies. Economic Inquiry 13:131–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  312. Bénassy, J.-P. 1976. The disequilibrium approach to monopolistic price setting and general monopolistic equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 43: 69–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  313. Bénassy, J.-P. 1977a. A neo-Keynesian model of price and quantity determination in disequilibrium. In Equilibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory, ed. G. Schwödiauer, Boston: Reidel Publishing Company.Google Scholar
  314. Bénassy, J.-P. 1977b. On quantity signals and the foundations of effective demand theory. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 79: 147–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  315. Bénassy, J.-P. 1982. The Economics of Market Disequilibrium. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  316. Bénassy, J.-P. 1984. A non-Walrasian model of the business cycle. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 5: 77–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  317. Bénassy, J.-P. 1986. Macroeconomics: An Introduction to the Non-Walrasian Approach. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  318. Bénassy, J.-P. 1987. Imperfect competition, unemployment and policy. European Economic Review 31: 417–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  319. Bénassy, J.-P. 1988. The objective demand curve in general equilibrium with price makers. Economic Journal 98, Supplement: 37–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  320. Bénassy, J.-P. 1990. Non-Walrasian equilibria, money and macroeconomics. In Handbook of Monetary Economics, (eds) B. Friedman and F.H. Hahn, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  321. Bénassy, J.-P. 1991a. Microeconomic foundations and properties of a macroeconomic model with imperfect competition. In Issues in Contemporary Economics. Markets and Welfare, ed. K.J. Arrow, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  322. Bénassy, J.-P. 1991b. Optimal government policy in a macroeconomic model with imperfect competition and rational expectations. In Equilibrium Theory and Applications: A Conference in Honor of Jacques Drèze, ed. W. Barnett, B. Cornet, C. D’Aspremont, J.J. Gabszewicz and A. Mas Colell, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  323. Bushaw, D.W. and Clower, R.W. 1957. Introduction to Mathematical Economics. Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
  324. Chamberlin, E.H. 1933. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. 7th edn, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1956.Google Scholar
  325. Clower, R.W. 1965. The Keynesian counterrevolution: a theoretical appraisal. In The Theory of Interest Rates, (eds) F.H. Hahn and F.P.R. Brechling, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  326. Cuddington, J.T. Johansson, P.-O. and Löfgren, K.G. 1984. Disequilibrium Macroeconomics in Open Economies. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  327. D’Autume, A. 1985. Monnaie, Croissance et Déséquilibre. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
  328. Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  329. Dixit, A.K. 1978. The balance of trade in a model of temporary equilibrium with rationing. Review of Economic Studies 45: 393–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  330. Dixon, H. 1987. A simple model of imperfect competition with Walrasian features. Oxford Economic Papers 39: 134–60.Google Scholar
  331. Drèze, J.H. 1975. Existence of an exchange equilibrium under price rigidities. International Economic Review 16: 301–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  332. Glustoff, E. 1968. On the existence of a Keynesian equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 35: 327–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  333. Grandmont, J.-M. and Laroque, G. 1976. On Keynesian temporary equilibria. Review of Economic Studies 43: 53–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  334. Greenberg, J. and Müller, H. 1979. Equilibria under price rigidities and externalities. In Game Theory and Related Topics, ed. O. Moeschlin and D. Pallaschke, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  335. Hahn, F.H. and Negishi, T. 1962. A theorem on non-tatonnement stability. Econometrica 30: 463–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  336. Hansen, B. 1951. A Study in the Theory of Inflation. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  337. Hart, O.D. 1982. A model of imperfect competition with Keynesian features. Quarterly Journal of Economics 97:109–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  338. Hicks, J.R. 1937. Mr. Keynes and the Classics: a suggested interpretation. Econometrica 5: 147–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  339. Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 2nd edn, 1946.Google Scholar
  340. Hildenbrand, K. and Hildenbrand, W. 1978. On Keynesian equilibria with unemployment and quantity rationing. Journal of Economic Theory 18: 255–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  341. Honkapohja, S. 1979. On the dynamics of disequilibria in a macro model with flexible wages and prices. In New Trends in Dynamic System Theory and Economics, (eds) M. Aoki and A. Marzollo, New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  342. Ito, T. 1980. Disequilibrium growth theory. Journal of Economic Theory 23: 380–409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  343. Jacobsen, H.-J. and Schultz, C. 1990. A general equilibrium macro model with wage bargaining. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92: 379–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  344. Keynes, J.M. 1936. The General Theory of Money, Interest and Employment. Reprinted in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 7, London: Macmillan, for the Royal Economic Society, 1973.Google Scholar
  345. Keynes, J.M. 1937. Alternative theories of the rate of interest. Economic Journal 47: 241–52. Reprinted in The Collected Writings of John May nard Keynes, London: Macmillan, for the Royal Economic Society, vol. 14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  346. Leijonhufvud, A. 1968. On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  347. Malinvaud, E. 1977. The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  348. Muellbauer, J. and Portes, R. 1978. Macroeconomic models with quantity rationing. Economic Journal 88: 788–821.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  349. Neary, P.J. 1980. Nontraded goods and the balance of trade in a neo-Keynesian temporary equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics 95:403–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  350. Neary, P.J. and Stiglitz, J.E. 1983. Towards a reconstruction of Keynesian economics: expectations and constrained equilibria. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98, Supplement: 199–228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  351. Negishi, T. 1961. Monopolistic competition and general equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 28:196–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  352. Negishi, T. 1977. Existence of an underemployment equilibrium. In Equilibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory, ed. G. Schwödiauer, Boston: D. Reidel Publishing Company.Google Scholar
  353. Negishi, T. 1979. Microeconomic Foundations of Keynesian Macroeconomics, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  354. Patinkin, D. 1956. Money, Interest and Prices. Evanston, Ill.: Row, Peterson and Company. 2nd edn, Harper and Row, New York, 1965.Google Scholar
  355. Persson, T. and Svensson, L.E.O. 1983. Is optimism good in a Keynesian economy? Economica 50: 291–300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  356. Picard, P. 1983. Inflation and growth in a disequilibrium macroeconomic model. Journal of Economic Theory 30: 266–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  357. Portes, R. 1981. Macroeconomic equilibrium and disequilibrium in centrally planned economies. Economic Inquiry 19: 559–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  358. Robinson, J. 1933. The Economics of Imperfect Competition, 2nd edn 1969, London: Macmillan and Co.Google Scholar
  359. Schulz, N. 1983. On the global uniqueness of fixprice equilibria. Econometrica 51:47–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  360. Silvestre, J. 1982. Fixprice analysis of exchange economies. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 28–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  361. Silvestre, J. 1983. Fixprice analysis in productive economies. Journal of Economic Theory 30: 401–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  362. Silvestre, J. 1988. Undominated prices in the three good model. European Economic Review 32: 161–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  363. Sneessens, H. 1987. Investment and the inflation-unemployment trade off in a macroeconomic rationing model with monopolistic competition. European Economic Review 31:781–815.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  364. Snower, D. 1983. Imperfect competition, unemployment and crowding out. Oxford Economic Papers 35: 569–84.Google Scholar
  365. Solow, R.M. and Stiglitz, J.E. 1969. Output, employment and wages in the short run. Quarterly Journal of Economics 82: 537–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  366. Svensson, L.E.O. 1986. Sticky goods prices, flexible asset prices, monopolistic competition and monetary policy. Review of Economic Studies 53: 385–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  367. Triffin, R. 1940. Monopolistic Competition and General Equilibrium Theory, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  368. Walras, L. 1874. Eléments d’Economie politique pure, Lausanne: Corbaz. Definitive edition translated by W. Jaffe as Elements of Pure Economics, London: Allen & Unwin, 1954.Google Scholar
  369. Weitzman, M.L. 1982. Increasing returns and the foundations of unemployment theory. Economic Journal 92: 787–804.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  370. Weitzman, M.L. 1985. The simple macroeconomics of profit sharing. American Economic Review 75: 937–53.Google Scholar
  371. Younes, Y. 1975. On the role of money in the process of exchange and the existence of a non-Walrasian equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 42: 489–501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  372. Anscombe, F.J. and Aumann, R.J. 1963. A definition of subjective probability. Annals of Mathematical Statistics 34:199–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  373. Chew, S.H. 1983. A generalization of the quasilinear mean with applications to the measurement of income inequality and decision theory resolving the Allais paradox. Econometrica 51: 1065–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  374. Chew, S.H. 1989. Axiomatic utility theories with the betweenness property. Annals of Operations Research 19: 273–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  375. Chew, S.H. and MacCrimmon, K.R. 1979. Alpha-nu choice theory: a generalization of expected utility theory. University of British Columbia Faculty of Commerce and Business Administration Working Paper No. 686.Google Scholar
  376. Ellsberg, D. 1961. Risk, ambiguity, and the Savage axioms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 75: 643–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  377. Epstein, L.G. 1991. Behavior under risk; recent developments in theory and applications. In Advances in Economic Theory, ed. J. J. Laffont, London: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  378. Epstein, L.G. and Zin, S.E. 1989. Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumpion and asset returns: a theoretical framework. Econometrica 57: 937–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  379. Epstein, L.G. and Zin, S.E. 1991. Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: an empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy 99: 263–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  380. Fishburn, P.C. 1983. Transitive measurable utility. Journal of Economic Theory 31: 293–317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  381. Gilboa, I. 1987. Expected utility with purely subjective nonadditive probabilities. Journal of Mathematical Economics 16: 65–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  382. Kami, E. and Safra, Z. 1989. Ascending bid auctions with behaviorally consistent bidders. Annals of Operations Research 19: 435–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  383. Kami, E. and Schmeidler, D. 1991a. Utility theory with uncertainty. In Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 4, ed. W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein, New York and Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
  384. Kami, E. and Schmeidler, D. 1991b. Atemporal dynamic consistency and expected utility theory. Journal of Economic Theory 54:401–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  385. Machina, M.J. 1982. ‘Expected utility’ analysis without the independence axiom. Econometrica 50: 277–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  386. Machina, M.J. 1989. Dynamic consistency and non-expected utility models of choice under uncertainty. Journal of Economic Literature 27:1622–68.Google Scholar
  387. Machina, M.J. and Schmeidler, D. 1990. A more robust definition of subjective probability. Mimeo.Google Scholar
  388. Quiggin, J. 1982. A theory of anticipated utility. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3: 323–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  389. Savage, L.J. 1954. The Foundations of Statistics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
  390. Schmeidler, D. 1986. Integral representation without additivity. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society 97: 255–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  391. Schmeidler, D. 1989. Subjective probability and expected utility without additivity. Econometrica 57: 571–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  392. Segal, U. 1990. Two-stage lotteries without the reduction axiom. Econometrica 58: 349–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  393. von Neumann, J. and Morgenstern, O. 1947. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. 2nd edn, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  394. Wakker, P.P. 1989. Additive Representation of Preferences, A New Foundation of Decision Analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  395. Yaari, M.E. 1987. The dual theory of choice under risk. Econometrica 55: 95–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  396. Beaver, W., Eger, C., Ryan, S. and Wolfson, M. 1989. Financial reporting, supplemental disclosures, and bank share prices. Journal of Accounting Research 27: 157–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  397. Simonson, D.G. 1987. Banks that fail. United States Banker, September: 78–80.Google Scholar
  398. Chiappori, P.-A. and Verdier, T. 1991. Interest rate deregulation and bank competition. Mimeo, DELTA, Paris.Google Scholar
  399. Dixit, A. 1979. Quality and quantity competition. Review of Economic Studies 46: 587–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  400. Matutes, C. and Padilla, J. 1991. Shared ATM networks and banking competition. Mimeo, IAE, University of Barcelona.Google Scholar
  401. Matutes, C. and Vives, X. 1991. Competition for deposits and risk of failure in banking. Mimeo, IAE, University of Barcelona.Google Scholar
  402. Salop, S. 1979. Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell Journal of Economics 10(1): 141–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  403. Startz, R. 1979. Implicit interest on demand deposits. Journal of Monetary Economics V: 515–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  404. Startz, R. 1983. Competition and interest rate ceilings in commercial banking. Quarterly Journal of Economics XCVIII: 255–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  405. Atchison, M., Butler, K. and Simonds, R. 1987. Nonsynchronous security trading and market index autocorrelation. Journal of Finance 42:111–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  406. Cohen, K., Maier, S., Schwartz, R. and Whitcomb, D. 1978. The returns generation process, returns variance, and the effect of thinness in securities markets. Journal of Finance 33:149–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  407. Cohen, K., Maier, S., Schwartz, R. and Whitcomb, D. 1979. On the existence of serial correlation in an efficient securities market. TIMS Studies in the Management Sciences 11: 151–68.Google Scholar
  408. Cohen, K., Hawawini, G., Maier, S., Schwartz, R. and Whitcomb, D. 1983a. Estimating and adjusting for the intervalling-effect bias in beta. Management Science 29: 135–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  409. Cohen, K., Hawawini, G., Maier, S., Schwartz, R. and Whitcomb, D. 1983b. Friction in the trading process and the estimation of systematic risk. Journal of Financial Economics 12: 263–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  410. Dimson, E. 1979. Risk measurement when shares are subject to infrequent trading. Journal of Financial Economics 7: 197–226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  411. Fisher, L. 1966. Some new stock market indexes. Journal of Business 39:191–225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  412. Fowler, D. and Rorke, C. 1983. Risk measurement when shares are subject to infrequent trading. Journal of Financial Economics 12: 279–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  413. Handa, P., Kothari, S. and Wasley, C. 1989. The relation between the return interval and betas. Journal of Financial Economics 23: 79–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  414. Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. 1988a. Stock market prices do not follow random walks: evidence from a simple specification test. Review of Financial Studies 1: 41–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  415. Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. 1988b. Notes on a Markov model of nonsynchronous trading. Working paper, Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
  416. Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. 1989. An econometric analysis of nonsynchronous trading. Journal of Econometrics 45: 181–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  417. Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. 1990. When are contrarian profits due to stock market overreaction? Review of Financial Studies 3: 175–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  418. Muthuswamy, J. 1990. Asynchronous closing prices and spurious autocorrelation in portfolio returns. Working paper, Fuqua School of Business, Duke University.Google Scholar
  419. Scholes, M. and Williams, J. 1977. Estimating beta from non- synchronous data. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 309–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  420. Shanken, J. 1987. Nonsynchronous data and the covariance structure of returns. Journal of Finance 42: 221–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  421. Berg, S.A., Forsund, F.R. and Jansen, E.S. 1991. Malmquist indices of productivity growth during the deregulation of Norwegian banking 1980–89. Norges Bank Arbeidsnotat (Working Paper) no. 2.Google Scholar
  422. Edison, H.J. and Vârdal, E. 1990. Optimal currency baskets for small, developed economies. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92(4): 559–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  423. Isachsen, A.J. (ed.) 1991. Ni Artikler om Penger, Kreditt og Valuta. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.Google Scholar
  424. Mundaca, E.G. 1991. The volatility of the Norwegian currency basket. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 93(1): 53–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  425. Norges Bank. 1989. Norwegian credit markets. Norwegian monetary and credit policy. Norges Banks Skriflserie no. 17.Google Scholar
  426. Norges Offentlige Utredninger (NOU). 1989. Penger og Kreditt i en Omstillingstid. (NOU 1989:1). Oslo: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
  427. Vikøren, B. 1989. Hvilke Muligheter har Norge til å føre en Selvstendig Rentepolitikk? Norsk Økonomisk Tidsskrift 103(1): 37–61.Google Scholar
  428. Cargill, T.F. and Garcia, G.G. 1982. Financial Deregulation and Monetary Control: Historical Perspective and Impact of the 1980 Art. Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press.Google Scholar
  429. Munn, G.G. and Garcia, F.L. 1991. Encyclopedia of Banking and Finance. Ninth Edition. Boston: Bankers Publishing Company.Google Scholar
  430. National Association of Mutual Savings Banks (NAMSB). Various years. Annual Report. Washington DC: NAMSB.Google Scholar
  431. Woerheide, W.J. 1984. The Savings and Loan Industry: Current Problems and Possible Solutions. Westport, Connecticut: Quorum Books.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited 1992

Authors and Affiliations

  • Peter Newman
  • Murray Milgate
  • John Eatwell

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations