Skip to main content

N

  • Chapter

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   429.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Bibliography

  • Cramer, J.S. 1981. The volume of transactions and of payments in the United Kingdom, 1968–1977. Oxford Economic Papers 33: 234–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Currie, M. and Steedman, I. 1990. Wrestling with Time: Problems in Economic Theory. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisner, R. 1986. How Real is the Federal Deficit? New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith, R. 1985. Comparative National Balance Sheets: A Study of Twenty Countries. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, C.A.E. 1983. Monetary Theory and Practice: The UK Experience. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendelson, M. 1962. The optimum of grossness in flow-of-funds accounts. In The Flow of Funds Approach to Social Accounting: Appraisal, Analysis, and Applications. Princeton: Princeton University Press for the NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patterson, K.D. and Stephenson, M.J. 1988. Stock-flow consistent accounting: a macroeconomic perspective. Economic Journal 98: 787–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patterson, K.D. 1990. Stock flow consistent income for industrial and commercial companies. Review of Income and Wealth 33: 289–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruggles, N.D. 1987. Financial accounts and balance sheets: issues for the revision of the SNA. Review of Income and Wealth 33: 39–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R.J. 1990. Market Volatility. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Canada. 1989. A Guide to the Financial Flow and National Balance Sheet Accounts. Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. 1968. A System of National Accounts. Series F, no. 2, Rev. 3, New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. 1975. Guidelines on National and Sectoral Balance Sheets and Reconciliation Accounts of the SNA. Series M, no. 60, New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. 1977. Guidelines on Statistics of Tangible Assets. Series M, no. 68, New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickson, P.G.M. 1967. The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit, 1688–1756. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, B. 1976. Political Economy in Parliament, 1819–1823. London: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, B. 1979. Economic Doctrine and Tory Liberalism, 1824–1830. London: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hansard, T.C. 1819. Parliamentary Debates. Vol. 40. London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilton, B. 1977. Corn, Cash, Commerce: The Economic Policies of the Tory Governments, 1815–1830. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kimmel, L.H. 1959. Federal Budget and Fiscal Policy, 1789–1958. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Ed. E. Cannan, New York: Random House, 1937.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassei, G. 1928. The rate of interest, the bank rate, and the stabilization of prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics 42, August: 511–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clower, R. 1965. The Keynesian counterrevolution: a theoretical appraisal. In The Theory of Interest Rates, ed. F.H. Hahn and F.P.R. Brechling, London: Macmillan; New York: St Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. 1931. Prices and Production. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul; 2nd edn, New York: A.M. Kelley, 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, T.M. 1986. Cumulative process models from Thornton to Wicksell. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, May–June.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1930. A Treatise on Money. 2 vols, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan; New York: Harcourt, Brace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leijonhufvud, A. 1981. The Wicksell connection. In A. Leijonhufvud, Information and Coordination, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindahl, E. 1939. Studies in the Theory of Money and Capital. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G. 1939. Monetary Equilibrium. Edinburgh: William Hodge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palander, T. 1941. On the concepts and methods of the Stockholm School. International Economic Papers No. 3, London: Macmillan, 1953.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robertson, D.H. 1926. Banking Policy and the Price Level. Reprinted, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1949.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. 1932. Dr Hayek on money and capital. Economic Journal 42, March: 42–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. 1898. Geldzins und Guterpreise. Jena: Gustav Fischer. Trans, by R.F. Kahn as Interest and Prices, London: Macmillan, 1936; reprinted New York: A.M. Kelley, 1962.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. 1906. Vorlesungen uber Nationalökonomie. Trans, by E. Classen as Lectures on Political Economy, Vol. II, London: Roudedge & Kegan Paul; reprinted New York: A.M. Kelley, 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Attfield, C.L.F., Demery, D. and Duck, N.W. 1981a. Unanticipated monetary growth, output and the price level: UK 1946–1977. European Economic Review 16:367–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attfield, C.L.F., Demery, D. and Duck, N.W. 1981b. A quarterly model of unanticipated monetary growth, output and the price level in the UK 1963–1978. Journal of Monetary Economics 8: 331–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. 1976. Rational expectations and the role of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 2:1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. 1977. Unanticipated money growth and unemployment in the United States. American Economic Review 67:101–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. 1978. Unanticipated money, output and the price level in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 86: 549–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. and Rush, M. 1980. Unanticipated money and economic activity. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press for National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bean, C.R. 1984. A litde bit more evidence on the natural hypothesis from the U.K. European Economic Review 25: 279–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58:1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R.J. 1982. Price inertia and policy ineffectiveness in the United States, 1890–1980. Journal of Political Economy 90, December: 1087–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R.J. 1990. What is new-Keynesian economics? Journal of Economic Literature 28:1115–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leiderman, L. 1980. Macroeconometric testing of the rational expectations and structural neutrality hypothesis for the United States. Journal of Monetary Economics 6: 69–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4:103–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1973. Some international evidence on output-inflation trade offs. American Economic Review 63:326–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1975. An equilibrium model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 83:1113–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAleer, M. and MacKenzie, C.R. 1991. Keynesian and New Classical models of unemployment revisited. Economic Journal 101, May: 359–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B.T. 1989. Real business cycle models. In Modern Business Cycle Theory, ed. R.J. Barro, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F.S. 1982. Does anticipated monetary policy matter? An econometric investigation. Journal of Political Economy 90, February: 22–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muth, J.F. 1961. Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica 29:315–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran, M.H. 1982. A critique of the proposed tests of the natural rate-rational expectations hypothesis. Economic Journal 92, September: 529–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran, M.H. 1987. The Limits to Rational Expectations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran, M.H. 1988. On the policy ineffectiveness proposition and a Keynesian alternative: a rejoinder. Economic Journal 98, June: 504–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E.S. 1967. Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time. Economica 34: 254–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E.S. 1970. The New Microeconomics in employment and inflation theory. In Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory, ed. E.S. Phelps et al., New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rush, M. and Waldo, D. 1988. On the policy ineffectiveness proposition and a Keynesian alternative. Economic Journal 98, June: 498–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.J. 1973. Rational expectations, the real rate of interest and the natural rate of unemployment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 429–72; correction of errors, 799–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.J. 1976. A classical macroeconomic model for the United States. Journal of Political Economy 84, April: 207–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.T. and Wallace, N. 1973. Rational expectations and the dynamics of hyperinflation. International Economic Review 14: 328–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.T. and Wallace, N. 1975. Rational expectations, the optimal monetary instrument and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 83: 241–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1970. The wage price mechanism. In The Econometrics of Price Determination Conference, ed. O. Eckstein, Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

    Google Scholar 

  • Artis, M.J. and Lewis, M.K. 1990. Money supply and demand. In Current Issues in Monetary Economics, ed. T. Bandyopadhyay and S. Ghatak, London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bank of England. 1990. Monetary aggregates in a changing environment: a statistical discussion paper. Bank of England Discussion Paper no. 47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, W.A. 1980. Economic monetary aggregates: an application of index number and aggregation theory. Journal of Econometrics 14:11–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, W.A., Offenbacher, E.K. and Spindt, P.A. 1984. The new Divisia monetary aggregates. Journal of Political Economy 92: 1049–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boughton, J.M. 1981. Money and its substitutes. Journal of Monetary Economics 8: 375–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cagan, P. and Schwartz, A.J. 1975. Has the growth of money substitutes hindered monetary policy? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 7:137–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty, V.K. 1969. On measuring the nearness of near-moneys. American Economic Review 59: 270–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chick, V. 1973. The Theory of Monetary Policy. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donovan, D.J. 1978. Modelling the demand for liquid assets: an application to Canada. IMF Staff Papers 25: 676–704.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ewis, N.A. and Fisher, D. 1984. The translog utility function and the demand for money in the United States. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 16: 34–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ewis, N.A. and Fisher, D. 1985. Toward a consistent estimate of the demand for monies: an application of the Fourier flexible form. Journal of Macroeconomics 7: 151–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feige, E.L. 1974. Temporal cross-section specifications of the demand for demand deposits. Journal of Finance 29: 923–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feige, E.L. and Pearce, D.K. 1977. The substitutability of money and near-monies: a survey of the time-series evidence. Journal of Economic Literature 15: 439–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurley, J.G. and Shaw, E.S. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Judd, J.P. and Scadding, J.L. 1982. The search for a stable money demand function: a survey of the post-1973 literature. Journal of Economic Literature 20: 993–1023.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, T.H. 1966. Substitutability of non-bank intermediary liabilities for money: the empirical evidence. Journal of Finance 21:441–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, T.C. 1983. Composite monetary indicators for the UK. Bank of England Discussion Paper, Technical Series, no. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radcliffe Committee. 1959. Report of the Committee on the Working of the Monetary System. London: HMSO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sayers, R. 1960. Monetary thought and monetary policy in England. Economic Journal 70: 710–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serletis, A. and Robb, A.L. 1986. Divisia aggregation and substitutability among monetary assets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 18: 430–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. and Brainard, W.C. 1963. Financial intermediaries and the effectiveness of monetary controls. American Economic Review 53 (Papers and Proceedings): 383–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J. 1952. The transactions demand for cash. Quarterly Journal of Economics 66, November: 545–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, S. 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85(1), February: 191–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, A. 1949. Monetary Theory and Fiscal Policy. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. 1937. Mr Keynes and the ‘classics’: a suggested interpretation. Econometrica 5, April: 147–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. 1980. Methods and problems in business cycle theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 12(4), pt 2, November: 696–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. and Sargent, T. 1979. After Keynesian macroeconomics. Federal Reserve Bank oí Minneapolis Quarterly Review 3(2), Spring: 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Metzler, L. 1951. Wealth saving and the rate of interest. Journal of Political Economy 59, April: 93–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F. 1944. Liquidity preference and the theory of interest and money. Econometrica 12, January: 45–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F. 1980. Collected Papen, Vol. I: Essays in Macroeconomics. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F. and Brumberg, R. 1954. Utility analysis and the consumption function: an interpretation of cross section data. In Post-Keynesian Economics, ed. K.K. Kurihara, New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. 1948. Price flexibility and full employment. American Economic Review 38, September: 543–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. 1956. Money, Interest and Prices. New York: Harper & Row; 2nd edn, 1965.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E. 1972. Inflation Policy and Unemployment Theory. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. 1951. Principles and rules in modern fiscal policy: a neoclassical reformulation. In Money, Trade and Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of John Henry Williams, ed. H.L. Waitzman, New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. 1955. Economics. 3rd edn, New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. 1980. Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88(1), February: 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1956. The interest-elasticity of transactions demand for cash. Review of Economics and Statistics 38, August: 241–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. Review of Economic Studies 25, February: 65–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arida, P. and Lara-Resende, A. 1986. Inflación inercial y reforma monetaria: Brasil. In Inflación Cero, ed. P. Arida, Bogota: Oveja Negra.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bacha, E. 1987. La inercia y el conflicto: el Plan Cruzado y sus desafíos. Estudios Económicos, El Colegio de Mexico (October).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, M., Di Tella, G., Dornbusch, R. and Fischer, S. (eds) 1988. Inflation Stabilization. Cambridge, Mass. and London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch, R. 1989. The road to economic recovery. Report of the Twentieth Century Fund Task Force on International Debt. New York: Priority Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jameson, K.P. 1986. Latin American structuralism: a methodological perspective. World Development, February.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. 1986. Rational Expectations and Inflation. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simonsen, M.H. 1987. Rational expectations, game theory and inflationary inertia. Paper presented to the Seventh Latin American Meeting of the Econometric Society, São Paulo, August.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, L. 1983. Structuralist Macroeconomics. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, L. ed. 1988. Varieties of Stabilization Experience. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Velasco, A. 1991. Monetarism and structuralism: some macroeconomic lessons. In The Latin American Development Debate, ed. P. Meller, Boulder and Oxford: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein, I. 1987. Periphery. In The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate and P. Newman, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosman, H.W.J. 1986. The Netherlands banking system. Amsterdam: Nederlands Instituut voor het Bank- en Effectenbedrijf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buist, M.G. 1974. At Spes Non Frata, Hope & Co. 1770–1815. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jong, A.M. de. 1967. Geschiedenis van de Nederlandse Bank (History of the Netherlands Bank). Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank (Parts I–IV).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kremers, J.J.M. 1987. Financing budget deficits in The Netherlands. De Economist 135: 340–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verrijn Stuart, G.M. 1956. Geld, Crediet en Bankwezen, Deel II Bankpolitiek (Money, Credit and the Banking System, Part II Bank Policy). The Hague: NV Uitgeversmaatschappij v/h G. Delwel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Archibald, G.C. and Lipsey, R.G. 1958. Monetary and value theory: a critique of Lange and Patinkin. Review of Economic Studies 28, October: 50–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, M.J. 1956. The welfare cost of inflationary finance. Journal of Political Economy 64, April: 93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. 1976. Rational expectations and the role of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 2, January: 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. 1978. Unanticipated money, output, and the price level in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 86, August: 549–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birati, A. and Cukierman, A. 1979. The redistributive effects of inflation and of the introduction of a real tax system in the US bond market. Journal of Public Economics 12, August: 125–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boianovsky, M. 1991. The use of the term ‘veil of money’ by Irving Fisher — a comment on Patinkin and Steiger. Unpublished note.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschen, J.F. and Grossman, H.I. 1982. Tests of equilibrium macroeconomics using contemporaneous monetary data. Journal of Monetary Economics 10, November: 309–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W.A. 1974. Money and growth: the case of long run perfect foresight. International Economic Review 15, October: 750–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cecchetti, S.G. 1986. Testing short-run neutrality. Journal of Monetary Economics 17, May: 409–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feaveryear, A. 1963. The Pound Sterling: A History of English Money, 2nd edn, revised by E.V. Morgan, Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. 1982. Inflation, capital taxation, and monetary policy. In Inflation: Causes and Effects, ed. R.E. Hall, Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 153–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, S. 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85, February: 191–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, S. 1980. On activist monetary policy with rational expectations. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 211–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. 1896. Appreciation and interest. AEA Publications 3(11), August: 331–442; reprinted, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1961.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. 1907. The Rate of Interest. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. 1911. The Purchasing Power of Money: Its Determination and Relation to Credit Interest and Crises. Rev. edn, New York: Macmillan; reprinted, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. 1923. ‘The business cycle largely a ‘Dance of the Dollar’, Journal of the American Statistical Association 18, December: 1024–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. 1930. The Theory of Interest. New York: Macmillan. Reprinted, New York: Kelley and Millman, 1954.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1970. The Counter-Revolution in Monetary Theory. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gale, D. 1982. Money: in Equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R.J. 1982. Price inertia and policy ineffectiveness in the United States, 1890–1980. Journal of Political Economy 90, December: 1087–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grandmont, J.-M. 1983. Money and Value: a Reconsideration of Classical and Neoclassical Monetary Theories. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gurley, J.G. and Shaw, E.S. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. von. 1931. Prices and Production. London: George Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F.A. von. 1935. Prices and Production. 2nd edn, London: George Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howitt, P. and Patinkin, D. 1980. Utility transformations and money illusion: comments. American Economic Review 70, September: 819–22, 826–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. 1752. ‘Of Money’, ‘Of Interest’ and ‘Of the Balance of Trade’. As reprinted in D. Hume, Writings on Economics, ed. E. Rotwein, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin Press, 1970: 33–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, T.M. 1991. Nonneutrality of money in classical monetary thought. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 77, March/April: 3–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1923. A Tract on Monetary Reform. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klausinger, H. 1990. The early use of the term ‘veil of money’ in Schumpeter’s monetary writings: a comment on Patinkin and Steiger. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92(4): 617–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleiman, E. 1984. Alut ha-inflatzya. Rivon Le-kalkalah (Economic Quarterly) 30, January: 859–64 (Hebrew). Translated and issued in May 1989 under title ‘The cost of inflation’, as Working Paper No. 211, Department of Economics, Hebrew University of Jerusalem.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. 1941. National Income and Its Composition, 1919–1938. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. 1951. National income and industrial structure. Proceedings of the International Statistical Conference 1947 5: 205–39. As reprinted in S. Kuznets, Economic Change, London: William Heinemann, 1954:145–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laidler, D. 1990. Money as a metaphorical garment before the Great War: a comment on Patinkin and Steiger. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92(4 : 613–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. 1936. The fundamental assumption of Mr. Keynes’ monetary theory of unemployment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 51, November: 192–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari, D. and Patinkin, D. 1968. The role of money in a simple growth model. American Economic Review 58, September: 713–53. As reprinted in Patinkin (1972c): 205–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lothian, J.R. 1985. Equilibrium relationships between money and other economic variables. American Economic Review 75, September: 828–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4, April: 103–24. As reprinted in Lucas (1981): 66–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1975. An equilibrium model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 83, December: 1113–44. As reprinted in Lucas (1981): 179–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1980. Two illustrations of the quantity theory of money. American Economic Review 70, December: 1005–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1981. Studies in Business Cycle Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B.T. 1980. Rational expectations and macroeconomic stabilization policy: an overview. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 12, November: 716–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metzler, L.A. 1951. Wealth, saving and the rate of interest. Journal of Political Economy 59, April: 93–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F.S. 1982. Does anticipated monetary policy matter? An econometric investigation. Journal of Political Economy 90, February: 22–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F.S. 1983. A Rational Expectations Approach to Macroeconometrics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F. 1944. Liquidity preference and the theory of interest and money. Econometrica 12, January: 45–88. As reprinted in American Economic Association, Readings in Monetary Theory, Philadelphia: Blakiston for the American Economic Association, 1951:186–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mundeil, R.A. 1963. Inflation and real interest. Journal of Political Economy 71, June: 280–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mundeil, R.A. 1965. A fallacy in the interpretation of macroeconomic equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy 73, February: 61–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. 1965. Money, Interest, and Prices. 2nd edn, New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. 1972a. On the short-run non-neutrality of money in the quantity theory. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review No. 100, March: 3–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. 1972b. Money and growth in a Keynesian full-employment model. In Patinkin (1972c): 195–204.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. 1972c. Studies in Monetary Economics. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. and Steiger, O. 1989. In search of the ‘veil of money’ and the ‘neutrality of money’: a note on the origin of terms. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 91(1): 131–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.J. 1976. A classical macroeconometric model for the United States. Journal of Political Economy 84, April: 207–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. 1917/18. Das Sozialprodukt und die Rechenpfennige. Archiv fir Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 44: 627–715. Translated under the title ‘Money and the social product’’, International Economic Papers 6:148–211. London: Macmillan, 1956, for the International Economic Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidrauski, M. 1967. Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy. American Economic Review 57, May: 534–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R.M. 1956. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, February: 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1965. Money and economic growth. Econometrica 33, October: 671–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1967. The neutrality of money in growth models: a comment. Economica 34, February: 69–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. 1898. Geldzins und Guterpreise. Trans, by R.F. Kahn as Interest and Prices: A Study of the Causes Regulating the Value of Money, London: Macmillan, 1936.

    Google Scholar 

  • Altonji, J.G. 1982. The intertemporal substitution model of labour market fluctuations: an empirical analysis. Review of Economic Studies 49(5), Special Issue: 783–824.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. 1977. Long-term contracting, sticky prices, and monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 3(3), July: 305–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. 1978. Unanticipated money, output, and the price level in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 86(4), August: 549–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. and Gordon, D. 1983. Rules, discretion, and reputation. Journal of Monetary Economics 12(1), July: 101–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, RJ. and Hercowitz, Z. 1980. Money stock revisions and unanticipated money growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 6(2), April: 257–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O.J. 1983. The production and inventory behaviour of the American automobile industry. Journal of Political Economy 91(3), June: 365–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boschen, J.F. and Grossman, H.I. 1982. Tests of equilibrium macroeconomics using contemporaneous monetary data. Journal of Monetary Economics 10(3), November: 309–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, S. 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85(1), February: 191–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, S. 1980. On activist monetary policy with rational expectations. In Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, ed. S. Fischer, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58(1), March: 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A.J. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garber, P.M. and King, R.G. 1983. Deep structural excavation. University of Rochester, Department of Economics, Working Paper 83–14, September.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R.E. and Mishkin, F.S. 1982. The sensitivity of consumption to transitory income — estimates from panel data on households. Econometrica 50(2), March: 461–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, L.P. and Singleton, K. 1983. Stochastic consumption, risk aversion, and the temporal behaviour of asset returns. Journal of Political Economy 91(2), April: 249–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O. and Hölmstrom, B. 1987. The theory of contracts. In Advances in Economic Theory, 5th World Congress, ed. T. Bewley, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, R.G. and Plosser, C.I. 1984. Money, credit, and prices in a real business cycle model. American Economic Review 74(3), June: 363–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. 1977. Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85(3), June: 473–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. 1982. Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50(6), November: 1345–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4(2), April: 103–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. 1973. Some international evidence on output-inflation tradeoffs. American Economic Review 63(3), September: 326–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: a critique. In The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. I, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. 1977. Understanding business cycles. In Stabilization of the Domestic and International Economy’, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 5, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. and Sargent, T.J. 1981. Rational Expectations and Econometric Practice. Minnesota: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N.G., Rotemberg, J.J. and Summers, L.H. 1985. Intertemporal substitution in macroeconomics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100(1), February: 225–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F.S. 1983. A Rational Expectations Approach to Macroeconometrics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. 1985. The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100(4), November: 1169–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.J. 1978. Estimation of dynamic labour demand schedules under rational expectations. Journal of Political Economy 86(6), December: 1009–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.J. 1982. Beyond demand and supply curves in macroeconomics. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 72(2), May: 382–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T.J. and Wallace, N. 1975. ‘Rational’ expectations, the optimal monetary instrument, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 83(2), April: 241–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims, C.A. 1980. Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica 48(1), January: 1–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J.B. 1980. Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88(1), February: 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, F. 1970. Banking and interest rates in a world without money: the effects of uncontrolled banking. Journal of Banking Research 1: 8–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. and Kroszner, R. 1987. The development of the new monetary economics. Journal of Political Economy 95: 567–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. and Kroszner, R. 1990a. Empirical predictions of the new monetary economics: perspectives on velocity. Journal of Policy Modeling 12: 265–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, T. and Kroszner, R. 1990b. Mutual fund banking: a market approach. Cato Journal 10: 223–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorn, J.A. 1989. Introduction: alternatives to government fiat money. Cato Journal 9: 277–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd, K. 1989. The State and the Monetary System. London and New York: Philip Allan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. 1980. Banking in the theory of finance. Journal of Monetary Economics 6: 39–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. 1983. Financial intermediation and price level control. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 7–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, S. 1983. A framework for monetary and banking analysis. Economic Journal (Supplement) 93: 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. 1986. Has government any role in money? Journal of Monetary Economics 17: 37–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, C.A.E. 1986. The implications of shifting frontiers in financial markets for monetary control. In Shifting Frontiers in Financial Markets, ed. D.E. Fair, Dordrecht: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenfield, R. and Yeager, L. 1983. A laissez-faire approach to monetary stability. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 15: 302–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenfield, R. and Yeager, L. 1986. Competitive payments systems: comment. American Economic Review 76: 848–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R.E. 1982a. Explorations in the Gold Standard and related policies for stabilising the dollar. In Inflation: Causes and Effects, ed. R.E. Hall, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R.E. 1982b. Monetary trends in the United States and the United Kingdom: a review from the perspective of new developments in monetary economics. Journal of Economic Literature 20:1552–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R.E. 1983. Optional fiduciary monetary systems. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. 1976. Denationalisation of Money. 2nd edn, London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1935. A suggestion for simplifying the theory of money. Economica N.S. 2:1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoover, K.D. 1988. Money, prices and finance in the new monetary economics. Oxford Economic Papers 40: 150–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, H.G. 1968. Problems of efficiency in monetary management. Journal of Political Economy 76: 971–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, R.G. 1983. On the economics of private money. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 127–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makinen, G.E. and Woodward, G.T. 1986. Some anecdotal evidence relating to the Legal Restrictions Theory of the demand for money. Journal of Political Economy 94: 260–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B.T. 1985. Bank deregulation, accounting systems of exchange, and the unit of account. A critical review. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 23: 13–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B.T. 1990. Comments on Empirical predictions of the new monetary economics: perspectives on velocity. Journal of Policy Modeling 12: 281–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. 1989. Eliminating monetary disturbances. Cato Journal 9: 423–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mott, T. 1989. A post Keynesian perspective on a ‘cashless’ competitive payments system. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 11:360–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niehans, J. 1978. The Theory of Money. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Driscoll, G.P. 1985. Money in a deregulated financial system. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Review, May: 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sumner, S. 1990. The forerunners of ‘new monetary economics’ proposals to stabilize the unit of account. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 22:109–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1963. Commercial banks as creators of ‘money’. In Banking and Monetary Studies, ed. D. Carson. Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallace, N. 1983. A legal restrictions theory of the demand for ‘money’ and the role of monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 7:1–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallace, N. 1988. A suggestion for oversimplifying the theory of money. Economic Journal (Conference Papers) 98:25–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L.H. 1984. Competitive payments systems and the unit of account. American Economic Review 74: 699–712.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L.H. 1986. Competitive payments systems: reply. American Economic Review 76: 850–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L.H. 1987. Accounting for non-interest bearing currency: a critique of the Legal Restrictions Theory of money. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 19: 448–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, L.H. 1989a. What kinds of monetary institutions would a free market deliver? Cato Journal 9: 367–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L.H. 1989b. Competition and Currency. New York and London: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L.H. 1990a. Competitive money reform: a review essay. Journal of Monetary Economics 26: 191–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, L.H. 1990b. Scottish banking and the Legal Restrictions Theory: a closer look. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 22: 526–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeager, L. 1989. A competitive payments system: some objections considered. Journal of Post-Key nesian Economia 11: 370–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeager, L. and Greenfield, R. 1989. Can monetary disequilibrium be eliminated? Cato Journal 9: 405–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B.S. 1983. Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the great depression. American Economic Review 73: 257–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunner, K. 1969. Monetary analysis and Federal Reserve policy. In Targets and Indicators of Monetary policy, ed. K. Brunner, San Francisco: Chandler.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gertler, M. 1988. Financial structure and aggregate economic activity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20(2) : 559–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gramley, L.E. and Chase, S.B., Jr. 1969. Time deposits in monetary analysis. In Targets and Indicators of Monetary policy, ed. K. Brunner, San Francisco: Chandler.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurley, J. and Shaw, E.S. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1963. Commercial banks as creators of ‘money’. In Banking and Monetary Studies, ed. D. Carson, Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1969. A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1:15–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. and Brainard, W.C. 1963. Financial intermediaries and the effectiveness of monetary control. American Economic Review 53:383–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • New York Stock Exchange. 1980–90. Fact Book. New York: New York Stock Exchange.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, R. 1967. The Big Board: A History of the New York Stock Market. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, R. 1975. N.YS.E.: A History of the New York Stock Exchange, 1935–1975. New York: Weybright and Talley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, F. 1986. Noise. Journal of Finance 41, July: 529–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D., Poterba, J. and Summers, L. 1989. What moves stock prices? Journal of Portfolio Management 15, Spring: 4–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Long, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L. and Waldmann, R. 1990. Noise trader risk in financial markets. Journal of Political Economy 98(4), August: 703–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Long, J.B. and Shleifer, A. 1991. The stock market bubble of 1929: evidence from closed-end mutual funds. Journal of Economic History 51(3), September: 675–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. 1965. The behavior of stock market prices. Journal of Business 38: 34–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. and French, K. 1988. Permanent and temporary components of stock market prices. Journal of Political Economy 96, April: 246–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French, K. and Poterba, J. 1989. Are Japanese stock prices too high? Cambridge, Mass.: Massachusetts Institute of Technology xerox.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1953. The case for flexible exchange rates. In Essays in Positive Economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keim, D. 1983. Size-related anomalies and stock market seasonality: further empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 12, June: 13–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyle, A.S. 1985. Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53, November: 1315–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, C., Shleifer, A. and Thaler, R. 1991. Investor sentiment and the closed-end fund puzzle. Journal of Finance 46, March: 75–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann, B. 1990. Fads, martingales, and market efficiency. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(1), February: 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malkiel, B. 1973. A Random Walk Down Wall Street. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. 1987. The interrelations of finance and economics: theoretical perspectives. American Economic Review 77, May: 29–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. 1989. Market Volatility. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maravall, A. and Pierce, D.A. 1983. Preliminary-data error and monetary aggregate targeting. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 1:179–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maravall, A. and Pierce, D.A. 1986. The transmission of data noise into policy noise in monetary control. Econometrica 43: 961–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgenstern, O. 1963. On the Accuracy of Economic Observations. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, C.R. 1972. The prediction performance of the FRB-MIT-Penn model of the US economy. American Economic Review 62: 902–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierce, D.A. 1977. Relationships — and the lack thereof- between economic time series, with special reference to money and interest rates. Journal of the American Statistical Association 71: 11–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierce, D.A., Parke, D.W., Cleveland, W.P. and Maravall, A. 1981. Uncertainty in the monetary aggregates: sources, measurement and policy effects. Journal of Finance 36: 507–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abuaf, N. and Jorion, P. 1990. Purchasing power parity in the long run. Journal of Finance 45: 157–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. 1989. The message in daily exchange rates: a conditional variance tale. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 7(3): 297–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. 1990. A multivariate generalized ARCH approach to modeling risk premia in forward foreign exchange rate markets. Journal of International Money and Finance 9: 309–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baillie, R.T. and McMahon, P. 1989. The Foreign Exchange Market: Theory and Econometric Evidence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diebold, F.X. and Nason, J.M. 1990. Nonparametric exchange rate prediction. Journal of International Economics 28: 315–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch, R. 1976. Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84: 1161–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, J.A. 1976. A monetary approach to the exchange rate: doctrinal aspects and empirical evidence. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 78: 200–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J.A. and Froot, K.A. 1987. Using survey data to test standard propositions regarding exchange rate expectations. American Economic Review 77: 133–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodrick, R.J. 1989. Risk, uncertainty, and exchange rates. Journal of Monetary Economics 23: 433–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meese, R.A. and Rogoff, R. 1983. Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: do they fit out of sample? Journal of International Economics 14: 3–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussa, M.L. 1979. Empirical regularities in the behavior of exchange rates and theories of the foreign exchange market. In Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy 11, ed. K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. 1983. Price asynchronization and price level inertia. In Inflation, Debt, and Indexation, ed. R. Dornbusch and M. Simonsen, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58, March: 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackman, R., Layard, R. and Nickell, S. 1991. Unemployment, Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4(2), April: 103–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. 1980. Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88(1): 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. 1980. Stabilization policy ten years after. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 10th Anniversary Issue: 19–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K.J. 1959. Towards a theory of price adjustment. In The Allocation of Economic Resources, ed. M. Abramowitz, Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K.J. and Debreu, G. 1954. Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica 22: 265–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K.J. and Hahn, F.H. 1971. General Competitive Analysis. San-Francisco: Holden-Day.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. and Grossman, H.I. 1971. A general disequilibrium model of income and employment. American Economic Review 61: 82–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J. and Grossman, H.I. 1976. Money, Employment and Inflation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1975a. Neo-Keynesian disequilibrium theory in a monetary economy. Review of Economic Studies 42: 503–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1975b. Disequilibrium exchange in barter and monetary economies. Economic Inquiry 13:131–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1976. The disequilibrium approach to monopolistic price setting and general monopolistic equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 43: 69–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1977a. A neo-Keynesian model of price and quantity determination in disequilibrium. In Equilibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory, ed. G. Schwödiauer, Boston: Reidel Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1977b. On quantity signals and the foundations of effective demand theory. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 79: 147–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1982. The Economics of Market Disequilibrium. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1984. A non-Walrasian model of the business cycle. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 5: 77–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1986. Macroeconomics: An Introduction to the Non-Walrasian Approach. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1987. Imperfect competition, unemployment and policy. European Economic Review 31: 417–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1988. The objective demand curve in general equilibrium with price makers. Economic Journal 98, Supplement: 37–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1990. Non-Walrasian equilibria, money and macroeconomics. In Handbook of Monetary Economics, (eds) B. Friedman and F.H. Hahn, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1991a. Microeconomic foundations and properties of a macroeconomic model with imperfect competition. In Issues in Contemporary Economics. Markets and Welfare, ed. K.J. Arrow, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy, J.-P. 1991b. Optimal government policy in a macroeconomic model with imperfect competition and rational expectations. In Equilibrium Theory and Applications: A Conference in Honor of Jacques Drèze, ed. W. Barnett, B. Cornet, C. D’Aspremont, J.J. Gabszewicz and A. Mas Colell, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bushaw, D.W. and Clower, R.W. 1957. Introduction to Mathematical Economics. Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin, E.H. 1933. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. 7th edn, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1956.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clower, R.W. 1965. The Keynesian counterrevolution: a theoretical appraisal. In The Theory of Interest Rates, (eds) F.H. Hahn and F.P.R. Brechling, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuddington, J.T. Johansson, P.-O. and Löfgren, K.G. 1984. Disequilibrium Macroeconomics in Open Economies. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • D’Autume, A. 1985. Monnaie, Croissance et Déséquilibre. Paris: Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A.K. 1978. The balance of trade in a model of temporary equilibrium with rationing. Review of Economic Studies 45: 393–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixon, H. 1987. A simple model of imperfect competition with Walrasian features. Oxford Economic Papers 39: 134–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drèze, J.H. 1975. Existence of an exchange equilibrium under price rigidities. International Economic Review 16: 301–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glustoff, E. 1968. On the existence of a Keynesian equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 35: 327–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grandmont, J.-M. and Laroque, G. 1976. On Keynesian temporary equilibria. Review of Economic Studies 43: 53–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, J. and Müller, H. 1979. Equilibria under price rigidities and externalities. In Game Theory and Related Topics, ed. O. Moeschlin and D. Pallaschke, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, F.H. and Negishi, T. 1962. A theorem on non-tatonnement stability. Econometrica 30: 463–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, B. 1951. A Study in the Theory of Inflation. London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O.D. 1982. A model of imperfect competition with Keynesian features. Quarterly Journal of Economics 97:109–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1937. Mr. Keynes and the Classics: a suggested interpretation. Econometrica 5: 147–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 2nd edn, 1946.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hildenbrand, K. and Hildenbrand, W. 1978. On Keynesian equilibria with unemployment and quantity rationing. Journal of Economic Theory 18: 255–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Honkapohja, S. 1979. On the dynamics of disequilibria in a macro model with flexible wages and prices. In New Trends in Dynamic System Theory and Economics, (eds) M. Aoki and A. Marzollo, New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ito, T. 1980. Disequilibrium growth theory. Journal of Economic Theory 23: 380–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen, H.-J. and Schultz, C. 1990. A general equilibrium macro model with wage bargaining. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92: 379–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1936. The General Theory of Money, Interest and Employment. Reprinted in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 7, London: Macmillan, for the Royal Economic Society, 1973.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1937. Alternative theories of the rate of interest. Economic Journal 47: 241–52. Reprinted in The Collected Writings of John May nard Keynes, London: Macmillan, for the Royal Economic Society, vol. 14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leijonhufvud, A. 1968. On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malinvaud, E. 1977. The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muellbauer, J. and Portes, R. 1978. Macroeconomic models with quantity rationing. Economic Journal 88: 788–821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neary, P.J. 1980. Nontraded goods and the balance of trade in a neo-Keynesian temporary equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics 95:403–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neary, P.J. and Stiglitz, J.E. 1983. Towards a reconstruction of Keynesian economics: expectations and constrained equilibria. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98, Supplement: 199–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Negishi, T. 1961. Monopolistic competition and general equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 28:196–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Negishi, T. 1977. Existence of an underemployment equilibrium. In Equilibrium and Disequilibrium in Economic Theory, ed. G. Schwödiauer, Boston: D. Reidel Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Negishi, T. 1979. Microeconomic Foundations of Keynesian Macroeconomics, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. 1956. Money, Interest and Prices. Evanston, Ill.: Row, Peterson and Company. 2nd edn, Harper and Row, New York, 1965.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. and Svensson, L.E.O. 1983. Is optimism good in a Keynesian economy? Economica 50: 291–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Picard, P. 1983. Inflation and growth in a disequilibrium macroeconomic model. Journal of Economic Theory 30: 266–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Portes, R. 1981. Macroeconomic equilibrium and disequilibrium in centrally planned economies. Economic Inquiry 19: 559–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. 1933. The Economics of Imperfect Competition, 2nd edn 1969, London: Macmillan and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulz, N. 1983. On the global uniqueness of fixprice equilibria. Econometrica 51:47–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silvestre, J. 1982. Fixprice analysis of exchange economies. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 28–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silvestre, J. 1983. Fixprice analysis in productive economies. Journal of Economic Theory 30: 401–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silvestre, J. 1988. Undominated prices in the three good model. European Economic Review 32: 161–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sneessens, H. 1987. Investment and the inflation-unemployment trade off in a macroeconomic rationing model with monopolistic competition. European Economic Review 31:781–815.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snower, D. 1983. Imperfect competition, unemployment and crowding out. Oxford Economic Papers 35: 569–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R.M. and Stiglitz, J.E. 1969. Output, employment and wages in the short run. Quarterly Journal of Economics 82: 537–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, L.E.O. 1986. Sticky goods prices, flexible asset prices, monopolistic competition and monetary policy. Review of Economic Studies 53: 385–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Triffin, R. 1940. Monopolistic Competition and General Equilibrium Theory, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walras, L. 1874. Eléments d’Economie politique pure, Lausanne: Corbaz. Definitive edition translated by W. Jaffe as Elements of Pure Economics, London: Allen & Unwin, 1954.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M.L. 1982. Increasing returns and the foundations of unemployment theory. Economic Journal 92: 787–804.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M.L. 1985. The simple macroeconomics of profit sharing. American Economic Review 75: 937–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Younes, Y. 1975. On the role of money in the process of exchange and the existence of a non-Walrasian equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 42: 489–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anscombe, F.J. and Aumann, R.J. 1963. A definition of subjective probability. Annals of Mathematical Statistics 34:199–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chew, S.H. 1983. A generalization of the quasilinear mean with applications to the measurement of income inequality and decision theory resolving the Allais paradox. Econometrica 51: 1065–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chew, S.H. 1989. Axiomatic utility theories with the betweenness property. Annals of Operations Research 19: 273–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chew, S.H. and MacCrimmon, K.R. 1979. Alpha-nu choice theory: a generalization of expected utility theory. University of British Columbia Faculty of Commerce and Business Administration Working Paper No. 686.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellsberg, D. 1961. Risk, ambiguity, and the Savage axioms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 75: 643–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G. 1991. Behavior under risk; recent developments in theory and applications. In Advances in Economic Theory, ed. J. J. Laffont, London: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G. and Zin, S.E. 1989. Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumpion and asset returns: a theoretical framework. Econometrica 57: 937–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G. and Zin, S.E. 1991. Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: an empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy 99: 263–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P.C. 1983. Transitive measurable utility. Journal of Economic Theory 31: 293–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilboa, I. 1987. Expected utility with purely subjective nonadditive probabilities. Journal of Mathematical Economics 16: 65–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kami, E. and Safra, Z. 1989. Ascending bid auctions with behaviorally consistent bidders. Annals of Operations Research 19: 435–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kami, E. and Schmeidler, D. 1991a. Utility theory with uncertainty. In Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 4, ed. W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein, New York and Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kami, E. and Schmeidler, D. 1991b. Atemporal dynamic consistency and expected utility theory. Journal of Economic Theory 54:401–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M.J. 1982. ‘Expected utility’ analysis without the independence axiom. Econometrica 50: 277–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M.J. 1989. Dynamic consistency and non-expected utility models of choice under uncertainty. Journal of Economic Literature 27:1622–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M.J. and Schmeidler, D. 1990. A more robust definition of subjective probability. Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quiggin, J. 1982. A theory of anticipated utility. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3: 323–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savage, L.J. 1954. The Foundations of Statistics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmeidler, D. 1986. Integral representation without additivity. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society 97: 255–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmeidler, D. 1989. Subjective probability and expected utility without additivity. Econometrica 57: 571–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segal, U. 1990. Two-stage lotteries without the reduction axiom. Econometrica 58: 349–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. and Morgenstern, O. 1947. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. 2nd edn, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P.P. 1989. Additive Representation of Preferences, A New Foundation of Decision Analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Yaari, M.E. 1987. The dual theory of choice under risk. Econometrica 55: 95–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaver, W., Eger, C., Ryan, S. and Wolfson, M. 1989. Financial reporting, supplemental disclosures, and bank share prices. Journal of Accounting Research 27: 157–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonson, D.G. 1987. Banks that fail. United States Banker, September: 78–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. and Verdier, T. 1991. Interest rate deregulation and bank competition. Mimeo, DELTA, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. 1979. Quality and quantity competition. Review of Economic Studies 46: 587–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matutes, C. and Padilla, J. 1991. Shared ATM networks and banking competition. Mimeo, IAE, University of Barcelona.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matutes, C. and Vives, X. 1991. Competition for deposits and risk of failure in banking. Mimeo, IAE, University of Barcelona.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop, S. 1979. Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell Journal of Economics 10(1): 141–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Startz, R. 1979. Implicit interest on demand deposits. Journal of Monetary Economics V: 515–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Startz, R. 1983. Competition and interest rate ceilings in commercial banking. Quarterly Journal of Economics XCVIII: 255–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atchison, M., Butler, K. and Simonds, R. 1987. Nonsynchronous security trading and market index autocorrelation. Journal of Finance 42:111–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, K., Maier, S., Schwartz, R. and Whitcomb, D. 1978. The returns generation process, returns variance, and the effect of thinness in securities markets. Journal of Finance 33:149–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, K., Maier, S., Schwartz, R. and Whitcomb, D. 1979. On the existence of serial correlation in an efficient securities market. TIMS Studies in the Management Sciences 11: 151–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, K., Hawawini, G., Maier, S., Schwartz, R. and Whitcomb, D. 1983a. Estimating and adjusting for the intervalling-effect bias in beta. Management Science 29: 135–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, K., Hawawini, G., Maier, S., Schwartz, R. and Whitcomb, D. 1983b. Friction in the trading process and the estimation of systematic risk. Journal of Financial Economics 12: 263–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dimson, E. 1979. Risk measurement when shares are subject to infrequent trading. Journal of Financial Economics 7: 197–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, L. 1966. Some new stock market indexes. Journal of Business 39:191–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fowler, D. and Rorke, C. 1983. Risk measurement when shares are subject to infrequent trading. Journal of Financial Economics 12: 279–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Handa, P., Kothari, S. and Wasley, C. 1989. The relation between the return interval and betas. Journal of Financial Economics 23: 79–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. 1988a. Stock market prices do not follow random walks: evidence from a simple specification test. Review of Financial Studies 1: 41–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. 1988b. Notes on a Markov model of nonsynchronous trading. Working paper, Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. 1989. An econometric analysis of nonsynchronous trading. Journal of Econometrics 45: 181–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. 1990. When are contrarian profits due to stock market overreaction? Review of Financial Studies 3: 175–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muthuswamy, J. 1990. Asynchronous closing prices and spurious autocorrelation in portfolio returns. Working paper, Fuqua School of Business, Duke University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scholes, M. and Williams, J. 1977. Estimating beta from non- synchronous data. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 309–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shanken, J. 1987. Nonsynchronous data and the covariance structure of returns. Journal of Finance 42: 221–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg, S.A., Forsund, F.R. and Jansen, E.S. 1991. Malmquist indices of productivity growth during the deregulation of Norwegian banking 1980–89. Norges Bank Arbeidsnotat (Working Paper) no. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edison, H.J. and Vârdal, E. 1990. Optimal currency baskets for small, developed economies. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 92(4): 559–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isachsen, A.J. (ed.) 1991. Ni Artikler om Penger, Kreditt og Valuta. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundaca, E.G. 1991. The volatility of the Norwegian currency basket. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 93(1): 53–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norges Bank. 1989. Norwegian credit markets. Norwegian monetary and credit policy. Norges Banks Skriflserie no. 17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norges Offentlige Utredninger (NOU). 1989. Penger og Kreditt i en Omstillingstid. (NOU 1989:1). Oslo: Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vikøren, B. 1989. Hvilke Muligheter har Norge til å føre en Selvstendig Rentepolitikk? Norsk Økonomisk Tidsskrift 103(1): 37–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cargill, T.F. and Garcia, G.G. 1982. Financial Deregulation and Monetary Control: Historical Perspective and Impact of the 1980 Art. Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munn, G.G. and Garcia, F.L. 1991. Encyclopedia of Banking and Finance. Ninth Edition. Boston: Bankers Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Association of Mutual Savings Banks (NAMSB). Various years. Annual Report. Washington DC: NAMSB.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woerheide, W.J. 1984. The Savings and Loan Industry: Current Problems and Possible Solutions. Westport, Connecticut: Quorum Books.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Peter Newman Murray Milgate John Eatwell

Copyright information

© 1992 Palgrave Macmillan, a division of Macmillan Publishers Limited

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Newman, P., Milgate, M., Eatwell, J. (1992). N. In: Newman, P., Milgate, M., Eatwell, J. (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money & Finance. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-11721-5_1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-11721-5_1

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-349-11723-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-349-11721-5

  • eBook Packages: Palgrave History CollectionHistory (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics