Sir James Steuart (1713–1780)

  • J. E. King

Abstract

It was with reference to Sir James Steuart that T. W. Hutchison wrote: ‘In no branch of the subject is the dictum about history being the reward of the victors more valid than in the history of economics.’1 Steuart’s Inquiry into the Principles of Political Oeconomy was the first systematic economic treatise to be published in Britain, and introduced the very term ‘political economy’ into the English language.2 But he was eclipsed by his compatriot Adam Smith, if not within his own lifetime then most definitely in the eyes of subsequent generations. In recent decades there has been something of a Steuart revival, accompanied, however, by fundamental differences in the interpretation of his ideas. For some commentators Steuart was a moderate liberal, a pioneer proponent of the mixed economy, and an important predecessor of Keynes on both theoretical matters and issues of economic policy.3 Others see him as the ‘apotheosis of mercantilism’, an enemy of the free market who urged the establishment of a corporate state.4 A third view, influenced by Steuart’s own ideological background as well as by the assessment of Karl Marx, is that he was essentially an early historical materialist whose prime concern was the interrelationship between economic development and sociopolitical change.5

Keywords

Income Explosive Expense Pyramid 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. 1.
    T. W. Hutchison, review of Sir James Steuart, An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Oeconomy, ed. A. S. Skinner (Edinburgh: Oliver & Boyd, 1966), hereafter cited as Principles, Economic Journal 77, 1967, p. 645.Google Scholar
  2. 2.
    W. Letwin, The Origins of Scientific Economics: English Economic Thought1660–1776 (London: Methuen, 1963), p. 217.Google Scholar
  3. According to Cannan, this was sufficient to prevent Adam Smith from using the term in the title of his Wealth of Nations: E. Cannan, A Review of Economic Theory (London: Cass, 1964; first published 1929), p. 43.Google Scholar
  4. 3.
    Hutchison, op. cit.; S. R. Sen, ‘Sir James Steuart’s General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money’, Economica n.s. 14, 1947, pp. 19–36;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Sen, The Economics of Sir James Steuart (London: London School of Economics/Bell, 1957);Google Scholar
  6. D. Vickers, Studies in the Theory of Money 1690–1776 (London: Peter Owen, 1960), pp. 240–90.Google Scholar
  7. 4.
    G. M. Anderson and R. D. Tollson, ‘Sir James Steuart as the Apotheosis of Mercantilism and his Relationship to Adam Smith’, Southern Economic Journal 51, 1984, pp. 456–68;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. W. Eltis, ‘Sir James Steuart’s Corporate State’, paper presented to the British Association for the Advancement of Science, Glasgow, 1985.Google Scholar
  9. 5.
    R. L. Meek, ‘The Rehabilitation of Sir James Steuart’, pp. 3–17 of Meek, Economics and Ideology and Other Essays: Studies in the Development of Economic Thought (London: Chapman & Hall, 1967);Google Scholar
  10. A. Skinner, ‘Sir James Steuart: Economics and Politics’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy 9, 1962, pp. 17–37; Skinner, ‘Analytical Introduction’ to Steuart, Principles, pp. lviii–lxxxiv;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. M. Perelman, ‘Classical Political Economy and Primitive Accumulation: the Case of Smith and Steuart’, History of Political Economy 15, 1983, pp. 451–94;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Perelman, Classical Political Economy: Primitive Accumulation and the Social Division of Labour (Totowa, N.J.: Rowman & Allanheld, 1983), ch. 3.Google Scholar
  13. 6.
    A. Chitnis, The Scottish Enlightenment (London: Croom Helm, 1976);Google Scholar
  14. J. Rendall, The Origins of the Scottish Enlightenment (London: Macmillan, 1976);Google Scholar
  15. R. H. Campbell and A. S. Skinner, The Origins and Nature of the Scottish Enlightenment (Edinburgh: John Donald, 1982);Google Scholar
  16. I. Hont and M. Ignatieff (eds), Wealth and Virtue: the Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983).Google Scholar
  17. 7.
    R. L. Meek, ‘The Scottish Contribution to Marxist Sociology’, pp. 34–50 of Meek, Economics and Ideology; A. S. Skinner, ‘A Scottish Contribution to Marxist Sociology?’, pp. 79–114 of I. Bradley and M. C. Howard (eds), Classical and Marxian Political Economy: Essays in Honour of R. L. Meek (London: Macmillan, 1982).Google Scholar
  18. 8.
    A. L. MacFie, ‘The Scottish Tradition in Economic Thought’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy 2, 1955, pp. 81–103;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. A. S. Skinner, ‘Economics and History: the Scottish Enlightenment’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy 12, 1965, pp. 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. 9.
    Unless otherwise stated, all biographical details are taken from A. S. Skinner, ‘Biographical Sketch’, in Steuart, Principles, pp. xxi-lvii, which largely supersedes W. L. Taylor, ‘A Short Life of Sir James Steuart: Political Economist’, South African Journal of Economics 25, 1957, pp. 290–302; andCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. P. Chamley, Documents rélatifs à Sir James Steuart (Paris: Dalloz, 1965).Google Scholar
  22. 10.
    MacFie, op. cit., p. 83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. 12.
    E. A. J. Johnson, Predecessors of Adam Smith (London: P. S. King, 1937), pp. 209–10;Google Scholar
  24. J. A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (London: Allen & Unwin, 1954), p. 176, n. 9.Google Scholar
  25. 14.
    Sir James Steuart, Works, Political, Metaphysical and Chronological, six volumes, ed. General Sir James Steuart (London: Cadell & Davies, 1805; reprinted New York, Kelley, 1967); for details of the Skinner edition see note 1.Google Scholar
  26. 15.
    Johnson, op. cit., p. 213. Sen and Vickers are important exceptions.Google Scholar
  27. 16.
    Anderson and Tollson, op. cit., pp. 463–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. 20.
    Works I, pp. 244–5 (Principles, pp. 160–1); cf. M. H. Dobb, Theories of Value and Distribution Since Adam Smith (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973), pp. 43–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. 25.
    Works I, pp. 375–7 (Principles, pp. 246–7). On Steuart’s pessimism, which is one of his most obvious intellectual characteristics, see Johnson, op. cit., pp. 229–30 (where it is attributed to the influence of David Hume);Google Scholar
  30. and W. Stark, ‘Steuart, James Denham’, in D. L. Sills (ed.), International Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences 15 (New York: Macmillan and The Free Press, 1968), pp. 265–6. The Scottish Enlightenment in general displayed less optimism than the contemporary French philosophers (Skinner, ‘Economics and History’, p. 17).Google Scholar
  31. 26.
    E. S. Furniss, The Position of the Labourer in a System of Nationalism (New York: Kelley, 1965; first published 1920), pp. 157–97, 201.Google Scholar
  32. 30.
    J. S. Mill, Principles of Political Economy, ed. W. J. Ashley (London: Longmans, Green, 1909; first published 1848), pp. 748–51; cf.Google Scholar
  33. Anderson and Tollson, op. cit., p. 459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. 43.
    Smith to William Pulteney, 3 September 1772, in E. C. Mossner and I. S. Ross, The Correspondence of Adam Smith (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1977), p. 164; Chamley, Documents, pp. 66–7, 141 (Letter from Steuart to Chalmers(?) on the price of grain, 14 October 1777).Google Scholar
  35. 44.
    Anderson and Tollson, op. cit., p. 465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. 46.
    S. Rashid, ‘Adam Smith’s Rise to Fame: a Re-examination of the Evidence’, The Eighteenth Century 23, 1982, pp. 64–85.Google Scholar
  37. 55.
    Rashid, op. cit., pp. 71, 78.Google Scholar
  38. 56.
    Ibid., pp. 76–9; Edinburgh Weekly Magazine, 7 December 1780, pp. 261–2.Google Scholar
  39. 60.
    Rashid, op. cit., pp. 80–1;Google Scholar
  40. P. Deane and W. A. Cole, British Economic Growth 1688–1959 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1967), p. 33, table 8.Google Scholar
  41. 61.
    D. Ricardo, The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, ed. P. Sraffa (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1951–2), I, p. 5; III, pp. 7, 32–3, 72–7, 81; IV, p. 59n; VI, p. 34; VII, p. 202.Google Scholar
  42. 62.
    J. K. Ingham, ‘Sir James Steuart’, in P. H. I. Palgrave (ed.), Dictionary of Political Economy (London: Macmillan, 1918), pp. 475–6.Google Scholar
  43. 63.
    A. Marshall, Principles of Economics (London: Macmillan, eighth edn, 1962; first published 1890), pp. 58, n. 2, 146, n. 2, 626;Google Scholar
  44. W. Cunningham, ‘The Progress of Economic Doctrine in England in the Eighteenth Century’, Economic Journal 1, 1891, pp. 84–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. 64.
    P. Chamley, Économie politique et philosophie chez Steuart et Hegel (Paris: Dalloz, 1963),Google Scholar
  46. and Chamley, ‘Les origines de la pensée économique de Hegel’, Hegel-Studien 3, 1965, pp. 225–61. More generally on Hegel’s social and economic thought,Google Scholar
  47. see S. Avineri, Hegel’s Theory of the Modern State (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1972) andCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. D. Cullen, Hegel’s Social and Political Thought: an Introduction (Dublin: Gill & Macmillan, 1979).Google Scholar
  49. 66.
    K. Marx, Capital I (Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House, 1961), pp. 352n, 616n, 657n (Malthus); Critique of Political Economy (London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1971), p. 168 (Smith).Google Scholar
  50. 67.
    K. Marx, The Poverty of Philosophy (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1973), p. 133.Google Scholar
  51. 69.
    Capital I, p. 332n; Marx, Theories of Surplus Value I (London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1969), pp. 41–3; IIII (London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1972), p. 399; Capital III (Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House 1962), p. 766;Google Scholar
  52. F. Engels, Anti-Dühring (London: Lawrence & Wishart, 1942), p. 278 (the relevant chapter was written by Marx, not Engels).Google Scholar
  53. 70.
    E. Cannan, Theories of Production and Distribution in English Political Economy From 1776 to 1848 (London: P. S. King, 1920; first published 1893), p. 4; cf. Cannan, Review of Economic Theory, p. 24;Google Scholar
  54. Johnson, op. cit., pp. 209–34.Google Scholar
  55. 71.
    P. Chamley, ‘Sir James Steuart, Inspirateur de la théorie générale de Lord Keynes?’, Revue d’Économie Politique 72, 1962, pp. 303–13;Google Scholar
  56. P. Lambert, ‘Steuart et Keynes: bref commentaire sur l’étude de M. Chamley’, ibid., 73, 1963, pp. 104–5;Google Scholar
  57. Chamley, ‘Steuart et Keynes: réflexions sur le commentaire de M. Lambert’, ibid., pp. 105–9.Google Scholar
  58. 72.
    Sen, ‘Sir James Steuart’s General Theory’, p. 35; Sen, Economics of Sir James Steuart, p. 188; on Steuart’s nationalism see G. E. Davie, ‘Anglophobe and Anglophil’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy 14, 1967, pp. 291–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. 73.
    D. Vickers, Studies, p. 268; Vickers, review of Steuart, Works, Journal of Economic Literature 8, 1970, pp. 1190–5.Google Scholar
  60. 76.
    M. A. Akhtar, ‘Steuart on Growth’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy 25, 1978, pp. 57–74;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Akhtar, ‘An Analytical Outline of Sir James Steuart’s Macroeconomic Model’, Oxford Economic Papers 31, 1979, pp. 283–302.Google Scholar
  62. 78.
    Perelman, Classical Political Economy, op. cit.;Google Scholar
  63. Skinner, ‘Sir James Steuart: Economics and Politics’, op. cit.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. 79.
    Anderson and Tollson, op. cit., p. 459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. 80.
    Eltis, op. cit., p. 31;Google Scholar
  66. L. Panitch, ‘Trade Unions and the Capitalist State’, New Left Review 125, 1981, pp. 21–43.Google Scholar
  67. 82.
    H. W. Spiegel, The Growth of Economic Thought (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1971), p. 215.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© J. E. King 1988

Authors and Affiliations

  • J. E. King
    • 1
  1. 1.University of LancasterUK

Personalised recommendations