A Survey of Welfare Economics, 1939–59

  • E. J. Mishan

Abstract

While it continues to fascinate many, welfare economics does not appear at any time to have wholly engaged the labours of any one economist. It is a subject which, apparently, one dabbles in for a while, leaves and, perhaps, returns to later in response to a troubled conscience—which goes some way to explain why, more than other branches of economics, it suffers from an unevenness in its development, a lack of homogeneity in its treatment and, until very recently, a distressing disconnectedness between its parts.2

Keywords

Corn Income Assure Beach Expense 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Bibliography

  1. 1.
    Abramovitz and others. Allocation of Economic Resources (California: Stanford U.P., 1959).Google Scholar
  2. 2.
    Allais, M. “Rendement Social et Productivité Sociale,” Econometrica, Supplement to Vol. 17. 1949. Section: Theory of Choice and Utilisation of Resources, p. 129.Google Scholar
  3. 3.
    Allen, C.L. “Modem Welfare Economies and Public Policy,” S.E. J., 1952–3, Vol. XIX, p. 28.Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    Allen, J.E. “A Fairer Income Tax,” E.J., 1940, p. 475.Google Scholar
  5. 5.
    Archibald, G.C. “Saving and the Welfare Theory of Taxation,” Economic Record, 1955, p. 90.Google Scholar
  6. 6.
    Archibald, G.C. “Welfare Economics, Ethics & Essentialism,” Economica, N.S., Vol. XXVI, November 1959, p. 104.Google Scholar
  7. 7.
    Armstrong, W.E. “Utility and the Theory of Welfare,” O.E.P., 1951, N.S., Vol. 3, No. 3, p. 259.Google Scholar
  8. 8.
    Armstrong, W.E. “A Reply,” O.E.P., 1953, N.S., Vol. 5, No. 3, p. 264.Google Scholar
  9. 9.
    Arrow, K.J. “The Possibility of a Universal Social Welfare Function.” Project Rand Rad (L)—289, October 26, 1948 (Santa Monica, California) (Lectographed).Google Scholar
  10. 10.
    Arrow, K.J. “A Difficulty in the Concept of Social Welfare,” J.P.E., 1950, Vol. LVIII, No. 4, p. 328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. 11.
    Arrow, K.J. “Little’s Critique of Welfare Economics,” A.E.R., 1951, p. 923.Google Scholar
  12. 12.
    Arrow, K.J. “The Allocation of Risk Bearing,” Econometrica, 1955 [Abstracts], p. 342.Google Scholar
  13. 13.
    Arrow, K.J. “An Extension of the Basic Theories of Classical Welfare Economics,” Proceedings of the 2nd Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics &c Probability (Univ. of Calif. Press, 1951).Google Scholar
  14. 14.
    Arrow, K.J. Social Choice and Individual Values (New York, 1951).Google Scholar
  15. 15.
    Arrow, K.J., and Hurwicz, L. “Dynamic Aspects of Achieving Optimal Allocation of Resources,” Econometrica, 1952 [Abstracts], p. 86.Google Scholar
  16. 16.
    Atkinson, F.J. “Saving and Investment in a Socialist State,” R.E.S., 1947–48, Vol. XV (2) 78.Google Scholar
  17. 17.
    Bailey, M.J. “The Interpretation and Application of the Compensation Principle,” EJ., 1954, p. 39.Google Scholar
  18. 18.
    Bailey, M.J. “The Welfare Cost of Inflationary Finance,” J.P.E., 1956, Vol. LXIV, No. 2, p. 93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. 19.
    Baldwin, R.E. “A Comparison of Welfare Criteria,” R.E.S., Vol. XXI (2), No. 55, p. 154.Google Scholar
  20. 20.
    Baldwin, R.E. “The New Economics and Gains in International Trade,” Q.J.E., 1952, p. 91.Google Scholar
  21. 21.
    Balogh, T. “Welfare & Freer Trade—A Reply,” E.J., 1951, p. 72.Google Scholar
  22. 22.
    Bator, F.M. “The Simple Analytics of Welfare Maximization,” A.E.R., 1957, p. 22.Google Scholar
  23. 23.
    Baumol, W.J. “Community Indifference,” R.E.S., Vol. XIV (1), No. 35, p. 44.Google Scholar
  24. 24.
    Baumol, W.J. “The Community Indifference Map: A Construction,” R.E.S., Vol. XVII (3), No. 44, p. 189.Google Scholar
  25. 25.
    Baumol, W.J. Review of K.J. Arrow, Social Choice and Individual Values, Econometrica, 1952, p. 110.Google Scholar
  26. 26.
    Baumol, W.J. Welfare Economics &c the Theory of the State (London: Longmans, 1952).Google Scholar
  27. 27.
    Benham, F. “The Terms of Trade,” Economica, 1940, p. 360.Google Scholar
  28. 28.
    Benham, F. “What is the Best Tax System?” Economica, 1942, p. 115.Google Scholar
  29. 29.
    Bergson, A. “Socialist Economics,” in A Survey of Contemporary Economics, Vol. I, ed. H.S. Ellis (A.E.A., 1948).Google Scholar
  30. 30.
    Bergson, A. “On the Concept of Social Welfare,” Q.J.E., 1954, p. 233.Google Scholar
  31. 31.
    Blau, J.H. “The Existence of Social Welfare Functions,” Econometrica, 1957, p. 302.Google Scholar
  32. 32.
    Blaug, M. “Welfare Indices in ‘The Wealth of Nations’,” S.E.J., Vol. XXVI, October 1959, p. 150.Google Scholar
  33. 33.
    Boulding, K.E. “Income or Welfare,” R.E.S., Vol. XVII (2), No. 43, p. 77.Google Scholar
  34. 34.
    Boulding, K.E. “The Concept of Economic Surplus,” A.E.R., 1945, p. 851.Google Scholar
  35. 35.
    Boulding, K.E. “The Concept of Economie Surplus—Corrections,” A.E.R., 1946, p. 393.Google Scholar
  36. 36.
    Boulding, K.E. “Welfare Economics” in Survey of Contemporary Economics, Vol. II, ed. B.F. Haley (A.E.A., 1952).Google Scholar
  37. 37.
    Boulding, K.E. Review of W.J. Baumol, Welfare Economics and the Theory of the State, Econometrica, 1953, p. 210.Google Scholar
  38. 38.
    Bowen, H.R. “The Interpretation of Voting in the Allocation of Economic Resources,” Q.J.E., p. 27, 1943–44.Google Scholar
  39. 39.
    Braybrooke, D. “Farewell to the New Welfare Economics,” R.E.S., Vol. XXII (3), No. 59, p. 180.Google Scholar
  40. 40.
    Break, G.F. “Excise Tax Burdens and Benefits,” A.E.R., 1954, p. 577.Google Scholar
  41. 41.
    Break, G.F., and Rolf, E.R. “The Welfare Aspects of Excise Taxes,” J.P.E., 1949, Vol. LVII, No. 1, p. 46.Google Scholar
  42. 42.
    Brown, E.C. “Mr. Kaldor on Taxation and Risk Bearing,” R.E.S., Vol. XXV (1), No. 66, p. 49.Google Scholar
  43. 43.
    Buchanan, J.M. “Knut Wicksell on Marginal Cost Pricing,” S.E.J., 1951–52, Vol. XVIII, p. 173.Google Scholar
  44. 44.
    Buchanan, J.M. “Individual Choice in Voting and the Market,” J.P.E., 1954, Vol. LXII, No. 4, p. 334.Google Scholar
  45. 45.
    Buchanan, J.M. “Social Choice, Democracy & Free Markets,” J.P.E., 1954, Vol. LXII, No. 2, p. 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. 46.
    Bye, R.T. “Welfare Considerations in Economics: A Reply,” A.E.R., 1952 [Communications], p. 384.Google Scholar
  47. 47.
    Checkland, S.G. “The Prescriptions of the Classical Economists,” Economica, 1953, p. 61.Google Scholar
  48. 48.
    Coase, R.H. “The Marginal Cost Controversy,” Economica, 1946, p. 169.Google Scholar
  49. 49.
    Coase, R.H. “The Marginal Cost Controversy. Some Further Comments,” Economica, 1947, p. 150.Google Scholar
  50. 50.
    Coen, E. “Decreasing Costs and the Gains from Trade,” Economica, 1951, p. 285.Google Scholar
  51. 51.
    Corlett, W.J., and Hague, D.C. “Complementarity and the Excess Burden of Taxation,” R.E.S., Vol. XXI, No. 54, p. 21.Google Scholar
  52. 52.
    Crutchfield, J.A. “Common Property Resources and Factor Allocation,” C.J.E. &c Pol Science, 1956, Vol. XXII, p. 292.Google Scholar
  53. 53.
    Davis, R.G. “Comment on Arrow and the ‘New Welfare’ Economics,” E.J., 1958, p. 834.Google Scholar
  54. 54.
    Debreu, G. “The Co-efficient of Resource Utilization,” Econometrica, 1951, July, p. 273.Google Scholar
  55. 55.
    Dehem, R. “Welfare Losses,” Econometrica, 1950 [Abstracts], p. 297.Google Scholar
  56. 56.
    Denis, H. “A Note on the Theory of Tariffs,” R.E.S., Vol. XII (2), No. 32, p. 110.Google Scholar
  57. 57.
    Dessus, G. The General Principles of Rate Fixing in Public Utilities. Report presented to the Congress of the Union Internationale des Producteurs et Distributeurs d’Energie Electrique, 1949. Translated in International Economie Papers, No. I, p. 5 (1951).Google Scholar
  58. 58.
    Dobb, M.H. “A Note on Index Numbers and Compensation Criteria,” O.E.P., 1956, Vol. 8, No. 1, p. 78.Google Scholar
  59. 59.
    Dorfman, R., Samuelson, P.A., and Solow, R.M. Linear Programming and Economie Analysis (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1958), Chapter 14.Google Scholar
  60. 60.
    Duesenberry, J.S. Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behaviour (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard U.P., 1949).Google Scholar
  61. 61.
    Eckstein, O. “Investment Criteria for Economic Development and the Theory of Intertemporal Welfare Economics,” Q.J.E., 1957, p. 56.Google Scholar
  62. 62.
    Ellis, H.S. “Competition and Welfare,” C.J.E. &c Pol. Science, Vol. XI, 1945, p. 554.Google Scholar
  63. 63.
    Ellis, H.S., and Fellner, W. “External Economies and Diseconomies,” A.E.R., 1943, p. 493.Google Scholar
  64. 64.
    Farrell, M.J. “Mr. Lancaster on Welfare and Choice,” E.J., 1959, p. 588.Google Scholar
  65. 65.
    Farrell, M.J. “In Defence of Public-utility Price Theory,” O.E.P., Vol. X, 1958, p. 109.Google Scholar
  66. 66.
    Fisher, F.M. “Income Distribution, Value Judgments and Welfare,” Q.J.E., 1956, p. 380.Google Scholar
  67. 67.
    Fisher, F.M., and Kenan, P.B. “Income Distribution, Value Judgments and Welfare: A Correction,” Q.J.E., 1957, p. 322.Google Scholar
  68. 68.
    Fleming, J.M. “On Making the Best of Balance of Payments Restrictions on Imports,” E.J., 1951, p. 48.Google Scholar
  69. 69.
    Fleming, J.M. “A Cardinal Concept of Welfare,” Q.J.E., 1952, p. 366.Google Scholar
  70. 70.
    Fleming, J.M. “Cardinal Welfare and Individualistic Ethics, a Comment,” J.P.E., 1957, Vol. LXV, No. 11, p. 355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. 71.
    Frankel, S.H. “‘Psychic’ and ‘Accounting’ Concepts of Income and Welfare,” O.E.P., 1952, N.S., Vol. 4, No. 1, p. 1.Google Scholar
  72. 72.
    Friedman, M. “Lerner on the Economics of Control,” J.P.E., 1947, Vol. LV, No. 5, p. 405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. 73.
    Friedman, M. “A Reply,” J.P.E., 1952, Vol. LX, No. 4, p. 334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. 74.
    Friedman, M. “The Welfare Effects of an Income Tax and Excise Tax,” J.P.E., 1952, Vol. LX, No. 1, p. 25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. 75.
    Friedman, M. “What all is Utility?” E.J., 1955, p. 405.Google Scholar
  76. 76.
    Frisch, R. “The Dupuit Taxation Theorem,” Econometrica, 1939, p. 145.Google Scholar
  77. 77.
    Frisch, R. “A Further Note on the Dupuit Taxation Theorem,” Econometrica, 1939, p. 156.Google Scholar
  78. 78.
    Gorman, W.M. “Tariffs, Retaliation and the Elasticity of Demand for Imports,” R.E.S., Vol. XXV (3), p. 133.Google Scholar
  79. 79.
    Gorman, W.M. “The Intransitivity of Certain Criteria used in Welfare Economics,” O.E.P., 1955, N.S., Vol. 7, p. 36.Google Scholar
  80. 80.
    Gorman, W.M. “Are Social Indifference Curves Convex?,” Q.J.E., 1959, p. 485.Google Scholar
  81. 81.
    Graaff, J. de V. “On Optimum Tariff Structures,” R.E.S., Vol. XVII (1), No. 42, p. 47.Google Scholar
  82. 82.
    Graaff, J. de V. “A Note on the Relative Merit of Taxes and Subsidies,” S.A.J.E., 1947, Vol. 15, No. 2, p. 149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. 83.
    Graaff, J. de V. “Towards an Austerity Theory of Value,” S.A.J.E., 1948, Vol. 16, p. 35.Google Scholar
  84. 84.
    Graaff, J. de V. Theoretical Welfare Economics (Cambridge U.P., 1957).Google Scholar
  85. 85.
    Haberler, G. “Some Problems in the Pure Theory of International Trade,” E.J., 1950, p. 223.Google Scholar
  86. 86.
    Haberler, G. “Welfare and Freer Trade,” E.J., 1951, p. 777.Google Scholar
  87. 87.
    Hare, A.E.C. “The Theory of Effort and Welfare Economics,” Economica, 1951, p. 69.Google Scholar
  88. 88.
    Haroldson, W.C. “A Note on Welfare Economics and Rationing,” Q.J.E., 1943–44, p. 146.Google Scholar
  89. 89.
    Harsanyi, J.C. “Welfare Economics of Varying Tastes,” R.E.S., Vol. XXI (3), No. 56, p. 204.Google Scholar
  90. 90.
    Harsanyi, J.C. “Cardinal Utility in Welfare Economics and in the Theory of Risk-taking,” J.P.E., 1953, Vol. LXI, No. 5, p. 434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. 91.
    Harsanyi, J.C. “Cardinal Welfare, Individualistic Ethics and Comparisons of Utility,” J.P.E., 1955, Vol. LXII, p. 309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. 92.
    Henderson, J.M., and Quandt, R.E. Microeconomic Theory—A Mathematical Approach (New York, 1958).Google Scholar
  93. 93.
    Henderson, A. “Consumers’ Surplus and the Compensating Variation,” R.E.S., Vol. VIII, No. 2, p. 117.Google Scholar
  94. 94.
    Henderson, A. “The Case for Indirect Taxation,” E.J., 1948, p. 538.Google Scholar
  95. 95.
    Henderson, A. “Discussion of Social Choice Functions,” Econometrica, 1953 [Abstracts], p. 481.Google Scholar
  96. 96.
    Hicks, J.R. “The Foundations of Welfare Economics,” E.J., 1939, p. 696. 97. Hicks, J.R. “The Valuation of the Social Income,” Economica, 1940, p. 105.Google Scholar
  97. 98.
    Hicks, J.R. “The Valuation of the Social Income. A Comment on Pro-fessor Kuznets’ Reflections,” Economica, 1948, p. 163.Google Scholar
  98. 99.
    Hicks, J.R. A Revision of Demand Theory (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1956).Google Scholar
  99. 100.
    Hicks, J.R. “The Rehabilitation of Consumers’ Surplus,” R.E.S., Vol. VIII, No. 2, p. 108.Google Scholar
  100. 101.
    Hicks, J.R. “The Generalized Theory of Consumers’ Surplus,” R.E.S., Vol. XIII (2), No. 34, p. 68.Google Scholar
  101. 102.
    Hicks, J.R. “The Four Consumers’ Surpluses,” R.E.S., Vol. XI, No. 1, p. 31.Google Scholar
  102. 103.
    Hicks, J.R. “Consumers’ Surplus and Index Numbers,” R.E.S., Vol. IX, No. 2, p. 126.Google Scholar
  103. 104.
    Hicks, J.R. Value and Capital, an Enquiry into some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1939).Google Scholar
  104. 105.
    Hicks, J.R. “The Measurement of Real Income,” O.E.P., 1959, Vol. 10, No. 2, p. 125.Google Scholar
  105. 106.
    Hildreth, C. “Alternative Conditions for Social Orderings,” Econometrica, 1953, p. 81.Google Scholar
  106. 107.
    Hotelling, H. “The Relation of Prices to Marginal Costs in an Optimum System,” Econometrica, 1939, p. 151.Google Scholar
  107. 108.
    Hotelling, H. “A Final Note,” Econometrica, 1939, p. 158.Google Scholar
  108. 109.
    Houghton, R. “Consumer’s Surplus and Discriminating Monopoly,” R.E.S., 1958, Vol. XXVI (1), No. 69, p. 72.Google Scholar
  109. 110.
    Hunter, A. “The Monopolies Commission and Economic Welfare,” Manchester School, 1955, January, p. 22.Google Scholar
  110. 111.
    Hunter, A. “Product Differentiation and Welfare Economics,” Q.J.E., 1955, p. 533.Google Scholar
  111. 112.
    Hurwicz, L. “Decentralized Resource Allocation,“Econometrica, 1955 [Abstracts], p. 342.Google Scholar
  112. 113.
    Inada, K. “Alternative Incompatible Conditions for a Social Welfare Function,” Econometrica, 1955, p. 396.Google Scholar
  113. 114.
    James, S.F., and Beckerman, W. “Interdependence of Consumers Preferences in the Theory of Income Distribution,” E.J., 1953, p. 70.Google Scholar
  114. 115.
    Johnson, H.G. “Optimum Welfare and the Maximum Revenue Tariffs,” R.E.S., Vol. XIX (1), No. 48, p. 28.Google Scholar
  115. 116.
    Johnson, H.G. “Optimum Tariffs and Retaliation,” R.E.S., Vol. XXI (2), No. 55, p. 142.Google Scholar
  116. 117.
    Johnson, H.G. Review Article of J.E. Meade, The Theory of International Economic Policy, Vol. I, The Balance of Payments, E.J., 1951, p. 812.Google Scholar
  117. 118.
    Joseph, M.F.W. “The Excess Burden of Indirect Taxation,” R.E.S., Vol. VI, No. 3, p. 226.Google Scholar
  118. 119.
    Kahn, R.F. “Tariffs and Terms of Trade,” R.E.S., Vol. XV (1), No. 37, p. 14.Google Scholar
  119. 120.
    Kaldor, N. “Income Burden of Capital Taxes,” R.E.S., Vol. IX, No. 2, p. 138.Google Scholar
  120. 121.
    Kaldor, N. “Community Indifference, a Comment,” R.E.S., Vol. XIV (1), No. 35, p. 44.Google Scholar
  121. 122.
    Kaldor, N. “A Note on Tariffs and the Terms of Trade,” Economica, 1940, p. 377.Google Scholar
  122. 123.
    Kaldor, N. “Welfare Propositions in Economics,” E.J., 1939, p. 549.Google Scholar
  123. 124.
    Kaldor, N. “Risk Bearing and Income Taxation,” R.E.S., Vol. XXV (3), No. 68, p. 206.Google Scholar
  124. 125.
    Kemp, M.G. “Arrow’s General Possibility Theorem,” R.E.S., Vol. XXI (3), No. 56, p. 240.Google Scholar
  125. 126.
    Kemp, M.G. “Welfare Economics: A Stocktaking,” Economic Record, 1954, p. 245.Google Scholar
  126. 127.
    Kemp, M.C. “The Efficiency of Competition as an Allocator of Resources,” C.J.E. &c Pol. Science, 1955, Vol. XXI.I. External Economies of Production, p. 30. II. External Economies of Consumption, p. 217.Google Scholar
  127. 128.
    Kemp, M.C. “Technological Change, the Terms of Trade and Welfare,” E.J., 1955, p. 457.Google Scholar
  128. 129.
    Kemp, M.C., and Asimakopulos, A. “A Note on Social Welfare Functions &c Cardinal Utility,” C.J.E. &c Pol. Science, 1952, Vol. XVIII, p. 195.Google Scholar
  129. 130.
    Kenan, P.B., and Fisher, F.M. “Income Distribution, Value Judgments and Welfare: A Correction,” Q.J.E., 1957, p. 322.Google Scholar
  130. 131.
    Kenan, P.B. “On the Geometry of Welfare Economics,” Q.J.E., 1957, p. 426.Google Scholar
  131. 132.
    Kendrick, M.S. “Ability-to-Pay Theory of Taxation,” A.E.R., 1939, p. 92.Google Scholar
  132. 133.
    Kennedy, C.M. “The Economic Welfare Function and Dr. Little’s Criterion,” R.E.S., Vol. XX (2), No. 52, p. 137.Google Scholar
  133. 134.
    Kennedy, C.M. “An Alternative Proof of a Theorem in Welfare Economics,” O.E.P., N.S., 1954, Vol. 6, No. 1, p. 98.Google Scholar
  134. 135.
    Klawe, K.W. Review of A.L. Macfie, Economic Efficiency and Social Welfare, C.J.E. & Pol. Science, 1946, Vol. XII, p. 105.Google Scholar
  135. 136.
    Konüs, A.A. “The Problem of the True Index of the Cost of Living,” Econometrica, 1939, p. 10.Google Scholar
  136. 137.
    Koo, A.Y.C. “Welfare and Direct Taxation,” C.J.E. &c Pol. Science, 1955, Vol. XXI, p. 43.Google Scholar
  137. 138.
    Kozlik, A. “Conditions for Demand Curves whose Curves of Total Revenue, Consumers’ Surplus, Total Benefit and Compromise Benefit are Convex,” Econometrica, 1940, p. 263.Google Scholar
  138. 139.
    Kozlik, A. “Note on Consumer’s Surplus,” J.P.E., 1941, No. 5, p. 754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  139. 140.
    Kuznets, S. “On the Valuation of Social Income. Reflections on Professor Hicks’ Article,” Economica, 1948, Part I, p. 1; Part II, p. 116.Google Scholar
  140. 141.
    Lancaster, K., and Lipsey, R.G. “The General Theory of Second Best,” R.E.S., Vol. XXIV (1), No. 63, p. 11.Google Scholar
  141. 142.
    Lancaster, K. “Welfare Propositions in Terms of Consistency and Expanded Choice,” E.J., 1958, p. 464.Google Scholar
  142. 143.
    Lancaster, K., and Lipsey, R.G. “McManus on Second Best,” R.E.S., 1959, Vol. XXVI (3), No. 71, p. 225.Google Scholar
  143. 144.
    Lange, O. “The Foundations of Welfare Economics,” Econometrica, 1942, p. 215.Google Scholar
  144. 145.
    Lange, O. The Practice of Economic Planning and the Optimal Allocation of Resources. Supplement to Econometrica, Vol. 17, 1949, p. 166.Google Scholar
  145. 146.
    Lazere, M. “Welfare Economics, A Misnomer” [A Communication], A.E.R., 1940, p. 346.Google Scholar
  146. 147.
    Lerner, A.P. “Theory and Practice in Socialist Economies,” R.E.S., Vol. VI, No. 1, p. 71.Google Scholar
  147. 148.
    Lerner, A.P. The Economics of Control (New York: The Macmillan Co., 1946).Google Scholar
  148. 149.
    Lerner, A.P. “Discussions of Social Choice Functions,” Econometrica, 1953 [Abstracts], p. 482.Google Scholar
  149. 150.
    Levin, H.J. “Standards of Welfare in Economic Thought,” Q.J.E., 1956, p. 117.Google Scholar
  150. 151.
    Lewis, W.A. “The Two-Part Tariff,” Economica, 1941, p. 249.Google Scholar
  151. 152.
    Lewis, W.A. “The Two-Part Tariff (A Reply to Mr. Rowson’s Notes),” Economics 1941, p. 399.Google Scholar
  152. 153.
    Lipsey, R.G. “The Theory of Customs Unions, Trade Diversion and Welfare,” Economica, 1957, p. 40.Google Scholar
  153. 154.
    Little, I.M.D. “The Foundations of Welfare Economics,” O.E.P., N.S., Vol. I, No. 2, 1949, p. 227.Google Scholar
  154. 155.
    Little, I.M.D. “Direct versus Indirect Taxes,” E.J., 1951, p. 577.Google Scholar
  155. 156.
    Little, I.M.D. “The Valuation of the Social Income,” Economica, 1949, p. 11.Google Scholar
  156. 157.
    Little, I.M.D. “Welfare and Tariffs,” R.E.S., Vol. XVI (2), No. 40, p. 65.Google Scholar
  157. 158.
    Little, I.M.D. Review of T. Scitovsky, Welfare and Competition, Econometrica, 1952, p. 703.Google Scholar
  158. 159.
    Little, I.M.D. “A Note on the Interpretation of Index Numbers,” Economica, 1949, p. 369.Google Scholar
  159. 160.
    Little, I.M.D. A Critique of Welfare Economics, 1st ed. (Oxford U.P., 1950).Google Scholar
  160. 161.
    Little, I.M.D. A Critique of Welfare Economics, 2nd ed. (Oxford U.P., 1957).Google Scholar
  161. 162.
    Little, I.M.D. “Social Choice and Individual Values,” J.P.E., 1952, Vol. LX, No. 5, p. 422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  162. 163.
    McGarvey, D.C. “A Theorem in the Construction of Voting Paradoxes,” Econometrica, 1953, p. 608.Google Scholar
  163. 164.
    McKenzie, L.W. “Ideal Output and the Interdependence of Firms,” E.J., 1951, p. 785.Google Scholar
  164. 165.
    McManus, M. “Comments on the General Theory of Second Best,” R.E.S., 1959, Vol. XXVI (3), No. 71, p. 209.Google Scholar
  165. 166.
    Majumdar, T. “Armstrong and the Utility Measurement Controversy,” O.E.P., 1957, Vol. 9, No. 1, p. 30.Google Scholar
  166. 167.
    Malinvaud, E. “Capital Accumulation and Efficient Allocation of Resources,” Econometrica, 1953, p. 233.Google Scholar
  167. 168.
    Manne, A.S. “Multiple Purposes Public Enterprises—Criteria for Pricing,” Economica, 1952, p. 322.Google Scholar
  168. 169.
    Margolis, J. “Welfare Criteria, Pricing and Decentralization of a Public Service,” Q.J.E., 1957, p. 448.Google Scholar
  169. 170.
    Marris, R.L. “Professor Hicks’ Index Number Theorem,” R.E.S., Vol. XXV (1), No. 66, p. 25.Google Scholar
  170. 171.
    Meade, J.E. “Mr. Lerner on ‘The Economics of Control’,” E. J., 1945, p. 47.Google Scholar
  171. 172.
    Meade, J.E. The Theory of International Economic Policy; Vol. II, “Trade and Welfare” (London, 1955).Google Scholar
  172. 173.
    Meade, J.E., and Fleming, J.M. “Price and Output Policy of State Enterprise. A Symposium,” E.J., 1944, p. 321.Google Scholar
  173. 174.
    Meade, J.E. The Theory of Customs Unions (Amsterdam, 1955).Google Scholar
  174. 175.
    Melville, L.G. “Economic Welfare,” E.J., 1939, p. 549.Google Scholar
  175. 176.
    Metzler, L.A. “Tariffs, the Terms of Trade, and the Distribution of National Income,” J.P.E., 1949, Vol. LVII, No. 1, p. 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  176. 177.
    Mishan, E.J. “The Principle of Compensation Reconsidered,” J.P.E., 1952, Vol. LX, No. 4, p. 312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  177. 178.
    Mishan, E.J. “An Investigation into some Alleged Contradictions in Welfare Economics,” E.J., 1957, p. 445.Google Scholar
  178. 179.
    Mishan, E.J. “Realism and Relevance in the Theory of Consumer’s Surplus,” R.E.S., Vol. XV, (1), No. 37, p. 27.Google Scholar
  179. 180.
    Mishan, E.J. “A Reappraisal of the Principles of Resource Allocation,” Economica, 1957, p. 324.Google Scholar
  180. 181.
    Mishan, E.J. “Arrow and the ‘New Welfare’ Economics, a Restatement,” E.J., 1958, p. 595.Google Scholar
  181. 182.
    Mishan, E.J. “Rent as a Measure of Welfare Change,” A.E.R., 1959, Vol. XLIX, No. 3, p. 386.Google Scholar
  182. 183.
    Mishan, E.J. “Mr. Lancaster’s Welfare Definitions. A Comment,” E. J., 1959, p. 395.Google Scholar
  183. 184.
    Moore, D.A., and Schwartz, E. “Distorting Effects of Direct Taxation: A Re-evaluation,” A.E.R., 1951, p. 139.Google Scholar
  184. 185.
    Mulcahy (S J.), R.E. “The Welfare Economics of Heinrich Pesch,” Q.J.E., 1949, p. 342.Google Scholar
  185. 186.
    Musgrave, R.A. “Proportional Income Taxation and Risk-Taking,” Q.J.E., 1943–44, p. 388.Google Scholar
  186. 187.
    Myint, H. “The Classical View of the Economic Problem,” Economica 1946, p. 119.Google Scholar
  187. 188.
    Myint, H. “The Welfare Significance of Productive Labour,” R.E.S., Vol. XI, No. 1, p. 20.Google Scholar
  188. 189.
    Myint, H. Theories of Welfare Economics (London: Longmans, 1948).Google Scholar
  189. 190.
    Myrdal, G. The Political Element in the Development of Economic Theory (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1953).Google Scholar
  190. 191.
    Newman, P. “Mr. Lancaster on Welfare and Choice,” E.J., 1959, p. 588.Google Scholar
  191. 192.
    Nordin, J.A. “The Marginal Cost Controversy: A Reply,” Economica, 1947, p. 134.Google Scholar
  192. 193.
    Norris, H. “State Enterprise, Price and Output Policy and the Problem of Cost Imputation,” Economica, 1947, p. 54.Google Scholar
  193. 194.
    Oort, C.J. Decreasing Costs as a Problem of Welfare Economics (Amsterdam: 1958).Google Scholar
  194. 195.
    Phipps, C.G. “Friedman’s ‘Welfare’ Effects,” J.P.E., 1952, Vol. LX, No. 4, p. 332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  195. 196.
    Pigou, A.C. “Comparisons of Real Income,” Economica, 1943, p. 93.Google Scholar
  196. 197.
    Pigou, A.C. “Real Income and Economic Welfare,” O.E.P., 1951, N.S., Vol. 3, No. 1, p. 16.Google Scholar
  197. 198.
    Pigou, A.C. “Some Aspects of Welfare Economics,” A.E.R., 1951, p. 287.Google Scholar
  198. 199.
    Polak, J.J. “‘Optimum Tariff’ and the Cost of Exports,” R.E.S., Vol. XIX (1), No. 48, p. 36.Google Scholar
  199. 200.
    Pole, D. “Pareto on the Compensating Principle,” E.J., 1955, p. 156.Google Scholar
  200. 201.
    Poole, K.E., “Spending Tax, Problems of Administration and Equity,” A.E.R., 1943, p. 63.Google Scholar
  201. 202.
    Radomysler, A. “Welfare Economics and Economic Policy,” Economica, 1946, p. 190.Google Scholar
  202. 203.
    Ramaswami, V.K. “Trade Imbalance, Gains from Trade and National Income Change,” E.J., 1955, p. 450.Google Scholar
  203. 204.
    Reder, M.W. “Welfare Economics and Rationing,” Q.J.E., 1942–43, p. 153.Google Scholar
  204. 205.
    Reder, M.W. “Theories of Welfare Economics,” J.P.E., 1950, Vol. LVIII, No. 2, p. 158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  205. 206.
    Reder, M.W. “Welfare Economics” in Survey of Contemporary Economics, ed. B.F., Haley, Vol. II (A.E.A., 1952).Google Scholar
  206. 207.
    Reder, M.W. Studies in the Theory of Welfare Economics (Oxford U.P., 1947).Google Scholar
  207. 208.
    Robbins, L.C. The Theory of Economic Policy in English Classical Political Economy (London: Macmillan, 1952).Google Scholar
  208. 209.
    Robertson, Sir Dennis. “Utility and All What? Part III,” E.J., 1954, p. 675.Google Scholar
  209. 210.
    Robertson, Sir Dennis. “Utility, A Rejoinder,” E.J., 1955, p. 410.Google Scholar
  210. 211.
    Robinson, H.W. “Consumer’s Surplus and Taxation ex ante or ex post?,” S.A.J.E., 1939, Vol. 7, p. 270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  211. 212.
    Rothenberg, J. “Marginal Preferences and the Theory of Welfare,” O.E.P., 1953, N.S., Vol. 5, No. 3, p. 248.Google Scholar
  212. 213.
    Rothenberg, J. “Conditions for a Social Welfare Function,” J.P.E., 1953, Vol. LXI, No. 5, p. 389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  213. 214.
    Rothenberg, J. “Welfare Comparisons and Changes in Taste,” A.E.R., 1953, Communications, p. 885.Google Scholar
  214. 215.
    Rothenberg, J. “Reconsideration of a Group Welfare Index. A Rejoinder on Marginal Preference,” O.E.P., 1954, N.S., Vol. 6, No. 2, p. 164.Google Scholar
  215. 216.
    Rothschild, K.W. “Monopsony, Buying Costs and Welfare Expenditure,” R.E.S., Vol. X, No. 1, p. 62.Google Scholar
  216. 217.
    Ruggles, N. “The Welfare Basis of the Marginal Cost Pricing Principle,” R.E.S., Vol. XVII (1), No. 42, p. 29.Google Scholar
  217. 218.
    Ruggles, N. “Recent Developments in the Theory of Marginal Cost Pricing,” R.E.S., Vol. XVII (2), No. 43, p. 107.Google Scholar
  218. 219.
    Ruggles, N. Review of B.P. Beckwith, Marginal Cost Price Output Control, Econometrica, 1956, p. 501.Google Scholar
  219. 220.
    Samuelson, P.A. “Further Commentary on Welfare Economics, A Communication,” A.E.R., 1943, p. 604.Google Scholar
  220. 221.
    Samuelson, P.A. “Evaluation of Real National Income,” O.E.P., 1950, N.S., Vol. 2, No. 1, p. 1.Google Scholar
  221. 222.
    Samuelson, P.A. Foundations of Economic Analysis, Chapter VIII (Cambridge: Harvard U.P., 1955).Google Scholar
  222. 223.
    Samuelson, P.A. “Social Indifference Curves,” Q.J.E., 1956, p. 1.Google Scholar
  223. 224.
    Sandee, J., and Van Eijk, C.J. “Quantitative Determination of an Optimum Economic Policy,” Econometrica, 1959, p. 1.Google Scholar
  224. 225.
    Schoeffler, S. “Note on Modern Welfare Economics,” A.E.R., 1952, Communications, p. 880.Google Scholar
  225. 226.
    Schultz, H. “A Misunderstanding in Index-number Theory: The True Konus Conidition on Cost of Living Index Numbers and its Limitations,” Econometrica, 1939, p. 1.Google Scholar
  226. 227.
    Scitovsky, T. “A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics,” R.E.S., Vol. IX, No. 1, p. 77.Google Scholar
  227. 228.
    Scitovsky, T. “Reconsideration of the Theory of Tariffs,” R.E.S., Vol. IX, No. 2, p. 89.Google Scholar
  228. 229.
    Scitovsky, T. “The State of Welfare Economics,” A.E.R., 1951, p. 303.Google Scholar
  229. 230.
    Scitovsky, T. Welfare and Competition, the Economics of a Fully Employed Economy (London: Allen & Unwin, 1952).Google Scholar
  230. 231.
    Staehle, H. “Elasticity of Demand and Social Welfare,” Q.J.E., 1939–40, p. 217.Google Scholar
  231. 232.
    Stafford, J. “The Optimum Utilization of National Resources,” Econometrica, Supplement to Vol. 17, 1949, p. 157.Google Scholar
  232. 233.
    Stigler, G.J. “The New Welfare Economics, A Communication,” A.E.R., 1943, p. 359.Google Scholar
  233. 234.
    Strotz, R.H. “How Income ought to be Distributed: A Paradox in Distributive Ethics,” J.P.E., 1958, Vol. LXVI, No. 3, p. 189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  234. 235.
    Theil, H. “Econometric Models and Welfare Maximisation,” Econometrica, 1954 [Abstracts], p. 121.Google Scholar
  235. 236.
    Thirlby, G.F. “The Marginal Cost Controversy,” Economica, 1947.Google Scholar
  236. 237.
    Threlfell, R.L. “The Relative Merits of Taxes and Subsidies,” S.A.J.E., 1947, Vol. 15, No. 2, p. 149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  237. 238.
    Timlin, M.F. Review of A.P. Lerner, The Economics of Control, C.J.E. &c Pol Science, Vol. XI, 1945, p. 285.Google Scholar
  238. 239.
    Timlin, M.F. Review Article on H. Myint, Theories of Welfare Economics, C.J.E. & Pol. Science, 1949, Vol. XV, p. 551.Google Scholar
  239. 240.
    Tinbergen, J. “The Influence of Productivity on Economic Welfare,” E.J., 1952, p. 68.Google Scholar
  240. 241.
    Tintner, G. “A Note on Welfare Economics,” Econometric, 1946, p. 69.Google Scholar
  241. 242.
    Tyszynski, H. “Economic Theory as a Guide to Policy: Some Suggestions for Reappraisal,” E.J., 1955, p. 195.Google Scholar
  242. 243.
    Vickrey, W. “Some Objections to Marginal Cost Pricing,” J.P.E., 1948, Vol. LVI, No. 3, p. 218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  243. 244.
    Viner, J. The Customs Union Issue (New York, 1950).Google Scholar
  244. 245.
    Wald, H.P. “The Classical Indictment of Indirect Taxation,” Q.J.E., 1945, Vol. LIX, p. 587.Google Scholar
  245. 246.
    Weldon, J.C. “On the Problem of Social Welfare Functions,” C.J.E. &c Pol. Science, 1952, Vol. XVIII, p. 452.Google Scholar
  246. 247.
    Whittaker, E. “Wealth and Welfare, A Communication,” A.E.R., 1940, p. 580.Google Scholar
  247. 248.
    Wilson, T. “The Inadequacy of the Theory of the Firm as a Branch of Welfare Economics,” O.E.P., 1952, Vol. 4, No. 1, p. 18.Google Scholar
  248. 249.
    Wiseman, J. “The Theory of Public Utility Price—An Empty Box,” O.E.P., 1957, Vol. 9, No. 1, p. 56.Google Scholar
  249. 250.
    Wiseman, J. “The Theory of Public Utility Price: A Further Note,” O.E.P., 1959, Vol. 11, No. 1, P. 88.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Royal Economic Society and the American Economic Association 1965

Authors and Affiliations

  • E. J. Mishan
    • 1
  1. 1.London School of Economics and Political ScienceUK

Personalised recommendations