Part of the Studies in Public Choice book series (SIPC, volume 20)


Roughly a half-century has passed since The Calculus of Consent was first published. Yet the questions raised by Buchanan and Tullock’s pioneering book seem to be more relevant today than they were in 1962. The spread of democracy, advances in technology, and population growth have increased the demand for new constitutions. Since The Calculus of Consent was written, more than half of the 160 countries in the world have thrown out their old constitution and adopted an entirely new one. Some have done so more than once (Goldwin and Kaufman, 1988, p. vii).


Public Choice Social Choice Majority Rule Pareto Optimality Vote Rule 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.


Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.


  1. Aldrich JH (1995) Why Parties? The Origin and Transformation of Political Parties in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  2. Arrow K (1951) Social Choice and Individual Values. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
  3. Austen-Smith D, Banks J (2005) Positive Political Theory II: Strategy and Structure.Google Scholar
  4. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  5. Bailyn B (1993) The Debate on the Constitution. New York: Library of America.Google Scholar
  6. Becker GS (1962) Irrational behavior and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy 70(1):1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Berggren N (1996) Social order through constitutional choice. Public Choice 89:339–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bianco WT, Lynch MS, Miller GJ, Sened I (2008) The constrained instability of majority rule: Experiments on the robustness of the uncovered set. Political Analysis 16:115–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Black D (1948) On the rationale of group decision-making. The Journal of Political Economy 56(1):23–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Brennan G, Hamlin A (2000) Democratic Devices and Desires. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Buchanan J (1962) The relevance of pareto optimality. Journal of Conflict Resolution 6(4):341–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Buchanan JM (1967) Public Finance in Democratic Process. Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
  13. Buchanan JM, Tullock G (1962) The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  14. Caplin A, Nalebuff B (1988) On 64%-majority rule. Econometrica 56(4):787–814.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Chamberlin JR, Cohen MD (1978) Toward applicable social choice theory: A comparison of social choice functions under spatial model assumptions. American Political Science Review 72(4):1341–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Clinton J, Jackman S, Rivers D (2004) The statistical analysis of roll call data. American Political Science Review 98(02):355–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Clinton JD, Meirowitz A (2004) Testing explanations of strategic voting in legislatures: A reexamination of the compromise of 1790. American Journal of Political Science 48(4):675–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Colomer JM (2001) Political Institutions: Democracy and Social Choice. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  19. Compte O, Jehiel P (2004) Bargaining over randomly generated offers: A new perspective on multi-party bargaining, c.E.R.A.S.-E.N.P.C., C.N.R.S., France.Google Scholar
  20. Cornes R, Sandler T (1996) The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods, 2nd ed. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  21. Coughlin PJ (1992) Probabilistic Voting Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Cox GW (1987) Electoral equilibrium under alternative voting institutions. American Journal of Political Science 31(1):82–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Crain WM, Tollison RD (1977) Legislative size and voting rules. Journal of Legal Studies 6(1):235–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Denzau A, RikerW, Shepsle K (1985) Farquharson and fenno: Sophisticated voting and home style. American Political Science Review 79(4):1117–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Diermeier D, Myerson RB (1999) Bicameralism and its consequences for the internal organization of legislatures. American Economic Review 89(5):1182–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Dietrich F, List C (2007) Arrows theorem in judgment aggregation. Social Choice and Welfare 29(1):19–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Dougherty KL, Edward J (2004) The pareto efficiency and expected costs of kmajority rules. Politics Philosophy and Economics 3(2):161–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Dougherty KL, Edward J (2005) A nonequilibrium analysis of unanimity rule, majority rule, and pareto. Economic Inquiry 43(4):855–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Dougherty KL, Edward J (2009) Odd or even: Assembly size and majority rule. Journal of Politics 71(02):733–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Dougherty KL, Edward J (2010a) The properties of simple vs. absolute majority rule: Cases where absences and abstentions are important. Journal of Theoretical Politics 22(1):85–122.Google Scholar
  31. Dougherty KL, Edward J (2010b) Voting for a Pareto optimality: a multidimensional analysis. Public Choice, (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  32. Dougherty KL, Heckelman J (2006) A pivotal voter from a pivotal state: Roger Sherman at the Constitutional Convention. American Political Science Review 100(2):297–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Dougherty KL, Pitts B, Moeller J, Ragan R (2010) An experimental study of the efficiency of unanimity rule and majority rule. Public Choice, (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  34. Downs A (1957) An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
  35. Duggan J (2006) Endogenous voting agendas. Social Choice and Welfare 27:495–530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Enelow JM, Hinich MJ (1990) Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  37. Farrand M (ed) (1966) The Records of the Federal Convention of 1787. New Haven: Yale University Press., 4 vols.Google Scholar
  38. Farrell DM (2001) Electoral Systems: A Comparative Introduction. New York: Palgrave.Google Scholar
  39. Feld SL, Grofman B, Miller N (1988) Centripetal forces in spatial voting: On the size of the yolk. Public Choice 59(1):37–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Felsenthal DS, Maoz Z, Rapoport A (1993) An empirical evaluation of six voting procedures: Do they really make any difference? British Journal of Political Science 23(01):1–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Fiorina MP, Plott CR (1978) Committee decisions under majority rule: An experimental study. American Political Science Review 72(2):575–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Fishburn PC (1973) The Theory of Social Choice. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  43. Fishburn PC (1987) Interprofile Conditions and Impossibility. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  44. Freixas J, Zwicker WS (2009) Anonymous yes–no voting with abstention and multiple levels of approval. Games and Economic Behavior 67(2):428–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Friedrich CJ (1963) Man and His Government: An Empirical Theory of Politics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  46. Gehrlein WV (2002a) Condorcet’s paradox and the likelihood of its occurrence: Different perspectives on balanced preferences. Theory and Decision 52:171–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Gehrlein WV (2002b) Obtaining representations for probabilities of voting outcomes with effectively unlimited precision integer arithmetic. Social Choice and Welfare 19(3):503–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. GehrleinWV, Lepelley D (2010) Voting Paradoxes and Group Coherence: The Condorcet Efficiency of Voting Rules. New York: Springer Publishing.Google Scholar
  49. Gode DK, Sunder S (1993) Allocative efficiency of markets with zero-intelligence traders: Market as a partial substitute for individual rationality. Journal of Political Economy 101(1):119–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Goldwin RA, Kaufman A (1988) Constitution Makers on Constitution Making: The Experience of Eight Nations. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.Google Scholar
  51. Grafstein R (1990) Missing the Archimedean point: Liberalism’s institutional presuppositions.Google Scholar
  52. American Political Science Review 84(1):177–93.Google Scholar
  53. Greif A, Laitin DD (2004) A theory of endogenous institutional change. American Political Science Review 98(4):633–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Groseclose T, Milyo J (2010) Sincere versus sophisticated voting in Congress: Theory and evidence. Journal of Politics 71(1):60–73.Google Scholar
  55. Guttman JM (1998) Unanimity and majority rule: The calculus of consent reconsidered.Google Scholar
  56. European Journal of Political Economy 14(2):189–207.Google Scholar
  57. Hammond TH, Miller GJ (1987) The core of the constitution. American Political Science Review 81(4):1155–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Hardin R (1988) Constitutional political economy: Agreement on rules. British Journal of Political Science 18(04):513–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Hardin R (1999) Liberalism, Constitutionalism, and Democracy. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Head JG (1974) Public Goods and Public Welfare. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
  61. Heckelman JC (2003) Probabilistic Borda rule voting. Social Choice and Welfare 21(3):455–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Heckelman JC, Dougherty KL (2010a) Majority rule versus supermajority rules: Their effects on narrow and broad taxes. Public Finance Review 38(6):738–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Heckelman JC, Dougherty KL (2010b) What influenced delegate voting at the constitutional convention, mimeo, University of Georgia, Athens, GA.Google Scholar
  64. Hinich M, Munger MC (1997) Analytical Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  65. Hobbes T ([1651] 1962) Leviathan. New York: Collier Macmillan.Google Scholar
  66. Intriligator MD (1973) A probabilistic model of social choice. Review of Economic Studies 40(4):553–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Janis IL (1972) Groupthink: psychological studies of policy decisions and fiascoes. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
  68. Jillson C (1978) Voting bloc analysis in the Constitutional Convention: Implications for an interpretation of the Connecticut compromise. Western Political Quarterly 31(4):535–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Jillson C (1988) Constitution Making: Conflict and Consensus in the Federal Convention of 1787. New York: Agathon Press.Google Scholar
  70. Koford KJ (1982) Centralized vote-trading. Public Choice 39(2):245–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Krehbiel K (1998) Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.S. Lawmaking. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  72. Laffont JJ (2000) Incentives and Political Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  73. Laruelle A, Valenciano F (2010) Majorities with a quorum. Journal of Theoretical Politics, (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  74. Lepelley D (1993) On the probability of electing the Condorcet loser. Mathematical Social Sciences 25(2):105–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Lepelley D, Pierron P, Valognes F (2000) Scoring rules, Condorcet efficiency, and social homogeneity. Theory and Decision 49(2):175–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Lijphart A (1999) Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  77. Lindahl E ([1919] 1967) Classics in the Theory of Public Finance, New York: St.Google Scholar
  78. Martin’s Press., chap Just Taxation – a Positive Solution, pp 168–76.Google Scholar
  79. Lipset SM (1963) The First New Nation: The United States in Historical and Comparative Perspective. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  80. Locke J ([1690] 1988) Two Treatises of Government. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  81. Lord C (1984) Roll calls of the Continental Congresses and the congresses of the confederation, 1777–1789. ICPSR data set 7537.Google Scholar
  82. Lutz DS (2006) Principles of Constitutional Design. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  83. May KO (1952) A set of independent necessary and sufficient conditions for simple majority decision. Econometrica 20:680–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. McCarty N, Poole KT, Rosenthal H (2005) Polarized America: The Dance of Ideology and Unequal Riches. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  85. McGann AJ (2006) The Logic of Democracy: Reconciling Equality, Deliberation, and Minority Protection. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  86. McGuire RA (2003) To Form a More Perfect Union: A New Economic Interpretation of the United States Constitution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  87. McKelvey RD (1976) Intransitivities in mulitdimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory 12:472–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. McKelvey RD (1986) Covering, dominance, and institution-free properties of social choice. American Journal of Political Science 30(2):283–314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. McKelvey RD, Ordeshook PC (1984) An experimental study of the effects of procedural rules on committee behavior. Journal of Politics 46(1):182–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Merrill S (1984) A comparison of efficiency of multicandidate electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science 28(1):23–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Miller GJ, Hammond TH (1990) Committees and the core of the constitution. Public Choice 66(3):201–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Mueller D (1996) Constitutional Democracy. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  93. Mueller D (2001) The importance of uncertainty in a two-stage theory of constitutions. Public Choice 108(3):223–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. Mueller D (2003) Public Choice III. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  95. Niemi RG, Weisberg HF (1968) A mathematical solution for the probability of the paradox of voting. Behavioral Science 13:317–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. Niou EM, Ordeshook PC (1985) Universalism in Congress. American Journal of Political Science 29(2):246–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  97. North DC, Weingast BR (1989) Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutional governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History 49(4):803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  98. Nozick R (1974) Anarchy, State, and Utopia. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  99. Nurmi H (1987) Comparing Voting Systems. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
  100. Nurmi H (1992) An assessment of voting system simulations. Public Choice 73(4):459–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  101. Nurmi H, Uusi-Heikkila Y (1986) Computer simulations of approval and plurality voting: The frequency of weak Pareto violations and Condorcet loser choices in impartial cultures. European Journal of Political Economy 2(1):47–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  102. Olson M (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  103. Ordeshook P (1986) Game Theory and Political Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  104. Ostrom E (1990) Governing the Commons. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  105. Palfrey TR (1984) Spatial equilibrium with entry. Review of Economic Studies 51(1):139–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  106. Penn EM (2009) A model of farsighted voting. American Journal of Political Science 53(1):36–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  107. Peress M (2009) Estimating proposal and status quo locations using voting and cosponsorship data, mimeo, University of Rochester, Rochester, NY.Google Scholar
  108. Plott CR (1967) A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. American Economic Review 57:787–806.Google Scholar
  109. Poole K, Rosenthal H (1984) The polarization of American politics. Journal of Politics 46(4):1061–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  110. Poole KT, Rosenthal H (1997) Congress: A Poltical-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  111. Pope J, Treier S (2009) Mapping dimensions of the conflict at the federal convention of 1787, mimeo, University of Minnesota, Twin Cities, MN.Google Scholar
  112. Przeworski A (2005) Democracy as an equilibrium. Public Choice 123(3):253–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  113. Rae DW(1969) Decision rules and individual values in constitutional choice. American Political Science Review 63(1):40–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  114. Rae DW (1975) The limits of consensual decision. American Political Science Review 69(4):1270–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  115. Rasch B (1995) Parliamentary Voting Procedures, New York: St. Martin’s Press, pp 488–527.Google Scholar
  116. Rasch BE (2000) Parliamentary floor voting procedures and agenda setting in Europe.Google Scholar
  117. Legislative Studies Quarterly 25(1):3–23.Google Scholar
  118. Regenwetter M, Groffman B, Marley A, Tsetlin I (2006) Behavioral Social Choice: Probabilistic Models, Statistical Inference, and Applications. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  119. Reilly B (2002) Social choice in the South Seas: Electoral innovation and the Borda count in the Pacific Island countries. International Political Science Review 23(4):355–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  120. Riker WH (1962) Review of the calculus of consent by James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock. Midwest Journal of Political Science 6(4):408–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  121. RikerWH(1980) Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions. American Political Science Review 74(2):432–46.Google Scholar
  122. Riker WH (1982) Liberalism against populism. Prospect Heights, IL: Waveland Press.Google Scholar
  123. Riker WH (1992) The justification of bicameralism. International Political Science Review 13(1):101–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  124. Riker WH, Brams SJ (1973) The paradox of vote trading. American Political Science Review 67(4):1235–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  125. Riker WH, Calvert RL, Mueller JE, Wilson RK (1996) The Strategy of Rhetoric: Campaigning for the American Constitution. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  126. Roberts KW (1980) Possibility theorems with interpersonally comparable welfare levels. Review of Economic Studies 47(2):409–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  127. Rogowski R (1974) Rational Legitimacy: A Theory of Political Support. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  128. Rousseau JJ ([1762] 1997) The Social Contract and Other Later Political Writings.Google Scholar
  129. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  130. Rowley CK (2004) The Selected Works of Gordon Tullock. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
  131. Saari DG (1995) Basic Geometry of Voting. New York: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
  132. Saari DG (1999) Explaining all three-alternative voting outcomes. Journal of Economic Theory 87(2):313–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  133. Saari DG (2003) Unsettling aspects of voting theory. Economic Theory 22(3):529–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  134. Saari DG (2008) Disposing Dictators, Demystifying Voting Paradoxes: Social Choice Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  135. Saari DG, Barney S (2003) Consequences of reversing preferences. The Mathematical Intelligencer 25(4):17–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  136. Schofield NJ (1978) Instability of simple dynamic games. Review of Economic Studies 45:575–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  137. Sen AK (1979a) Collective Choice and Social Welfare. New York: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  138. Sen AK (1979b) Utilitarianism and welfarism. Journal of Philosophy 76(9):463–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  139. Shepsle KA (1979) Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science 23(1):27–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  140. Shleifer A, Treisman D (2001) Without a Map: Political Tactics and Economic Reform in Russia. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  141. Spindler ZA (1990) Constitutional design for a rent-seeking society: Voting rule choice. Constitutional Political Economy 1(3):73–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  142. Council of State Governments (2009) The Book of the States. Lexington, KY: The Council of State Governments.Google Scholar
  143. Stewart C (2001) Analyzing Congress. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
  144. Tsebelis G (1990) Nested Games: Rational Choice in Comparative Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  145. Tsebelis G (2002) Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
  146. Tullock G (1998) On Voting: A Public Choice Approach. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  147. Tversky A, Kahneman D (1974) Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases.Google Scholar
  148. Science 185(4157):1124–31.Google Scholar
  149. Van Newenhizen J (1992) The Borda method is most likely to respect the Condorcet principle. Economic Theory 2(1):69–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  150. Voigt S (1997) Positive constitutional economics: A survey. Public Choice 90(1):11–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  151. Voigt S (2011) Positive constitutional economics II: a survey of recent developments.Google Scholar
  152. Public Choice 146(1–2):205–56.Google Scholar
  153. Weimer DL, Vining AR (2005) Policy Analysis: Concepts and Practice, 4th ed.Google Scholar
  154. Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
  155. Wicksell K ([1896] 1967) Classics in the Theory of Public Finance, 3rd ed., New York: McGraw-Hill., chap New Principle of Just Taxation, pp 72–118.Google Scholar
  156. Young HP (1974) An axiomitizatoin of Borda’s rule. Journal of Economic Theory 9(2):43–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2011

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Political ScienceUniversity of GeorgiaAthensUSA
  2. 2.Department of MathematicsFlorida International UniversityMiamiUSA

Personalised recommendations