Skip to main content

The Chinese Imbalance in Capital Flows

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 2077 Accesses

Abstract

China has three major imbalances: a trade surplus, a capital account surplus and a large annual build up, and a very high level of international reserves. Capital flows, especially flows of US government securities, are also important in assessing the bilateral and overall imbalances in transactions. China has a capital account surplus reinforcing its current account surplus and the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves, mainly US dollar denominated assets. This is unusual because a sustainable fixed or floating requires that countries with large current account surpluses run capital account deficits.

The worst consequences of imbalances have been the build-up of large, low-return foreign exchange. These reserves have led to rapid growth in money and credit and, in turn, to a sharp acceleration in inflation, something that China had assiduously avoided since 1994 and that has raised serious doubts about the credibility of the monetary authorities and damaged its inflation-fighting reputation. Moreover, efforts to offset money growth and inflation have deepened existing inefficiencies in the financial system, which China had hoped to begin remedying by its efforts to recapitalize and list its banks’ equities on stock exchanges. China could eliminate these imbalances by policies that would reduce growth. An alternative solution is to lift restrictions on capital outflows, allowing households and business to diversify their wealth holdings and realize higher returns and/or less volatility in their own income and wealth. This would transform future asset growth from massive central bank holdings of US securities to holdings of higher return and lower risk assets abroad. Such a step also would eliminate pressures on the People’s Bank of China (PBOC), allowing for more rapid deregulation of banks, slower money, and credit growth and lower inflation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The current account refers to Balance of Payments accounting where the current account measures the exports (credit, +) and imports (debit, –) of goods, services, income payments for resource services, and unilateral international transfers.

  2. 2.

    See Tatom (2007) for a discussion of some of the arguments over the US–China trade imbalance and the likely lack of justification and the ineffectiveness of bilateral exchange rate or trade policy actions in eliminating a multilateral imbalance. Cheung et al. (2008) provide supporting evidence that the Renminbi is not misaligned so that efforts to force a currency appreciation are doomed to failure, as they did earlier (2007). See also Bailey and Lawrence (2006).

  3. 3.

    In 2007, the US current account deficit with China was US $289.7 billion, 39.2% of the overall US current account deficit. China’s leading trade partner, the United States, accounts for 32.5% of China’s trade in goods and services, while the United States’ top trade partner, Canada, accounts for 16.8% of US trade; China, accounts for 10.3%.

  4. 4.

    Phillips (2008) suggests that the overall US capital inflow is at risk because of concerns over future policy or simply the large indebtedness of the United States to the rest of the world. The diversification, liquidity, return, and safety benefits to foreign investors in the United States are not written in stone, and policy discussions and decisions over the past year raise doubts about the extent of those benefits in the future. The concentration of foreign exchange holding in a single increasingly risky name is more likely to be the tripwire for adverse global capital market developments.

  5. 5.

    Goldstein and Lardy (2008) argue that the Chinese have not appreciated their currency enough since the amount allowed so far has been accompanied by a growing current account surplus and an acceleration on foreign exchange growth.

  6. 6.

    Capital controls typically apply to inflows, but putting restrictions on inflows or outflows reduce incentives for foreigners to invest in a country. Chilean restrictions on capital inflows outflows from 1991-98 were expected to insulate the country from the sudden stops of capital inflows associated with the financial crises in Asia. Instead, the restrictions acted as a disincentive to invest in the country and the undesired fall in the capital account balance was accomplished by a surge in outflows instead of a decline in inflows. See Forbes (2007) for evidence of how these restrictions also raised the cost of capital for smaller traded domestic firms and Gallego et al. (2000) and Cowan and De Gregorio (2005) for overviews and lessons from the Chilean experience.

  7. 7.

    Cappiello and Ferrucci (2008) focus on the importance of opening the capital account and moving toward a flexible exchange rate as sequenced steps to reduce the opportunity cost of a fixed exchange rate system. They do not single out the benefits of lifting capital outflow restrictions, however, which are emphasized here. People’s Bank of China Deputy Governor Xiang (2006) provides an excellent review of China’s financial sector and economic development and outlines the next steps to be taken. He notes the importance of a harmonious relation between economic development and development of the financial sector. He also points to the importance of developing internal financial markets and opening the sector to global competition.

  8. 8.

    Chinese authorities have made recent changes in tax incentives for capital inflows that will reduce such investments, but these changes are strongly in the interest of promoting economic efficiency and equality and may actually boost the attractiveness of investing in China. Earlier, in order to promote direct investment, tax incentives were given that lowered the income tax rate paid by foreign firms. These may have been successful in priming the pump for foreign investment, but they misallocated capital and other resources within the economy. Ending those subsides will improve the integrity of the tax system and of economic policy, even if they have a slight negative effect on capital inflows. Unfortunately, regulators have offset the benefits of these steps by tightening restrictions on majority or even minority ownership of foreign acquisitions in the financial services industry and by regulatory delays in approving such acquisitions. Regulators have also cracked down on capital inflows that have come from inflated invoicing of exports, forcing more rapid and exact documentation to convert dollar receipts into Renminbi. Making foreign investment subject to changing and arbitrary rules, as well as limiting the potential for control of domestic financial firms severely diminishes the attraction of investing in China.

  9. 9.

    See Beim and Calomiris (2001) for an extended discussion of the conditions and effects of repressed financial markets.

  10. 10.

    Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (2008b) provide a detailed review of the literature on the finance-growth linkage and they provide new evidence that government policies have significant effects on the operations of the financial system and on access to financial services by large segments of the population. Their review shows that “The services provided by the financial system exert a first-order impact on long-run economic growth.” (p. 2).

  11. 11.

    Some analysts argue that Asia, or at least China, is the exception to the rule that the quality of financial institutions is a critical determinant of economic growth and development. Maksimovic et al. (2008) find evidence that formal financial institution finance is associated with faster firm growth, but funds raised from alternative channels is not. Moreover, they find that this result is not due to the selection process for firms that have access to formal financial institutions.

  12. 12.

    Porter (1998) emphasized the role of competition in open goods markets for upgrading the competitiveness of domestic enterprise and boosting economic growth. In the case of financial services firms, such improved competitiveness will arise through the import of capital from abroad.

  13. 13.

    Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (2008a) provide evidence that the more developed the financial system is the lower is income inequality and poverty and the greater is access by low income households to financial services.

References

  • Bailey Martin N. and Robert Z. Lawrence, “Can America Still Compete or Does It Need a New Paradigm?” Peter G. Peterson Institute for International Economics Policy Brief, No. 4–9, December 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beim David O. and Charles W. Calomiris, Emerging Financial Markets, New York: McGraw Hill/Irwin, 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cappiello Lorenzo and Gianluigi Ferrucci, “The Sustainability of China’s Exchange Rate Policy and Capital Account Liberalization,” European Central Bank Occasional Paper No. 82, March 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung Yin-Wong, Menzie David Chinn and Eiji Fujii, “Pitfalls in Measuring Exchange Rate Misalignment: The Yuan and Other Currencies,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 14168, July, 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung Yin-Wong, Menzie David Chinn and Eiji Fujii, “The Overvaluation of Renminbi Undervaluation,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 12850, June 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowan, Kevin and Jose De Gregorio, “International Borrowing, Capital Controls and the Exchange Rate: Lessons from Chile,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 11382, May, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demirguc-Kunt Asli and Ross Levine, “Finance and Economic Opportunity,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4468, January 2008a.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demirguc-Kunt Asli and Ross Levine, “Finance, Financial Sector Policies, and Long-Run Growth,” World Bank Policy research Working Paper No. 4469, January 2008b.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forbes Kristin J., “One Cost of the Chilean Capital Controls: Increased Financial Constraints for Smaller traded Firms,” Journal of International Economics 71, April 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallego Franciso A., Leonardo Hernandez, and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, “Capital Controls in Chile: Effective? Efficient?” Econometric Society World Congress 2000 contributed paper No. 0330, 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein Morris and Nicholas Lardy, “China’s Currency Needs to Rise Further,” Financial Times, July 23, 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics, July 2008 and Various Earlier Issues.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maksimovic Vojislav, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, and Meghana Ayyagari, “Formal vs. Informal Finance: Evidence form China,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4465, January 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phillips Michael M., “Capital Flow From Emerging Nations to U.S. Poses Some Risks,” The Wall Street Journal, June 23, 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter Michael E., The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York: Simon and Schuster Adult Publishing Group, June 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rohwer Jim, Asia Rising, London: Nicholas Brealey Publishing, 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith Adam and Andrew Skinner, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Penguin Classics edition, 1982, original 1776.

    Google Scholar 

  • State Administration for Foreign Exchange, “China’s Balance of Payments Maintains a Twin Surplus in 2007,” SAFE News, June 5. 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tatom John A. “The US-China Currency Dispute: Is a Rise in the Yuan Inevitable, Necessary or Desirable?” Global Economy Journal, 17(3), article 2, pp. 1–13, 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xiang Junbo, “Harmonious Financial Development: The Expectations of the World’s Economy and Financial Industry,” Speech at the Opening Ceremony of the Lujiazui Financial Culture Week and Lujiazui International Financial Forum, reprinted by Risk News, December 11, 2006.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John A. Tatom .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tatom, J.A. (2009). The Chinese Imbalance in Capital Flows. In: Barth, J., Tatom, J., Yago, G. (eds) China’s Emerging Financial Markets. The Milken Institute Series on Financial Innovation and Economic Growth, vol 8. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-387-93769-4_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics