Skip to main content

Theory

What Should We Observe if Democratic Governance Weakens Economic Performance?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 659 Accesses

Part of the book series: Studies in Public Choice ((SIPC,volume 14))

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The IDEA conference on “Building Electoral Participation” is illustrative – see http://idea.int/, accessed on 31 July 2003.

  2. 2.

    See, for example, http://www.ifes.org/civil.html, accessed on 4 December 2008.

  3. 3.

    Source H-PolMeth Discussion Network. Available at http://www.h-net.org/. Accessed 6 July 2004 (emphasis added).

  4. 4.

    Arthur Denzau and Michael Munger (1986) developed a related conclusion from a model where competition between lobbying firms creates forces that discourage complete capture.

  5. 5.

    By total surplus, we mean the sum of consumers’ benefit from purchasing a good or service at a price below their willingness to pay and producers’ benefit from selling a good or service above their willingness to supply. Graphically, in Fig. 1.1, total surplus equals the sum of the areas below the demand curve and above a given price (consumer surplus) and above the supply curve and below that price (producer surplus). Note that this measure of economic performance reaches its maximum (the size of the pie is greatest) when competition exhausts all mutually beneficial trades and thus extinguishes the “deadweight loss” triangles C and F.

  6. 6.

    Thomas Lyon (2003) developed a similar insight to evaluate how the migration of regulatory authority from the municipal- to state-level may have strengthened regulatory commitments.

  7. 7.

    See, for example, Joseph Pereira’s (2008a,b) reports on a recent Supreme Court decision(and subsequent political backlash) that minimum-pricing contracts are not per se anticompetitive.

  8. 8.

    This dependence is also evident in Gary Becker’s (1983) model of pressure group competition.

  9. 9.

    Peltzman (1976) argued that the cost of transacting in political markets limits the gains of “dominant groups.” Applied to our current framework, this limit implies that the parameter α will not rest at either of its extreme values (i.e., α ≠ 0 or 1, although Peltzman’s reference to the competitive outcome as a “benchmark” and corresponding reference to equilibrium (regulated) prices and quantities being read off of demand curves imply that he considered α = 0.5 as an effective maximum). Our objective in examining the related problem (1.1) is to facilitate a more general normative investigation of electoral accountability by making transparent the observable implications of changing α.

  10. 10.

    The constraint Q(P) = Qs(P) defines rule (Equation 1.7)’s domain as the interval α ∈ (1/2, 1).

  11. 11.

    Edward Leamer (1985) prominently called attention to this importance.

  12. 12.

    Looking forward to our formal empirical examination, if we define quantity as an option for households to connect to the telecommunications network, then marginal costs plausibly increase with quantity; e.g., the physical distance over which local exchange service producers and subscribers must connect increases with additional subscribers. In this case, the supply curve slopes upward as in our pressure group model. If, instead, quantity refers to exercised options (e.g., calling minutes), then marginal (but not average) costs may be negligible.

  13. 13.

    Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott (1977) developed a seminal model of this type of opportunism.

  14. 14.

    See, for example, Levy and Spiller (1994), Acemoglu et al. (2001), Rodrik et al. (2002), Stasavage (2002), and Falaschetti (2003b).

  15. 15.

    Sidak (2001, p. 747) argued that giving producers (corporations, in particular) a voice in policy deliberations is “significant” since “the repudiation of substantive due process, the decline of the Takings and Contract Clauses since the New Deal, and the simultaneous rise of the administrative state as a regulator of economic activity have made it increasingly difficult for individuals to defend their property against expropriation by the state.”

  16. 16.

    The literature on mechanism design in “multitasking” environments also highlights “the difficulties of contracting in a multidimensional outcome setting” (Hatfield and Miquel 2006).

  17. 17.

    Besley and Coate (2003) developed preliminary evidence to this effect.

  18. 18.

    Jerry Hausman (1997) and Hausman and J. Gregory Sidak (1999) argued for the importance of accounting for such options when regulating the price at which incumbent local exchange companies sell unbundled network elements to competitors.

  19. 19.

    The idea here is that lowering price caps does not change the variance in expected revenues(i.e., price caps do not change uncertainty about the demand curve per se, though they do change where we expect to end up on a given demand curve), but it does reduce the reward for accepting that risk, and thus discourages investment.

References

  • Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, Alberto and Guido Tabellini (2007). Bureaucrats or politicians? Part I: A single policy task. American Economic Review, 97(1), 169–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, Mark and David E. M. Sappington (2006). Regulation, competition, and liberalization. Journal of Economic Literature 44(2), 325–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, Gary S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, Douglas B. and Michael D. Whinston (1986). Menu auctions, resource allocation, and economic influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(1), 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, Timothy (2003). Elected versus appointed regulators. In Charles K. Rowley and Friedrich Schneider (Eds.), Encyclopedia of Public Choice (pp. 198–201). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, Timothy and Robin Burgess (2002). The political economy of government responsiveness: theory and evidence from India. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1415–1453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, Timothy and Stephen Coate (2003). Elected versus appointed regulators: Theory and evidence. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(5), 1176–1206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, Arthur T. and Michael C. Munger (1986). Legislators and interest groups: how unorganized interests get represented. American Political Science Review, 80(1), 89–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobbs, Ian (2004). Intertemporal price cap regulation under uncertainty. Economic Journal, 114(495), 421–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Earle, Robert, Karl Schmedders, and Tymon Tatur (2007). On price caps under uncertainty. Review of Economic Studies, 74(1), 93–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falaschetti, Dino (2003a). Can latent groups influence policy decisions? The case of telecommunications policy. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 19(1), 83–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falaschetti, Dino (2003b). Credible commitments and investment: Does opportunistic ability or incentive matter? Economic Inquiry, 41(4), 660–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleck, Robert K. (1999). The value of the vote: a model and test of the effects of turnout on distributive policy. Economic Inquiry, 37(4), 609–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleck, Robert K. (2001). Inter-party competition, intra-party competition, and distributive policy: a model and test using new deal data. Public Choice, 108(1–2), 77–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garfinkel, Michelle R. and Jaewoo Lee (2000). Political influence and the dynamic consistency of policy. American Economic Review, 90(3), 649–666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, James T. (1993). Politics and social costs: estimating the impact of collective action on hazardous waste facilities. RAND Journal of Economics, 24(1), 101–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatfield, John and Gerard Miquel (2006). Multitask Political Agency. Stanford University Graduate School of Business, Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, Jerry A. (1997). Valuation and the effect of regulation on new services in telecommunications. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, Jerry A. and J. Gregory Sidak (1999). A consumer-welfare approach to the mandatory unbundling of telecommunications networks. Yale Law Journal 190(3), 417–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, Albert O. (1970). Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holburn, Guy L. F. and Pablo T. Spiller (2002). Interest Group Representation in Administrative Institutions: The Impact of Consumer Advocates and Elected Commissioners on Regulatory Policy in the United States. University of California Energy Institute (UCEI), Energy Policy and Economics Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Key, V. O. Jr. (1984 [1949]). Southern Politics in State and Nation – A New Edition. Knoxville, TN: University of Tennessee Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85(3),473–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leamer, Edward (1985). Sensitivity analysis would help. American Economic Review, 75(3), 308–313.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy, Brian and Pablo T. Spiller (1994). The institutional foundations of regulatory commitment: A comparative analysis of telecommunications regulation. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 10(2), 201–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lyon, Thomas P. (2003). Capture or contract? The Early Years of Electric Utility Regulation. Indiana University and Resources for the Future, working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marceau, Nicolas and Michael Smart (2003). Corporate lobbying and commitment failure in capital taxation. American Economic Review, 93(1), 241–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, Douglass C. and Barry Weingast (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, Sam (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pereira, Joseph (2008a). Price-fixing makes a comeback after Supreme Court ruling. Wall Street Journal, August 18, A1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pereira, Joseph (2008b). Minimum-price foes to use eBay in effort. Wall Street Journal, December 5, B7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Power to the people (2004). Wall Street Journal, March 15, A16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi (2002). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. NBER Working Paper 9305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee, Richard (2004). Sunk costs and antitrust barriers to entry. MIT Sloan School of Management, Working Paper 4457–04 (January).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidak, J. Gregory (2001). Mr. Justice Nemo’s social statistics. Texas Law Review, 79, 737–765.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smart, Susan R. (1994). The consequences of appointment methods and party controls for telecommunications pricing. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3(2), 301–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stasavage, David (2002). Private investment and political institutions. Economics and Politics, 14(1), 41–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dino Falaschetti .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Falaschetti, D. (2009). Theory. In: Democratic Governance and Economic Performance. Studies in Public Choice, vol 14. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-387-78707-7_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics