Building on the seminal contributions by Pigou (1920), Coase (1960) and Baumol and Oates (1971), economists have extensively explored the role that economic incentives might play in bringing a more efficient allocation of natural resources. The theory of environmental economics suggests that pricing instruments are an adequate means to internalize external costs. More specifically, there is widespread agreement within the scientific community that from a theoretical point of view pricing instruments are preferable to alternative measures, owing to their efficiency advantages (Frey et al., 1985). However, though economists see pricing instruments as an attractive policy tool, most attempts to introduce economic incentives in environmental policy have failed, and the acceptance of these mechanisms in the political debate is still rather limited (Hahn, 1989; Schneider and Weck-Hannemann, 2005).

There are many possible reasons why incentive instruments as a means to internalize external costs have been rarely applied in the past. It certainly would be too simple just to refer to imperfect information on the part of decision-makers about the advantages of incentive-based instruments. On the contrary, there seem to be good reasons why politicians, voters, bureaucrats, and/or representatives of interest groups are rather reluctant to favor price instruments on a large scale in environmental politics.


Public Choice Environmental Policy Environmental Politics External Cost Environmental Taxis 


Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.


  1. Baumol, W.J. and Oates, W.E. (1971). ‘‘The use of standards and prices for the protection of the environment.’’ Swedish Journal of Economics, 73, 42-54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Becker, G.S. (1983). ‘‘A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence.’’ The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371-400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Bohringer, C. and Lange, A. (2005). ‘‘Economic implications of alternative allocation schemes for emission allowances.’’ Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 107(3), 563-581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bohringer, C. and Vogt, C. (2004). ‘‘The dismantling of a breakthrough: The Kyoto protocol as symbolic policy.’’ European Journal of Political Economy, 20, 597-617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bommer, R. (1998). Economic Integration and the Environment. A Political-Economic Perspective. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
  6. Bovenberg, A.L. and DeMooij, R.A. (1994). ‘‘Environmental levies and distortionary taxation.’’ American Economic Review, 84, 1085-1089.Google Scholar
  7. Brennan, G. and Buchanan, J.M. (1980). The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal Constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  8. Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G. (1975). ‘‘Polluters’ profits and political response: direct controls versus taxes.’’ American Economic Review, 65, 139-147.Google Scholar
  9. Coase, R.H. (1960). ‘‘The problem of social cost.’’ Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1-44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Coate, S. and Morris, S. (1995). ‘‘On the form of transfers in special interests.’’ Journal of Political Economy, 103(6), 1210-1235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Congleton, R.D. (ed.) (1996). The Political Economy of Environmental Protection: Analysis and Evidence. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  12. Congleton, R.D. (2006). ‘‘The Story of Katrina: New Orleans and the political economy of catastrophe.’’ Public Choice, 127, 5-30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Dewees, D.N. (1983). ‘‘Instrument choice in environmental policy.’’ Economic Inquiry, 21, 53-71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Dijkstra, B.R. (1999). The Political Economy of Environmental Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
  15. Downing, P.B. (1991). ‘‘A political economy model of implementing pollution laws.’’ Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 8, 255-271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  17. Ekins, P. and Speck, S. (1999). ‘‘Competitiveness and exemptions from environmental taxes in Europe.’’ Environmental and Resource Economics, 13, 369-396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Frey, B.S. (1997). Not Just for the Money. An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
  19. Frey, B.S. (2003). ‘‘Why are efficient transport policy instruments so seldom used?,’’ in J. Schade and B. Schlag (eds.) Acceptability of Transport Pricing Strategies. Oxford: Elsevier, 63-75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Frey, B.S. and Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1996). ‘‘Fair siting procedures: An empirical analysis of their importance and characteristics.’’ Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 15, 353-376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Frey, B.S., Schneider, F., and Pommerehne, W.W. (1985). ‘‘Economists’ opinions on environmental policy instruments: Analysis of a survey.’’ Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 12(1), 62-71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Goulder, L.H. (1995). ‘‘Environmental taxation and the double dividend — A reader’s guide.’’ International Tax and Public Finance, 2, 157-183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Hahn, R.W. (1989). ‘‘Economic prescriptions for environmental problems: how the patient followed the doctor’s orders.’’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(2), 95-114.Google Scholar
  24. Hahn, R.W. (1990). ‘‘The political economy of environmental regulation: Towards a unifying framework.’’ Public Choice, 65, 21-47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., and Thaler, R. (1986). ‘‘Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market.’’ American Economic Review, 76, 728-741.Google Scholar
  26. Kimenyi, M.S., Lee, D.R., and Tollison, R.D. (1990). ‘‘Efficient lobbying and earmarked taxes.’’ Public Finance Quarterly, 18(1), 104-113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Kirchgässner, G. (1994). ‘‘Constitutional economics and its relevance for the evolution of rules.’’ Kyklos, 47(3), 321-339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Kirchgässner, G. (1998). ‘‘The double dividend debate: Some comments from a politico-economic perspective.’’ Empirica, 25(1), 37-49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Kirchgässner, G. (1999). ‘‘International environmental policy: Problems and possible solutions.’’ Aussenwirtschaft, 54(2), 269-290.Google Scholar
  30. Kirchgässner, G. and Schneider, F. (2003). ‘‘On the political economy of environmental policy.’’ Public Choice, 116(3-4), 369-396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Lepper, M. and Greene, D. (eds.) (1978). The Hidden Costs of Reward: New Perspectives on the Psychology of Human Motivation. New York: Erlbaum.Google Scholar
  32. Oberholzer-Gee, F. and Weck-Hannemann, H. (2002). ‘‘Pricing road use: Politico-economic and fairness considerations.’’ Transportation Research Part D: Transport and Environment, 7, 357-371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  34. Pearson, M. (1995). ‘‘The political economy of implementing environmental taxes,’’ in L. Bovenberg and S. Cnossen (eds.) Public Economics and the Environment in an Imperfect World. Boston; Kluwer, pp. 37-57.Google Scholar
  35. Pigou, A.C. (1920). The Economics of Welfare. London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
  36. Schneider, F. and Weck-Hannemann, H. (2005). ‘‘Why is Economic Theory Ignored in Environmental Policy Practice?’’ in C. Bohringer and A. Lange (eds.) Applied Research in Environmental Economics. Heidelberg: Physika, pp. 257-275.Google Scholar
  37. Schulze, G.G. and Ursprung, H.W. (eds.) (2001). International Environmental Economics — A Survey of the Issues. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  38. Schwarze, R. and Wagner, G.G. (2007). ‘‘The political economy of natural disaster insurance: Lessons from the failure of a proposed compulsory insurance scheme in Germany.’’ European Environment, 17(6), 403-415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Svendsen, G.T. (1999). ‘‘U.S. interest groups prefer emission trading: A new perspective.’’ Public Choice, 101, 109-128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Tullock, G. (1983). Economics of Income Redistribution. Boston: Kluwer.Google Scholar
  41. Weck-Hannemann, H. (2006). ‘‘Efficiency of Protection Measures,’’ in W.J. Ammann et al. (eds.) Risk 21 - Coping with Risks Due to Natural Hazards in the 21st Century. London: Taylor & Francis, pp. 147-154.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2008

Authors and Affiliations

  • Hannelore Weck-Hannemann

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations