Effectiveness of Coercive and Voluntary Institutional Solutions to Social Dilemmas

  • Yuval Samid
  • Ramzi Suleiman

In his seminal paper on “The Tragedy of the Commons,” Hardin (1968) analyzes the danger of excessive use of common resources. His discussion deals with common pastures, freedom of the seas, overcrowded national parks, pollution, and excessive population growth. Hardin rules out the appeal to conscience because it is self-eliminating in some cases and pathogenic in most cases. He claims that if the inherent logic of the commons dilemma generates tragedy, then the structure of the dilemma should be changed, and the structural change should introduce some form of coercive measure. For instance, the use of parking meters and traffic fines is required to keep downtown shoppers temperate in their use of parking spaces: “We need not actually forbid a citizen to park as long as he wants to; we need merely make it increasingly expensive for him to do so. Not prohibition, but carefully biased options are what we offer him” (Hardin, 1968, p. 1247). Hardin states that although we may not enjoy coercion, we must recognize that voluntary temperance would favor the conscienceless. The only kind of coercion Hardin recommends is “mutual coercion, mutually agreed upon by the majority of the people affected” (1968, p. 1247).


Collective Decision Social Dilemma Coercive Power Partial Feedback Full Feedback 


Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.


  1. Dawes, R. M. (1980). Social dilemmas. Annual Review of Psychology, 31, 169–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Dawes, R. M., Orbell, J. M., Simmons, R. T., Van de Kragt, A. J. C. (1986) Organizing groups for collective action. American Political Science Review, 80, 1171–1185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243–1248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Hobbes, T. (1651). Leviathan, or The Matter, Forme, & Power of a Common-Wealth Ecclesiasticall and Civill. London: Green Dragon in St. Pauls Church-yard.Google Scholar
  5. Kramer, C. Y. (1956). Extension of multiple range tests to group means with unequal numbers of replications. Biometrics, 12, 307–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Mulder, L. B., Van Dijk, E., De Cremer, D., Wilke, H. A. M. (2005). The effect of feedback on support for a sanctioning system in a social dilemma: a question of installing or maintaining the sanction. Journal of Economic Psychology, 26, 443–458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Mulder, L. B., Van Dijk, E., De Cremer, D. (2006a). Fighting noncooperative behavior in organizations: The dark side of sanctions. In E. A. Mannix & M. A. Neale (eds.), Ethics in Groups, Vol. 8, (research on managing groups and teams) (pp. 59–82). Stamford, CT: JAI Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Mulder, L. B., Van Dijk, E., De Cremer, D., Wilke, H. A. M. (2006b). Undermining trust and cooperation: The paradox of sanctioning systems in social dilemmas. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 42, 147–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Mulder, L. B., Van Dijk, E., De Cremer, D., Wilke, H. A. M. (2006c). When sanctions fail to increase cooperation in social dilemmas: Considering the presence of a defective alternative defective option. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 32, 1312–1324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Orbell, J. M., Rutherford, B. (1973). Can Leviathan make the life of man less solitary, poor, nasty, brutish, and short? British Journal of Political Science, 3, 383–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Platt, G. (1973). Social traps. American Psychologist, 28, 641–651.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Rapoport, A., Eshed-Levy, D. (1989) Provision of step-level public goods: Effects of greed and fear of being gypped. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 44, 325–344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Satterthwaite, F. W. (1946). An approximate distribution of estimates of variance components. Biometrics Bulletin, 2, 110–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Sidak, Z. (1967). Rectangular confidence regions for the means of multivariate normal distributions. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 62, 626–633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Van Meegeren, R. C. F. (1997). Communicatie en maatschappelijke acceptatie. Een onderzoek naar de houding ten aanzien van de “dure afvalzak” in Barendrecht. [Communication and social acceptance. A study of the attitude to the “expensive garbage bag” in Barendrecht]. Wageningen Universiteit, Wageningen.Google Scholar
  16. Yamagishi, T. (1986). The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51, 110–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Yamagishi, T. (1988a). Seriousness of social dilemmas and the provision of a sanctioning system. Social Psychology Quarterly, 51, 32–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Yamagishi, T. (1988b). The provision of a sanctioning system in the United States and Japan. Social Psychology Quarterly, 51, 264–270.Google Scholar
  19. Yamagishi, T. (1992). Group size and the provision of a sanctioning system in a social dilemma. In W. B. G. Liebrand, D. M. Messick. & H. A. M. Wilke (eds.), Social Dilemmas (pp. 267–287). Oxford: Pergamon Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2008

Authors and Affiliations

  • Yuval Samid
    • 1
  • Ramzi Suleiman
    • 1
  1. 1.University of HaifaMount CarmelIsrael

Personalised recommendations