Skip to main content

Spatial Theory

  • Chapter

Abstract

Assume that every voter’s preferences are single-peaked and slope downward monotonically on either side of the peak (unless his peak lies at one extreme of the scale).... The best way [for each party] to gain more support is to move toward the other extreme, so as to get more voters outside of it — i.e., to come between them and its opponent. As the two parties move closer together, they become more moderate and less extreme in policy in an effort to win the crucial middle-of-the-road voters, i.e., those whose views place them between the two parties. This center area becomes smaller and smaller as both parties strive to capture moderate votes; finally the two parties become nearly identical in platforms and actions. (Downs, 1957, pp. 116–117)

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   429.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Aristotle ([c. 350 B.C.] 1979). Politics and Poetics (translated by Benjamin Jowett and S.H. Butcher, Norwalk, CT: Easton Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, Kenneth J. (1951, 1963). Social Choice and Individual Values. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barr, James and Otto Davis (1966). “An elementary political and economic theory of the expenditures of local government.” Southern Economic Journal, 33: 149–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, Mark, Michael Munger, and Richard Potthoff. (2000). “The Downsian model predicts divergence.” Journal of Theoretical Politics, 12: 78–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, Duncan ([1958], 1987). The Theory of Committees and Elections. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, Duncan and Newing, R.A. (1951). Committee Decisions With Complementary Valuation. London: Lowe and Brydon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, Peter (1992). Probabilistic Voting Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, Gary (1987). “The core and the uncovered set.” American Journal of Political Science 31: 408–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, Otto and Melvin Hinich (1966). “A mathematical model of policy formation in a democratic society,” in J. Bernd (ed.) Mathematical Applications in Political Science, Volume II. Dallas: Southern Methodist University Press, pp. 175–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, Otto and Melvin Hinich (1967). “Some results related to a mathematical model of policy formation in a democratic society,” in J. Bernd (ed.) Mathematical Applications in Political Science, Volume III. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, pp. 14–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, Otto A. and Hinich Melvin, J., (1968). “On the power and importance of the mean preference in a mathematical model of democratic choice.” Public Choice, 5: 59–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, Otto A., Hinich Melvin, J., and Ordeshook, Peter C. (1970). “An expository development of a mathematical model of the electoral process.” American Political Science Review, 64: 426–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, Arthur and Robert Parks (1977). “A problem with public sector preferences.” Journal of Economic Theory, 14: 454–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, Arthur and Robert Parks (1979). “Deriving public sector preferences.” Journal of Public Economics, 11: 335–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, Anthony (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, James M. and Hinich Melvin, J. (1983). “On plott’s pair-wise symmetry condition for majority rule equilibrium.” Public Choice, 40(3): 317–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, James and Melvin Hinich, J., (1984). Spatial Theory of Voting: An Introduction. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, James M. and Melvin Hinich, J. (1989). “A general probabilistic spatial theory of elections.” Public Choice, 61: 101–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, James M. and Hinich, Melvin J. (eds.) (1990). Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, Melvin J. (1977). “Equilibrium in spatial voting: the median voting result is an artifact.” Journal of Economic Theory, 16: 208–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, Melvin J., Ledyard, John O., and Ordeshook, Peter C. (1973). “A theory of electoral equilibrium: a spatial analysis based on the theory of games.” Journal of Politics, 35: 154–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, Melvin and Michael Munger (1994). Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, Melvin and Michael Munger (1997). Analytical Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, Harold (1929). “Stability in competition.” Economic Journal, 39: 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, A.P. and Singer, H.W. (1937). “Some notes on duopoly and spatial competition.” The Journal of Political Economy, 45: 145–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, Richard (1976a). “General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models.” Econometrica, 47: 1085–1111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, Richard (1976b), “Intransitivities in multidimensional voting bodies and some implications for agenda control.” Journal of Economic Theory, 30: 283–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, Richard (1979). “Covering, dominance, and institution-free properties of social choice.” American Journal of Political Science, 30: 283–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, Richard (1986). “General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models.” Econometrica, 47: 1085–1111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, Richard and Peter Ordeshook (1990). “A decade of experimental results on spatial models of elections and committees,” in Enelow and Hinich (eds.) Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 99–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, Nicholas (1980). “A new solution set for tournament and majority voting.” American Journal of Political Science, 24: 68–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, Peter C. (1986). Game Theory and Political Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, Peter C. (1997). “The spatial analysis of elections and committees: four decades of research,” in Dennis Mueller (ed.) Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 247–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C.R. (1967). “A nation of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule.” American Economic Review, 57: 787–806.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, Keith and Howard Rosenthal (1996). Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll-Call Voting. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, William (1980). “Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions.” American Political Science Review, 74: 432–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, Thomas and Howard Rosenthal (1978). “Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo.” Public Choice, 33: 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, Howard (1990). “The setter model,” in Enelow and Hinich (eds.) Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 199–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, Norman (1978). “Instability of simple dynamic games,” Review of Economic Studies, 45: 575–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, Norman (1984). “Social equilibrium and cycles on compact sets,” Journal of Economic Theory, 33: 59–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slutsky, Steven (1977). “A voting model for the allocation of public goods: existence of an equilibrium.” Journal of Economic Theory, 14: 299–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smithies, Arthur (1941). “Optimum location in spatial competition.” The Journal of Political Economy, 49: 423–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2004 Kluwer Academic Publishers

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hinich, M.J., Munger, M.C. (2004). Spatial Theory. In: Rowley, C.K., Schneider, F. (eds) The Encyclopedia of Public Choice. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-306-47828-4_26

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-306-47828-4_26

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-0-7923-8607-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-0-306-47828-4

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics