Skip to main content

Regulation and Antitrust

  • Chapter

Abstract

The state — the machinery and power of the state — is a potential resource or threat to every industry in the society. With its power to prohibit or compel, to take or give money, the state can and does selectively help or hurt a vast number of industries. (Stigler, 1971: 3)

I benefited from the comments and suggestions of Fred McChesney, Michael Reksulak, Charles Rowley, Russell Sobel, Alexander Tabarrok and Robert Tollison. As is customary, however, I accept full responsibility for any remaining errors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   429.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Acton, J.P. and Vogelsang, I. (1989). “Price-cap regulation: introduction.” RAND Journal of Economics, 20: 369–372.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A.A. (1965). “Some economics of property rights.” Il Politico, 30(4): 816–829.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G.M., Ekelund, R.B. Jr, and Tollison, R.D. (1989). “Nassau senior as economic consultant: the factory acts reconsidered.” Economica, 56: 71–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G.M. and Tollison, R.D. (1984). “A rent-seeking explanation of the British factory acts,” in D.C. Collander (ed.) Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, pp. 187–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aranson, P.H. (1990). “Theories of economic regulation: from clarity to confusion.” Journal of Law and Politics, 6: 247–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armentano, D.T. (1990). Antitrust and Monopoly: Anatomy of a Policy Failure, Second Edition. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asch, P. (1975). “The determinants and effects of antitrust policy.” Journal of Law and Economics, 18: 575–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asch, P. and Seneca, J.J. (1976). “Is collusion profitable?” Review of Economics and Statistics, 58: 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Averch, H. and Johnson, L.L. (1962). “Behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint.” American Economic Review, 52: 1052–1069.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartel, A.P. and Thomas, L.G. (1987). “Predation through regulation: the wage and profit effects of the occupational safety and health administration and the environmental protection agency.” Journal of Law and Economics, 20: 239–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bator, F.M. (1958). “The anatomy of market failure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72: 351–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J., Bailey, E., and Willig, R. (1977). “Weak invisible hand theorems on the sustainability of prices in a multiproduct monopoly.” American Economic Review, 67: 350–365.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J. and Klevorick, A.K. (1970). “Input choices and rate-of-return regulation: an overview of the discussion.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 1: 162–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J., Panzar, J.C., and Willig, R.D. (1982). Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J. and Ordover, J.A. (1985). “Use of antitrust to subvert competition.” Journal of Law and Economics, 28: 247–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baxter, W.F. (1980). “The political economy of antitrust,” in R.D. Tollison (ed.) The Political Economy of Antitrust: Principal Paper by William Baxter. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, pp. 3–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1983). “A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98: 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1985). “Public policies, pressure groups, and dead weight costs.” Journal of Public Economics, 28: 329–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoletti, P. and Poletti, C. (1997). “X-inefficiency, competition and market information.” Journal of Industrial Economics, 45: 359–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bork, R.H. (1966). “Legislative intent and the policy of the Sherman act.” Journal of Law and Economics, 9: 7–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bork, R.H. (1978). The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudreaux, D.J., DiLorenzo, T.J., and Parker, S. (1995). “Antitrust before the Sherman act,” in F.S. McChesney and W.F. Shughart III (eds.) The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust: The Public-Choice Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 255–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1972). “Toward analysis of closed behavioral systems,” in J.M. Buchanan and R.D. Tollison (eds.) Theory of Public Choice. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 11–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1980). “Reform in the rent-seeking society,” in J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison, and G. Tullock (eds.) Toward a Theory of The Rent-Seeking Society. College Station: Texas A&M University Press, pp. 359–367.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G. (1962). The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G. (1968). “The ‘dead hand’ of monopoly.” Antitrust Law and Economic Review, 1: 85–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cawley, J. and Philipson, T. (1999). “An empirical examination of barriers to trade in insurance.” American Economic Review, 89: 827–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S.N.S. (1973). “The fable of the bees: an economic interpretation.” Journal of Law and Economics, 16: 11–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. (1946). “The marginal cost controversy.” Economica, 13: 169–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. (1959). “The federal communications commission.” Journal of Law and Economics, 2: 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. (1960). “The problem of social cost.” Journal of Law and Economics, 3: 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. (1974). “The lighthouse in economics.” Journal of Law and Economics, 17: 357–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coate, M.B., Higgins, R.S., and McChesney, F.S. (1990). “Bureaucracy and politics in FTC merger challenges.” Journal of Law and Economics, 33: 463–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coate, M.B. and McChesney, F.S. (1992). “Empirical evidence on FTC enforcement of the merger guidelines.” Economic Inquiry, 30: 277–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M. and McCormick, R.E. (1984). “Regulators as an interest group,” in J.M. Buchanan and R.D. Tollison (eds.) The Theory of Public Choice-II. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 287–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Alessi, L. (1982). “On the nature and consequences of private and public enterprise.” Minnesota Law Review, 67: 191–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Alessi, L. (1983). “Property rights, transaction costs, and X-efficiency: an essay in economic theory.” American Economic Review, 73: 64–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Alessi, L. (2001). “Property rights: private and political institutions,” in W.F. Shughart II and L. Razzolini (eds.) The Elgar Companion to Public Choice. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar, pp. 33–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Alessi, L. and Staaf, R.J. (1991). “The common law process: efficiency or order?” Constitutional Political Economy, 2: 107–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1968). “Why regulate utilities?” Journal of Law and Economics, 11: 55–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1969). “Information and efficiency: another viewpoint.” Journal of Law and Economics, 12: 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1970). “The private production of public goods.” Journal of Law and Economics, 13: 293–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1992). “How many cheers for antitrust’s 100 years?” Economic Inquiry, 30: 207–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiLorenzo, T.J. (1985). “The origins of antitrust: an interest-group perspective.” International Review of Law and Economics, 5: 73–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiLorenzo, T.J. and High, J.C. (1988). “Antitrust and competition, historically considered.” Economic Inquiry, 26: 423–435.

    Google Scholar 

  • Douglas, G.W. and Miller, J.C. III (1974). “Quality competition, industry equilibrium, and efficiency in the price-constrained airline market.” American Economic Review, 64: 657–669.

    Google Scholar 

  • Douglas, G.W. and Miller, J.C. III (1976). Economic Regulation of Domestic Air Transport: Theory and Policy. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterbrook, F.H. (1984). “The limits of antitrust.” University of Texas Law Review, 63: 1–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckbo, B.E. and Wier, P. (1985). “Antimerger policy under the Hart-Scott-Rodino act: a reexamination of the market-power hypothesis. Journal of Law and Economics, 28: 119–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R.B. Jr., McDonald, M.J., and Tollison, R.D. (1995). “Business restraints and the Clayton Act of 1914: publicor private-interest legislation?” in F.S. McChesney and W.F. Shughart II (eds.) The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust: The Public-Choice Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 271–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elzinga, K.G. (1969). “The antimerger law: Pyrrhic victories?” Journal of Law and Economics, 12: 43–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faith, R.L., Leavens, D.R. and Tollison, R.D. (1982). “Antitrust pork barrel.” Journal of Law and Economics, 25: 329–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garber, P.M. (2000). Famous First Bubbles: The Fundamentals of Early Manias. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harberger, A.C. (1954). “Monopoly and resource allocation.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 44: 77–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hay, D.A. and Morris, D.J. (1991). Industrial Economics and Organization: Theory and Evidence, Second Edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hazlett, T.W. (1984). “Interview with George Stigler.” Reason, January: 44–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, D.R. (1995). “Antitrust busters.” Reason, August/September: 62–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1938). “The general welfare in relation to problems of taxation and railway and utility rates.” Econometrica, 6: 242–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976). “Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordan, W.A. (1972). “Producer protection, prior market structure and the effects of government regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics, 15: 151–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. and Noll, R. (1981). “Regulation in theory and practice: an overview,” in G. Fromm (ed.) Studies in Public Regulation. Cambridge: MIT Press, pp. 1–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaysen, C. and Turner, D.F. (1959). Antitrust Policy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeler, T.E. (1972). “Airline regulation and market performance.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 3: 399–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keeler, T.E. (1984). “Theories of regulation and the deregulation movement.” Public Choice, 44(1): 103–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleit, A.N. (1993). “Common law, statute law, and the theory of legislative choice: an inquiry into the goal of the Sherman Act.” Economic Inquiry, 31: 647–662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A.O. (1974). “The political economy of the rent-seeking society.” American Economic Review, 64: 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lande, R.H. (1982). “Wealth transfers as the original and primary concern of antitrust: the efficiency interpretation challenged.” Hastings Law Journal, 34: 65–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Letwin, W. (1965). Law and Economic Policy in America: The Evolution of the Sherman Antitrust Act. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G.D. (1992). “The rise of the Chicago packers and the origins of meat inspection and antitrust.” Economic Inquiry, 30: 242–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. (1966). “Allocative efficiency vs. ‘x-efficiency’.” American Economic Review, 56: 392–415.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. (1978). “X-inefficiency xists — reply to an xorcist.” American Economic Review, 68: 203–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, W.F., Schramm, R., and Tollison, R.D. (1973). “The determinants of antitrust activity.” Journal of Law and Economics, 16: 351–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J.R. Jr (1997). “Donald Wittman’s The myth of democratic failure: review article.” Public Choice, 92: 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maloney, M.T. and McCormick, R.E. (1982). “A positive theory of environmental quality regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics, 25: 99–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marvel, H.P. (1977). “Factory regulation: a reinterpretation of early English experience.” Journal of Law and Economics, 20: 379–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F.S. (1987). “Rent extraction and rent creation in the economic theory of regulation.” Journal of Legal Studies, 16: 101–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F.S. (1991). “Rent extraction and interest-group organization in a Coasean model of regulation.” Journal of Legal Studies, 20: 73–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F.S. (1997). Money for Nothing: Politicians, Rent Extraction, and Political Extortion. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F.S. (1999). “Of stranded costs and stranded hopes: the difficulties of deregulation.” Independent Review, 3: 485–509.

    Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F.S. and Shughart, W.F. II (eds.) (1995). The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust: The Public-Choice Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R.E. (1984). “The strategic use of regulation: a review of the literature,” in R.A. Rogowsky and B. Yandle (eds.) The Political Economy of Regulation: Private Interests in the Regulatory Process. Washington, DC: Federal Trade Commission, pp. 13–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R.E., Shughart, W.F. II, and Tollison, R.D. (1984). “The disinterest in deregulation.” American Economic Review, 74: 1075–1079.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R.E. and Tollison, R.D. (1981). Politicians, Legislation, and the Economy: An Inquiry into the Interest-Group Theory of Government. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGraw, T.K. (1984). Prophets of regulation: Charles Francis Adams, Louis D. Brandeis, James M. Landis, Alfred E. Kahn. Cambridge and London: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moore, T.G. (1986). “U.S. airline deregulation: its effects on passengers, capital, and labor.” Journal of Law and Economics, 29: 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, P. (1970). “Information and consumer behavior.” Journal of Political Economy, 78: 311–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pashigian, B.P. (1985). “Environmental quality regulation: whose self-interests are being protected? Economic Inquiry, 23: 551–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). “Toward a more general theory of regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics, 19: 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1993). “George Stigler’s contribution to the economic analysis of regulation.” Journal of Political Economy, 101: 818–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1989, 1998). “The economic theory of regulation after a decade of deregulation,” in S. Peltzman (eds.) Political Participation and Government Regulation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 286–323.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peterman, J.A. (1975). “The Brown Shoe case.” Journal of Law and Economics, 18: 81–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A.C. (1932). The Economics of Welfare, Fourth Edition. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R.A. (1969a). “The federal trade commission.” University of Chicago Law Review, 37: 47–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R.A. (1969b, 1999). Natural Monopoly and its Regulation. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R.A. (1971). “Taxation by regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2: 22–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R.A. (1974). “Theories of economic regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5: 335–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R.A. (1975). “The social costs of monopoly and regulation.” Journal of Political Economy, 83: 807–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, F.P. (1927). “A contribution to the theory of taxation.” Economic Journal, 37: 47–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogowsky, R.A. (1986). “The economic effectiveness of section 7 relief.” Antitrust Bulletin, 31: 187–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogowsky, R.A. (1987). “The Pyrrhic victories of section 7: a political economy approach,” in R.J. Mackay, J.C. Miller III, and B. Yandle (eds.) Public Choice and Regulation: A View From Inside the Federal Trade Commission. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, pp. 220–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, T.W. (1984). “Winners and losers under the Robinson-Patman Act.” Journal of Law and Economics, 27: 243–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C.K. (1966). The British Monopolies Commission. London: George Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C.K. (1997). “Donald Wittman’s The myth of democratic failure: review article.” Public Choice, 92: 15–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C.K. and Peacock, A.T. (1975). Welfare Economics: A Liberal Restatement. Oxford: Martin Robertson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C.K. and Yarrow, G.K. (1981). “Property rights, regulation and public enterprise: the case of the British steel industry 1957–1975.” International Review of Law and Economics, 1: 63–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P.H. (1995). “What do economists think about antitrust? A random walk down Pennsylvania avenue,” in F.S. McChesney and W.F. Shughart II (eds.) The Causes and Consequences of Antitrust: The Public-Choice Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 33–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1954). “The pure theory of public expenditure,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 36: 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer, F.M. (1980). Industrial market structure and economic performance, Second Edition. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, K.M. (1997). “Managerial incentives and product market competition.” Review of Economic Studies, 64: 191–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, R.W. and Simpson, P. (1986). “The persistence of monopoly: an investigation of the effectiveness of the United Kingdom monopolies commission.” Journal of Industrial Economics, 34: 355–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sherman, R. (1989). The Regulation of Monopoly. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W.F. II (1990). Antitrust Policy and Interest-Group Politics. New York: Quorum Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W.F. II (1997). The Organization of Industry, Second Edition. Houston, TX: Dame Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W.F. II (1999). “The reformer’s dilemma.” Public Finance Review, 27: 561–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W.F. II and Tollison, R.D. (1985). “The positive economics of antitrust policy: a survey article.” International Review of Law and Economics, 5: 39–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shy, O. (2001). The Economics of Network Industries. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegfried, J.J. (1975). “The determinants of antitrust activity.” Journal of Law and Economics, 17: 559–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H.A. (1957). Models of Man. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sproul, M.T. (1993). “Antitrust and prices.” Journal of Political Economy, 101: 741–754.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spulber, D.F. (1989). Regulation and Markets. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1964). “Public regulation of the securities market.” Journal of Business, 2: 117–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1966). “The economic effects of the antitrust laws.” Journal of Law and Economics, 9: 225–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1971). “The economic theory of regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2: 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1975). “Supplementary note on economic theories of regulation (1975),” in G.J. Stigler (ed.) The Citizen and The State: Essays on Regulation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 137–141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1976). “The xistence of x-efficiency.” American Economic Review, 86: 213–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1985). “The origin of the Sherman Act.” Journal of Legal Studies, 14: 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (ed.) (1988). Chicago Studies in Political Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. and Friedland, C. (1962). “What can regulators regulate? The case of electricity.” Journal of Law and Economics, 5: 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R.D. and Wagner, R.E. (1991). “Romance, realism, and economic reform.” Kyklos, 44(1): 57–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train, K.E. (1991). Optimal Regulation: The Economic Theory of Natural Monopoly. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Troesken, W. (2000). “Did the trusts want a federal antitrust law? An event study of state antitrust enforcement and passage of the Sherman Act,” in J.C. Heckelman, J.C. Moorhouse, and R.M. Whaples (eds.) Public Choice Interpretations of American Economic History. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 77–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). “The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies and theft.” Western Economic Journal, 5: 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1975). “The transitional gains trap.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 6: 671–678.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). “Efficient rent seeking,” in J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison, and G. Tullock (eds.) Toward a Theory of The Rent-Seeking Society. College Station: Texas A&M University Press, pp. 97–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Utton, M. (2000). “Going European: Britain’s new competition law.” Antitrust Bulletin, 45: 531–551.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weir, C. (1992). “Monopolies and mergers commission, merger reports and the public interest: a probit analysis.” Applied Economics, 24: 27–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilcox, C. (1966). Public Policies Toward Business, Third Edition. Homewood, IL: Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1968a). “Economies as an antitrust defense: the welfare tradeoffs.” American Economic Review, 58: 18–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1968b). “Wage rates as a barrier to entry: the Pennington case in perspective.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82: 85–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1976). “Franchise bidding for natural monopolies — in general and with respect to CATV.” Bell Journal of Economics, 7: 73–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1977). “Economies as an antitrust defense revisited.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 125: 699–736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1989). “Why democracies produce efficient results.” Journal of Political Economy, 97: 1395–1424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1995). The Myth of Democratic Failure: Why Political Institutions are Efficient. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2004 Kluwer Academic Publishers

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Shughart, W.F. (2004). Regulation and Antitrust. In: Rowley, C.K., Schneider, F. (eds) The Encyclopedia of Public Choice. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-306-47828-4_22

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-306-47828-4_22

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-0-7923-8607-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-0-306-47828-4

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics