Skip to main content
  • 1223 Accesses

Abstract

What does increasing globalization mean for workers? This would appear to be a fairly straightforward question to which one might have a forthright answer. In fact, ‘the answer’ may just depend on one’s perspective. To the auto worker in Detroit, increasing integration of the world economy means long-term unemployment, loss of human capital, and perhaps lost dreams. For the new university graduate in India, rapid globalization may mean the creation of exciting new opportunities for employment in well-paid jobs. Deeper integration with the world economy provides a campaign issue politicians of all stripes: some railing against the damage caused by a tsunami of cheap foreign imports with others extolling the vast benefits of greater access to foreign markets. For a trade economist, expanded trade might mean changes in relative price and the associated Stolper-Samuelson effects, reducing real wages in labour scarce countries while increasing real wages in labour abundant countries. In contrast a labour economist might suggest that the factor trade implicit in a country’s net exports effectively augments (or diminishes) the country’s available supply of labour, thereby reducing (or increasing) the wage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 189.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Agell, J. and P. Lundborg (1995). Fair wages in the open economy. Economica, 62: 325–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albrecht, J. and S. Vroman (2002). A matching model with endogenous skill requirements. International Economics Review, 43(1): 282–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altenberg, L. and A. Brenken (2008). Effort, trade and unemployment. Canadian Journal of Economics, 41(3): 864–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antras, P., L. Garicano, and E. Rossi-Hansberg (2006). Offshoring in a knowledge economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121: 31–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Artuç, E., S. Chaudhuri, and J. McLaren (2007). Trade shocks and labor adjustment: A structural empirical approach. NBER Working Paper # 13465.

    Google Scholar 

  • — (2008). Delay and dynamics in labor market adjustment: Simulation results. Journal of International Economics, 75(1): 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C. (1975). Implicit contracts and underemployment equilibria. Journal of Political Economy, 83(6): 1183–1202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baily, M. (1974). Wage and employment under uncertain demand. Review of Economic Studies, 41: 37–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., J. Mutti, and D. Richardson (1980). Welfare effects on the United States of a significant multilateral tariff reduction. Journal of International Economics, 10(3): 405–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1973). A theory of marriage: Part I. Journal of Political Economy, 81(4): 813–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bound, J. and G. Johnson (1992). Changes in the structure of wages in the 1980s: An evaluation of alternative explanations. The American Economic Review, 82(3): 371–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradford, S. (2006). Protection and unemployment. Journal of International Economics, 69(2): 257–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brecher, R. (1974a). Minimum wage rates and the pure theory of international trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88(1): 98–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1974b). Optimal commercial policy for a minimum-wage economy. Journal of International Economics, 4(2): 139–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1992). An efficiency wage model with explicit monitoring: Unemployment and welfare in an open economy. Journal of International Economics, 32(1–2): 179–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brecher, R. and E. Choudhri (1994). Pareto gains from trade, reconsidered: Compensating for jobs lost. Journal of International Economics, 36(3–4): 223–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, S., S. Chaudhuri, and J. McLaren (2007). Trade shocks and labor adjustment: Theory. NBER Working Paper # 13463.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, T. (1999). Illegal immigration in an efficiency wage model. Journal of International Economics, 49(2): 385–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, S. and J. McLaren (2007). Some simple analytics of trade and labor mobility. NBER Working Paper # 13464.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chin, J. (1998). Rural-urban wage differentials, unemployment, and efficiency wages: An open economy policy analysis. Southern Economic Journal, 65(2): 294–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemenz, G. (1995). Adverse selection in labor markets and international trade. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97(1): 73–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland, B. (1989). Efficiency wages in a Ricardian model of international trade. Journal of International Economics, 27(3–4): 221–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A. (2009a). Jobs, jobs, jobs: A ‘new’ perspective on protectionism. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(5): 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2009b). An elementary theory of comparative advantage. Econometrica, 77(4): 1165–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A. and J. Vogel (2009). Matching and inequality in the world economy. MIT working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Das, S. (2006). Incentive pay, worker effort and trade protection. Review of International Economics, 4(2): 141–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, C., L. Martin, and S. Matusz (1987). Search, unemployment and the production of jobs. Economic Journal, 97(388): 857–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1988). The structure of simple general equilibrium models with frictional unemployment. Journal of Political Economy, 96(6): 1267–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1991). Multiple free trade equilibria in micro models of unemployment. Journal of International Economics, 31(1–2): 157–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1999). Trade and search generated unemployment. Journal of International Economics, 48(2): 271–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, C. and S. Matusz (2000). Globalization and labour-market adjustment: How fast and at what cost? Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 16(3): 42–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2004a). International Trade and Labor Markets: Theory, Evidence and Policy Implications. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • — (2004b). An overlapping generations model of escape clause protection. Review of International Economics, 12(5): 749–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2004c). Should policy makers be concerned about adjustments costs? In The Political Economy of Trade, Aid and Foreign Investment Policies (D. Mitra and A. Panagariya, eds), Elsevier, Springer-Verlag and Edward Elgar: 31–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • — (2005). Trade and turnover: Theory and evidence. Review of International Economics, 13(5): 861–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2006a). Trade liberalization and compensation. International Economic Review, 47(3): 723–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2006b). Long run lunacy, short run sanity: A simple model of trade with labor market turnover. Review of International Economics, 14(2): 261–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, C., S. Matusz, and A. Shevchenko (2008a). Globalization and firm level adjustment with imperfect labor markets. Journal of International Economics, 75(2): 295–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2008b). Outsourcing Peter to pay Paul: High-skill expectations and low-skill wages with imperfect labor markets. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 12(4): 463–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, D. (1998). Does European unemployment prop up American wages? National labor markets and global trade. American Economic Review, 88(3): 478–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, D. and J. Harrigan (2007). Good jobs, bad jobs and trade liberalization. Columbia University Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, S., J. Haltiwanger, and S. Schuh (1996). Job Creation and Job Destruction. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. and V. Norman (1980). Theory of International Trade. London: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dutt, P., D. Mitra, and P. Ranjan (2009). International trade and unemployment: Theory and cross-national evidence. Journal of International Economics, 78(1): 32–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger, H. and U. Kreickemeier (2008a). Fairness, Trade, and Inequality. CESifo Working Paper 2344.

    Google Scholar 

  • — (2008b). International fragmentation: Boon or bane for domestic employment. European Economic Review, 52(1): 116–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2009). Firm heterogeneity and the labor market effects of trade liberalization. International Economic Review, 50(1): 187–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ethier, W. (1982). Dumping. Journal of Political Economy, 90(3): 487–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. (2010). Offshoring in the Global Economy: Microeconomic Structure and Macroeconomic Implications. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. and G. Hanson (1996). Globalization, outsourcing and wage inequality. American Economic Review, 86(2): 240–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • — (1999). The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: Estimates for the United States, 1979–1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3): 907–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr, G., J Prat, and H. Schmerer (2008). Globalization and labor market outcomes: Wage bargaining, search frictions and firm heterogeneity. IZA Discussion Paper 3363.

    Google Scholar 

  • — (2009). Trade and unemployment: What do the data say? IZA Discussion Paper 4184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R. (1992). Terms-of-trade uncertainty, incomplete markets and unemployment. International Economic Review, 33(4): 881–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaisford, J. and L. Leger (2000). Terms-of-trade shocks, labor-market adjustment and safeguard measures. Review of International Economics, 8: 100–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, D. (1974). A neo-classical theory of Keynesian unemployment. Economic Inquiry, 12: 431–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. (2004). The distribution of talent and the pattern and consequences of international Trade. Journal of Political Economy, 112(1): 209–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. and G. Maggi (2000). Diversity and trade. American Economic Review, 90(5): 1255–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. and O. Itskhoki (2009). Labor market rigidities, trade and unemployment. Harvard University Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., O. Itskhoki and S. Redding (2009). Inequality and unemployment in a global economy. Harvard University working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoon, H. (2000). Trade, Jobs and Wages. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Ltd.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • — (2001a). Adjustment of wages and equilibrium unemployment in a Ricardian global economy. Journal of International Economics, 54: 193–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (2001b). General-equilibrium implications of international product-market competition for jobs and wages. Oxford Economic Papers, 53: 138–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hosios, A. (1990). Factor market search and the structure of simple general equilibrium models. Journal of Political Economy, 98(2): 325–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson, L., R. LaLonde, and D. Sullivan (1993a). Earnings losses of displaced workers. American Economic Review, 83(4): 685–709.

    Google Scholar 

  • — (1993b). The Costs of Worker Dislocation. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Janeba, E. (1999). Exports, unemployment, and the welfare state. Canadian Journal of Economics, 42(3): 930–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janiak, A. (2007). Does trade liberalization lead to unemployment: Theory and some evidence. ECARES, Universite Libre de Bruxelles Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, G. and F. Stafford (1999). The labor market implications of international trade. In Handbook of Labor Economics (O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds.). Elsevier 1(3): 2215–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karp, L. and T. Paul (1994). Phasing in and phasing out protectionism with costly adjustment of labour. Economic Journal, 104: 1379–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1998). Labor adjustment and gradual reform: When is commitment important? Journal of International Economics, 46: 333–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kletzer, L. (2001). Job Loss from Imports: Measuring the Costs. Washington D.C.: Peterson Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreickmeier, U. and D. Nelson (2006). Fair wages, unemployment and technological change in a global economy. Journal of International Economics, 70(2): 451–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kremer, M. and E. Maskin (2006). Globalization and inequality. Harvard University Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1993). What do undergraduates need to know about trade? American Economic Review, 83(2): 23–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lapan, H. (1976). International trade, factor market distortions, and the optimal dynamic subsidy. American Economic Review, 66: 335–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leamer, E. and J. Levinsohn (1995). International trade theory: The evidence. In Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3 (G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, eds.). Amsterdam, Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Legros, P. and A. Newman (2002). Monotone matching in perfect and imperfect worlds. Review of Economic Studies, 69(4): 925–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magee, C., C. Davidson and S. Matusz (2005). Trade, turnover, and tithing. Journal of International Economics, 66(1): 157–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magee, S. (1972). The welfare effects of restriction on US trade. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3: 645–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matusz, S. (1985). The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model with implicit contracts. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(4): 1313–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1986). Implicit contracts, unemployment and international trade. Economic Journal, 96(382): 307–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1994). International trade policy in a model of unemployment and wage differentials. Canadian Journal of Economics, 27(4): 939–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1996). International trade, the division of labor, and unemployment. International Economic Review, 37(1): 71–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1998). Calibrating the employment effects of trade. Review of International Economics, 6(4): 592–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71: 1695–1725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, M. and P. Ranjan (2005). Globalisation and skill-biased technological change: Implications for unemployment and wage inequality. Economic Journal, 115(503): 391–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. and F. Welch (1989). Wage premiums for college graduates: recent growth and possible explanations. Educational Researcher, 18(4): 17–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussa, M. (1993). Making the practical case for freer trade. American Economic Review, 83(2): 372–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohlin, B. (1933). Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohnsorge, F. and D. Trefler (2007). Sorting it out: International trade with heterogeneous workers. Journal of Political Economy, 115(5): 868–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1948). International trade and the equalization of factor prices. Economic Journal, 58(230): 163–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • — (1949). International factor-price equalization once again. Economic Journal, 59(234): 181–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimer, R. and L. Smith (2000). Assortative matching and search. Econometrica, 68: 343–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sly, N. (2009). Labor matching behavior in open economies and trade adjustment. University of Oregon Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slaughter, M. (1999). Globalization and wages: A tale of two perspectives. World Economy, 22: 609–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trefler, D. (2004). The long and short of the Canada-US Free Trade Agreement. American Economic Review, 94(4): 870–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winters, A. and W. Tackas (1991). Labour adjustment costs and British footwear protection. Oxford Economic Papers, 43: 479–501.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 2013 Carl Davidson and Steven J. Matusz

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Davidson, C., Matusz, S.J. (2013). Trade and Labour Markets. In: Bernhofen, D., Falvey, R., Greenaway, D., Kreickemeier, U. (eds) Palgrave Handbook of International Trade. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-230-30531-1_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics