Skip to main content

Inter-Organizational Cooperation and Supply Chain Management

  • Chapter
Book cover Evaluation of Cooperative Planning in Supply Chains
  • 811 Accesses

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Refer for example to Marwell & Schmitt, 1975, p. 5; Plaßmann, 1974, pp. 9f; Schwarz, 1979.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Also refer to Grunwald, 1981, p. 74.

    Google Scholar 

  3. For cooperation within the firm refer, for example, to Zörgiebel, 1983, pp. 102f; Schwarz, 1979, pp. 88f; Endress, 1991, pp. 74f.

    Google Scholar 

  4. In the context of this dissertation, the term Hierarchy can be derived into the terms group, corporation, merger, or acquisition (Rotering, 1993, p. 9). Refer also to Büchs, 1991, pp. 3f.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Other theoretical frameworks that allow delimiting “cooperation” are, for example, the Theory of Organizational Equilibrium (Barnard, 1968; see also Simon, 1947; March & Simon, 1993; Boettcher, 1974) and the Contingency Theory as a reaction to Weber (1922) and the older work on Organization Theory (Pugh & Hickson, 1971; Pugh, 1981; Frese, 2000, pp. 313f; Kieser & Walgenbach, 2003). Refer to Rotering (1993, pp. 66–147) for an evaluation of these approaches for delimiting “cooperation”.

    Google Scholar 

  6. For the origins of the differentiation between conscious and unconscious cooperation refer to Mill, 1924, pp. 174f.

    Google Scholar 

  7. For these topics refer, for example, to Schelling, 1963; Kenneth, 1986; Gowa, 1986; Jervis, 1988; Milner, 1992; Axelrod, 1997; Lake & Powell, 1999; Axelrod, 2000

    Google Scholar 

  8. A core competency “provides potential access to a wide variety of markets [...], should make a significant contribution to the perceived customer benefits of the end product [...], [and] should be difficult for competitors to imitate” (Prahalad & Hamel, 1990, p. 83). For more on the concept of core competencies, see Prahalad and Hamel (1990), who developed the main ideas of this concept, and Grant (1998) for a more general discussion of a firm’s competencies and core competencies.

    Google Scholar 

  9. For a differentiation between descriptive and normative characteristics of the term “cooperation” refer to Salje, 1981, pp. 3f.

    Google Scholar 

  10. For further structuring methodologies refer, for example, to Boettcher, 1974, pp. 25f; Bleicher, 1989, p. 4; Schaude, 1991, pp. 6f.

    Google Scholar 

  11. For the Sociology, for example, refer to Parsons, 2001, p. 72; for Jurisprudence, for example, refer to Hueck, 2003, p. 27; for the general differentiation between “pooling” and “exchanging” in other fields of research refer to Hansen et al., 1983, p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Rotering (1993, p. 56) gives an example for a reciprocal cooperation. He describes how Lufthansa AG and Air France performed an exchange of higher management personnel for the period of some months.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Other reciprocities described by Sahlins (1973, pp. 147f) are “generalized reciprocity” which are transactions that are altruistic, and “negative reciprocity” which is “the attempt to get something for nothing with impunity.”

    Google Scholar 

  14. For more information on the business functions and on the processes, see Lambert et al. (1998), Lambert (2002), Cooper et al. (1997b), Croxton et al. (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  15. Transaction costs can be defined as “[t]he costs other than the money price that are incurred in trading goods or services” (Johnson, 2000). They are the sum of “search and information costs”, “bargaining and decision costs”, and “policing and enforcement costs” (Johnson, 2000). These kinds of costs are discussed within the framework of transaction cost economics (TCE) which was developed by Coase (1937) and Williamson (1979 and 1981)

    Google Scholar 

  16. For a more detailed information on the business functions and on the processes, see Lambert et al. (1998), Lambert (2002), Croxton (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  17. For further information on the principal-agent theory refer, for example, to Mirrless (1974, 1976), Grossmann and Hart (1983), and Holmstrom (1979).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2006 Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag ∣ GWV Fachverlage GmbH, Wiesbaden

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2006). Inter-Organizational Cooperation and Supply Chain Management. In: Evaluation of Cooperative Planning in Supply Chains. DUV. https://doi.org/10.1007/3-8350-5714-6_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics