Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

  • 785 Accesses

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. See Werner, 2002; Neuhoff, 2003 and 2005; Hirschfeld, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003; Scheurle, 2003; Heinrichs, 2004; Wünschmann, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  2. See WIK, 2005; Newbery, 2000, discusses also more network markets.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Kahn, 1988, p. 127.

    Google Scholar 

  4. See Heng, 2005, p. 3, for a complete listing of the relevant green-papers.

    Google Scholar 

  5. See Büchner, 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See Schütz, 2005a, pp. 166 ff., for an overview of the key decisions of the German NRA.

    Google Scholar 

  7. See Bundeskartellamt, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  8. See Fredebeul-Krein/ Freytag, 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  9. See Commission of the European Communities, 2002b, Article 4 (1); Heun et al., 2002, p. 426, for the German telecommunications market; in the German TKG 2004 this is regulated in § 16.

    Google Scholar 

  10. See Ritter, 2004; Büchner, 1990; Jäger, 1994, Knieps, 2004, for an overview of the developments, especially in the German telecommunications market.

    Google Scholar 

  11. See Scherer, 2002. Tele2, 2005, offers an international overview of the regulatory situation in Europe. See Coen, 2005, for a critical view on the convergence into a single European regulatory model.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See Schütz, 2005a, pp. 189 ff.; Kurth, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See EITO, 2005, pp. 93 ff.; Arthur D. Little, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  14. See EITO, 2005, pp. 12 ff., for a description of the dynamic development of the telecommunication markets worldwide. 18 See Bijl/ Peitz, 2005, for an international overview of the (regulatory-) problems of this bottleneck, mostly discussed under the heading ‘local loop unbundling’.

    Google Scholar 

  15. See Elixmann/ Schäfer/ Schwab, 2004, for an overview of the German value added services market.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See Putz & Partner, 2004, for a complete listing of the associations in the telecommunications market in Germany.

    Google Scholar 

  17. See Dialog Consult/ VATM, 2004; see RegTP, 2005a, for data on the competitive market situation in Germany. See Scholl, 1998; Büchner, 1999, for the political background. See Neumann/ Stamm, 2002, for an overview of the discussion on further reform.

    Google Scholar 

  18. See Koenig/ Vogelsang/ Winkler, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  19. See Hempell, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Monopolkommission, 2004a; Soltwedel et al., 1986, p. 198.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See Rickert, 2004; FAZ, 2004d, p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  22. See Koch, 2004; Commission of the European Communities, 2005b.

    Google Scholar 

  23. See RegTP, 2005a and 2003b; Monopolkommission, 2004a.

    Google Scholar 

  24. See Frost & Sullivan, 2004, who state that WLAN could be a product which moves in between the two products fixed and mobile. This could hinder the substitution even more, as it drives the markets further apart. At present however, it seems as if it would connect the two markets. 30 See Lunden, 2005; Kuthan, 2004; Sisalem, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See RegTP, 2004b.

    Google Scholar 

  26. See Golvin, 2004; Rodini/ Ward/ Woroch, 2003; Deutsche Bank, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  27. See Frost & Sullivan, 2004; Koenig/ Vogelsang/ Winkler, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  28. See OECD, 1998, pp. 191 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  29. See Polatschek, 2004; Die Bahn, 2005a, allows for a technical overview of this complexity of running a railway.

    Google Scholar 

  30. See Kirchner, 2003, for an overview of the European rail transport markets.

    Google Scholar 

  31. See Friebel/ Ivaldi/ Vibes, 2004, p. 2; OECD, 1998, pp. 141 ff. See Miller, 2003, for a historic worldwide overview of the economic development of the rail transport sector.

    Google Scholar 

  32. See OECD, 1998, p. 147.

    Google Scholar 

  33. See OECD, 1998, p. 12, for more details on this study called ‘Untersuchung Wettbewerbsfähigkeit Bahn’.

    Google Scholar 

  34. For the reform process of the rail sector in Germany see: OECD, 1998; Bennemann, 1994, Julitz, 1997, Berndt/ Kunz, 2000. For a critical view see VCD, 2004a; Ilgmann, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  35. See OECD, 1998, p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  36. See Bundesregierung, 2002a; PSPC, 2003; Bundesrat, 2005, for the reform of the AEG.

    Google Scholar 

  37. See EBA, 2004; Schweinsberg, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  38. See Allianz pro Schiene, 2004, for a critical appraisal of the reform. For the political dimension of the German liberalisation see Friedrich, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  39. See Brauner/ Kühlwetter, 2002, p. 493; in the AEG this is regulated in § 14 (4); Schweinsberg, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  40. See Kirchner, 2003 and 2004, for an overview and structure.

    Google Scholar 

  41. See OECD, 1998, p. 12, for more details on this study called ‘Untersuchung Wettbewerbsfähigkeit Bahn’.

    Google Scholar 

  42. For the reform process of the rail sector in Germany see: OECD, 1998; Bennemann, 1994, Julitz, 1997, Berndt/ Kunz, 2000. For a critical view see VCD, 2004a; Ilgmann, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  43. See OECD, 1998, p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  44. See Bundesregierung, 2002a; PSPC, 2003; Bundesrat, 2005, for the reform of the AEG.

    Google Scholar 

  45. See EBA, 2004; Schweinsberg, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  46. See Allianz pro Schiene, 2004, for a critical appraisal of the reform. For the political dimension of the German liberalisation see Friedrich, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  47. See Brauner/ Kühlwetter, 2002, p. 493; in the AEG this is regulated in’ 14 (4); Schweinsberg, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  48. See Kirchner, 2003 and 2004, for an overview and structure.

    Google Scholar 

  49. See Stinnes, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  50. See Die Bahn, 2005b.

    Google Scholar 

  51. See Miller, 2003, p. 58.

    Google Scholar 

  52. See Scherer, 2002, p. 283

    Google Scholar 

  53. See Miller, 2003, p. 13.

    Google Scholar 

  54. See Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  55. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  56. See SPD, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  57. See RegTP, 2004a; Tele2, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  58. See Fredebeul-Krein/ Freytag, 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  59. See Kiessling/ Blondeel, 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  60. See Kirchner, 2003 and 2004, for the railway markets.

    Google Scholar 

  61. See Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  62. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  63. Pelkmans, 2001, p. 437.

    Google Scholar 

  64. See Commission of the European Communities, 2004d.

    Google Scholar 

  65. See ERG, 2003b, for an example of the working groups of the national regulators and their discussion of harmonisation of remedies to counter the market failures.

    Google Scholar 

  66. See Ruhle, 2005, p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  67. See Yan, 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  68. See Heinrichs, 2003; Scheurle, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  69. See Bundesregierung, 2002b, pp. 16 and 44 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  70. See Winkler, 2005; in the German TKG 2004 this arbitration is regulated in § 51 and mediation in § 124.

    Google Scholar 

  71. See Kurth, 2002; Schütz, 2005a, p. 159.

    Google Scholar 

  72. See Wünschmann, 2005; Rochlitz, 2003; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  73. See Kurth, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  74. See Bijl / Peitz, 2002, p. xi, for regulation in telecommunication markets. For a critical view on asymmetrical regulation in the broadband market see Crandall/ Sidak/ Singer, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  75. See Ritter, 2004. pp. 110 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  76. See Ernst, 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  77. See Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  78. See Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  79. See Mai, 2004, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  80. See Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  81. See Nett/ Neumann/ Vogelsang, 2004; Freytag/ Winkler, 2003; Nolte/ König, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  82. See Wirtschaftsrat, 2004, pp. 2 ff., demonstrating that the mobile operators express a belief that it should stay that way.

    Google Scholar 

  83. See Koenig/ Vogelsang/ Winkler, 2005; Crandall/ Sidak, 2004; Deutsche Bank, 2004; Rodini/ Ward/ Woroch, 2003; Frost&Sullivan, 2004; Wengler/ Schäfer, 2003; Monopolkommission, 2004a, for the fixed to mobile termination issue and the regulatory problems around it

    Google Scholar 

  84. See Winkelhage, 2005, p. 20.

    Google Scholar 

  85. See ecta, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  86. See Ludewig, 2005, p. 19.

    Google Scholar 

  87. See Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  88. See Giovannetti, 2005, p. 46.

    Google Scholar 

  89. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  90. See McKinsey, 2002, p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  91. See OECD, 1998, p. 23 and pp. 169 ff., on regulation in railway markets.

    Google Scholar 

  92. See Canoy/ Bijl/ Kemp, 2004, pp. 161 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  93. See Engel, 2002a.

    Google Scholar 

  94. See Kiessling/ Blondeel, 1998, p. 571.

    Google Scholar 

  95. See Héritier, 2001b, p. 24.

    Google Scholar 

  96. This paragraph builds on Schaaffkamp, 2004; Balzuweit/ Brümmer, 2002; Wiesmann/ Steinbach, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  97. See Rochlitz, 2002, p. 1, for a critical view on tender-competition.

    Google Scholar 

  98. See OECD, 1998, p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  99. See Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  100. See Friebel/ Ivaldi/ Vibes, 2004, p. 2, for the rail markets and Ritter, 2004, pp. 272 ff., for the telecommunications market.

    Google Scholar 

  101. See Friebel/ Ivaldi/ Vibes, 2004, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  102. See Ypsilanti/ Xavier, 1998, p. 653; in the German TKG 2004 this is regulated in § 23.

    Google Scholar 

  103. See Stoffels, 2004, p. 6, discusses the possibilities of the operators to negotiate standard contracts and adapt them to their own needs with the incumbent DT. He finds that even though negotiations take place, DT is not willing to change core issues of the contract.

    Google Scholar 

  104. See Better Regulation Task Force, 2001, p. 5; OECD, 1998, pp. 211 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  105. See Ritter, 2004, pp. 273 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  106. See Perrucci/ Cimatoribus, 1997, p. 508.

    Google Scholar 

  107. See Susskind/ McKearnan/ Thomas-Larmer, 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  108. See Scheurle, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  109. See Rochlitz, 2003; Heinrichs, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  110. See Frühbrodt, 2002b, p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  111. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  112. See Kirchner, 2003 and 2004, for an overview of the legal situation over time in the rail markets in Europe.

    Google Scholar 

  113. See Handelsblatt, 2001, which shows that in 2001 there were about 1,200 cases in Germany where RegTPs decisions were appealed by operators. The exact numbers are not published.

    Google Scholar 

  114. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  115. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Heinrichs, 2004; Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  116. See Die Bahn, 2002b–2005b.

    Google Scholar 

  117. See Rochlitz, 2003; Heinrichs, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  118. See Scheurle, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  119. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  120. See Ritter, 2004, pp. 177 ff., for a detailed description on the genesis of the EBC ruling.

    Google Scholar 

  121. See Gifford, 2003, pp. 477 ff. He even claims for the public utilities regulators that “it is a wonder that they can do their job at all.”

    Google Scholar 

  122. See Kiessling/ Blondeel, 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  123. See Rawls, 1971, pp. 136 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  124. See Canoy/ Bijl/ Kemp, 2004, p. 162.

    Google Scholar 

  125. See Büllingen/ Hillebrand/ Wörter, 2002, pp. 65 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  126. See Heinrichs, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  127. See Krummheuer, 2005b, p. 17, for the example of Connex, which publicly claims that they will go to court and to the EU commission to gain access to the network of DB.

    Google Scholar 

  128. See Wünschmann, 2005; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  129. See Heinrichs, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  130. See Neuhoff, 2003; Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  131. See Elixmann/ Metzler/ Schäfer, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  132. See Monopolkommission, 2004b. For a critical view see Heinacher, 2004

    Google Scholar 

  133. See Rochlitz/ Winkler, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  134. See Bundesrat, 2004, for an illustration on just how deep into details the discussion goes.

    Google Scholar 

  135. See Cave, 2004, p. 27.

    Google Scholar 

  136. See Ruhle/ Lichtenberger/ Kittl, 2005, p. 127, for Austria; Scheurle, 2003, for Germany.

    Google Scholar 

  137. See Eberlein, 2001, p. 381.

    Google Scholar 

  138. See McKinsey, 2002, pp. 2 ff., highlighting the importance of lobbying within Deutsche Bahn.

    Google Scholar 

  139. See Commission of the European Communities, 2003, describing the timephasing of monopolies.

    Google Scholar 

  140. See Scheurle, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  141. See Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  142. See Neuscheler, 2005, p. 45; Jamison, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  143. See Wirtschaftsrat, 2003, p.3.

    Google Scholar 

  144. See Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  145. See Germis, 2004, p. 45.

    Google Scholar 

  146. See FAZ, 2004a, pp. 13–15.

    Google Scholar 

  147. See Keuter/ Waitschies, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  148. See FAZ, 2005c, p. 13; FAZ, 2005a, p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  149. See Neuhoff, 2005; Handelsblatt, 2005c, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  150. See Rochlitz/ Winkler, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  151. See Handelsblatt, 2005b, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  152. See Ilgmann, 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  153. See Tomik, 2002, pp. 41 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  154. See PSPC, 2004, pp. 51 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  155. See Héritier, 2001b, pp. 7 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  156. See Rochlitz, 2003; Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  157. See Gifford, 2003, pp. 471 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  158. See VATM, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  159. See Die Bahn, 2002b, p. 29. DB denies that long term contracts are signed in order to cut out the competition, but only to be able to make investments.

    Google Scholar 

  160. See FAZ, 2002a, p. 15.

    Google Scholar 

  161. See Schaaffkamp, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  162. See Werner et al., 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  163. See Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  164. See PSPC, 2004, pp. 16 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  165. See Scheerer/ Nonnast, 2005, p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  166. See Handelsblatt, 2005a, p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  167. See Lyon/ Huang, 2002, p. 112, point to the following order of actions in a regulated market: negotiation, conflict, regulation, then again negotiation.

    Google Scholar 

  168. See Pelkmans, 2001, p. 436, for an overview of the dynamic development of the EU liberalisation.

    Google Scholar 

  169. See Wegmann, 2001, pp. 50 ff., for this paradox

    Google Scholar 

  170. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  171. See Newbery, 2000, p. 141.

    Google Scholar 

  172. See OECD, 1998, p. 22.

    Google Scholar 

  173. See Ermert, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  174. See Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  175. See Wünschmann, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  176. See Héritier, 2001a, p. 28.

    Google Scholar 

  177. See Newbery, 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  178. See Canoy/ Bijl/ Kemp, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  179. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  180. See Heng, 2004b.

    Google Scholar 

  181. See FAZ, 2005g, p. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  182. See Michalowitz, 2004, pp. 17ff.

    Google Scholar 

  183. See Miller, 2003, pp. 76 ff., for examples in the rail sector; EON, 2005, for an example in the electricity market.

    Google Scholar 

  184. See Neuhoff, 2003; Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  185. See Cassel, 2001, p. 112.

    Google Scholar 

  186. See Evans/ Fingleton, 2002, p. 15; Strauch, 1993, p. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  187. See Althaus, 2004, p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  188. See Strauch, 1993, pp. 147 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  189. See Schönborn/ Wiebusch, 2002, p. VIII.

    Google Scholar 

  190. This paragraph builds on Putz & Partner, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  191. See Baethge/ Hübner, 2004, for an overview of the efficiency of the German lobby-associations in general.

    Google Scholar 

  192. See Schönborn/ Wiebusch, 2002, pp. 93 ff., for a specific example of a campaign run by the internet-provider AOL.

    Google Scholar 

  193. See Rochlitz, 2005, for the difference between personal and institutional influence with examples.

    Google Scholar 

  194. See Werner, 2002; Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  195. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  196. See Epstein/ Nitzan, 2005, pp. 15 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  197. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  198. See Althaus, 2004, p. 7; Putz & Partner, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  199. See Freytag, 1998; Soltwedel et al., 1986, pp. 284 ff.; Becker, 1983 and 1985; Fockenbrock, 2005, p. 24, on the explicit example of DT.

    Google Scholar 

  200. See Strauch, 1993, p. 8; Schönborn/ Wiebusch, 2002, p. 11. For a critical view see Grass, 2005, who states that lobbying as such is a danger for society.

    Google Scholar 

  201. See Glachant, 2002, p. 297.

    Google Scholar 

  202. See Stigler, 1971.

    Google Scholar 

  203. See Knieps, 2004, pp. 18 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  204. For both markets examples of the misuse of power in connection with essential facilities exist. For the telecommunications market see VATM, 2001. For the rail market see Mehr Bahnen, 2003 and 2005; McKinsey, 2002. Kirchner, 2003 and 2004 list all the theoretical market barriers for rail markets and structure them.

    Google Scholar 

  205. See Heinen, 2001; Peltzman/ Winston, 2000; Vogelsang, 2002; Wissenschaftlicher Beirat beim Bundesminister für Verkehr, 2002. See PSPC, 2004, for a listing of the essential facilities in the German rail market.

    Google Scholar 

  206. See Engel, 2002b.

    Google Scholar 

  207. See Bijl/ Peitz, 2002, p. 243.

    Google Scholar 

  208. See Scheurle, 2003; Heinrichs, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  209. See Shapiro/ Varian, 1999, p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  210. See Die Bahn, 2004, p. 17, for the point of view of an incumbent on essential facilities in the rail sector.

    Google Scholar 

  211. See Kirchner, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  212. See Freytag/ Winkler, 2003; Ewers/ Ilgmann, 2001a, p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  213. See Rochlitz, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  214. See Knieps/ Brunekreeft, 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  215. See Monopolkommission, 2004a; RegTP, 2003b.

    Google Scholar 

  216. See Vanberg, 2002, pp. 8 ff., for the details of this case.

    Google Scholar 

  217. See Die Bahn, 2004, pp. 34 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  218. See Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  219. See Die Bahn, 2002b, pp. 31 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  220. See Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  221. See Schweinsberg, 2002, for a listing of the different cases. 75% of those revolve around issues of access.

    Google Scholar 

  222. See Heinrichs, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  223. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Heinrichs, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  224. See Krummheuer, 2005a, p. 17.

    Google Scholar 

  225. See FAZ, 2003b, p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  226. See Die Bahn, 2004, pp. 34 ff., for a discussion of these ‘extra-services’.

    Google Scholar 

  227. See Petersdorff, 2005, p. 33.

    Google Scholar 

  228. See RegTP, 2002, for this case.

    Google Scholar 

  229. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  230. See Die Bahn, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  231. See Scheurle, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  232. See Berke, 2005, p. 10.

    Google Scholar 

  233. See Winkler/ Rochlitz, 2005; BDI, 2005, pp. 8 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  234. See Die Bahn, 2002b, p. 7. Even the incumbent DB admits that the crucial characteristic of a competitive market is the open access to it. Obviously, different actors have different ideas as to what ‘open’ means.

    Google Scholar 

  235. See OECD, 1998, pp. 7 ff., for the theoretical discussion on alternative models of ownership and control in the rail transport markets and an extensive overview of 15 countries. Here only the German and the UK market will be considered in greater detail. For a critical view that the separation has a positive effect on regulatory reform, see Friebel/ Ivaldi/ Vibes, 2004, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  236. See PSPC, 2004, pp. 46 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  237. See Knieps, 2004, p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  238. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Die Bahn, 2002b.

    Google Scholar 

  239. See Hirschhausen/ Siegmann, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  240. See Lavender, 2005. In the telecommunications market the incumbent BT is (in 2005) about to set up a separate ‘Access Service Division’ with its own headquarters and brand but which will remain part of BT.

    Google Scholar 

  241. See Böhmer/ Schnitzler, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  242. See Die Bahn, 2004, pp. 20 ff.; Die Bahn, 2005b, p. 39. The incumbent DB is obviously against such an approach and voices its opposition loudly.

    Google Scholar 

  243. See NZZ, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  244. See for the current discussion Allianz pro Schiene, 2004; FDP, 2004; Ewers/ Ilgmann, 2001b; BDI, 2005, pp. 8 ff; FAZ, 2004c.

    Google Scholar 

  245. See Ewers/ Ilgmann, 2001a, p. 6. They look at the pricing system of Deutsche Bahn, which discriminates between the competitors: not so much on pricing issues but on quality aspects. These are the issues that are hard to prove and can be extremely disturbing as they cause cost in terms of time and legal expenses.

    Google Scholar 

  246. See Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  247. See Köster, 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  248. See Siedenbiel, 2003, p. 78. Connex took one of its main lines in Germany out of service, because the level of usage dropped. One of the reasons for the end of the service was the lack of connection with the incumbent’s trains.

    Google Scholar 

  249. See Schintler et al., 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  250. See Scheurle, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  251. See Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Arbeit, 2003; Schäfer, 2003, gives a detailed telecommunications market overview from the perspective of the consumers.

    Google Scholar 

  252. See Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  253. See Neuhoff, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  254. See FAZ, 2005h, for a listing of the TOP 100 companies in Germany.

    Google Scholar 

  255. See A.T. Kearney, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  256. See Hirschfeld, 2003; FAZ, 2005e, p. 19.

    Google Scholar 

  257. See Wünschmann, 2005; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  258. Die Bahn, 2004, p. 1, points to the complexity of the day to day work in respect to the changes necessary when working with many new, small companies — a process which is caused and controlled by regulation.

    Google Scholar 

  259. See Höckels/ Rottenbiller, 2003. The incumbent feels discriminated against in terms of his ability to introduce innovative products.

    Google Scholar 

  260. See Balsen, 2005, p. 10.

    Google Scholar 

  261. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Wünschmann, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  262. See Frühbrodt, 2002a p. 15.

    Google Scholar 

  263. See Monopolkommission, 2004b. See Pergande, 2004, p. 18, for an example of such a product variation.

    Google Scholar 

  264. See Schütz, 2005a, p. 166.

    Google Scholar 

  265. See IRG, 2005, for an international overview of the concept of reciprocity.

    Google Scholar 

  266. See Ruhle/ Lichtenberger/ Kittl, 2005, p. 10, who describe that the concept of reciprocity is also seen as a basis of the economic liberalisation principles in Austria.

    Google Scholar 

  267. See RegTP, 2003a.

    Google Scholar 

  268. See Williamson, 1993, pp. 45 ff. Neumann, 2004, p. 3, discusses reciprocity as a (necessary) part of a consistent pricing regime.

    Google Scholar 

  269. See Commission of the European Communities, 2005a.

    Google Scholar 

  270. See FAZ, 2005d, p. 13, for a description of the same effect in the rail sector.

    Google Scholar 

  271. See Rochlitz, 2003; Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  272. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003; Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  273. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  274. See Winkler, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  275. See Tele2, 2005, pp. 27 ff., for this example.

    Google Scholar 

  276. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  277. See Rochlitz, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  278. See Heinrichs, 2004; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  279. See Stoffels, 2004, p. 6, who describes that in practice the incumbent can even use the non-discrimination clause against the new operators, when he is not willing to give access to a new product or price.

    Google Scholar 

  280. See Riedel, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  281. See Wendel, 2004, on the internal problem within DT of implementing this reform. See Tartler, 2005, for an example of DB trying to keep up the propaganda; Neuhoff, 2003; Heinrichs, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  282. See Armstrong, 1998; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  283. See Grabitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  284. See Wünschmann, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  285. See Scheurle, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  286. See Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  287. See Arnback, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  288. See Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  289. See Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003; Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  290. See Michalowitz, 2004, pp. 229 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  291. See Märker/ Trénel, 2003, p. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  292. See VCD, 2004b.

    Google Scholar 

  293. See Köster, 1999, p. 168.

    Google Scholar 

  294. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Werner, 2002; Wünschmann, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  295. See Schneider, 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  296. See Engel, 2002b, p. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  297. See Heinrichs, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  298. See Rochlitz, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003; Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  299. See Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  300. See Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  301. See FAZ, 2003a, p. 11; Rochlitz, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  302. This case builds on Jahn/ Prüfer, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  303. See Donegan, 2005, p. 29, for more technical details.

    Google Scholar 

  304. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  305. See Engel, 2002b. See Bundesministerium für Verkehr, 2001; Wissenschaftlicher Beirat beim Bundesminister für Verkehr, 2002; Monopolkommission, 2004a; RegTP, 2002 and 2003b, for a description of the possible instruments.

    Google Scholar 

  306. See Scheurle, 2003; Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  307. See Kohlstedt, 2003b.

    Google Scholar 

  308. See Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  309. This case builds on Freytag/ Winkler, 2004. See Ritter, 2004, pp. 195 ff., for a detailed description on the genesis of the billing contract.

    Google Scholar 

  310. See Stüwe, 2004, p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  311. See Mechnig, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  312. See Deutsche Telekom, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  313. See VATM, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  314. See Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  315. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  316. See Schütz, 2005a, p. 170.

    Google Scholar 

  317. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  318. See Piepenbrock, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  319. See RegTP, 2004a, p. 769.

    Google Scholar 

  320. See Koenig/ Vogelsang/ Winkler, 2005, pp. 47 ff.; Bauer, 2004, p. 19.

    Google Scholar 

  321. See Koenig/ Vogelsang/ Winkler, 2005. pp. 32 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  322. See Koenig/ Vogelsang/ Winkler, 2005. They demonstrate that even when the so-called market analysis for this market is concluded by all EU member states, the national regulators will decide how they interfere in the markets.

    Google Scholar 

  323. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  324. See Rochlitz, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  325. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003

    Google Scholar 

  326. See McKinsey, 2002, for a ‘blueprint’ on negotiation strategies of an incumbent in a network market.

    Google Scholar 

  327. See RegTP, 2002 and 2003; Monopolkommission, 2004b, for cases in the telecommunications markets. See Schweinsberg, 2002, p. 16, for cases in the rail sector.

    Google Scholar 

  328. See Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003; Heinrichs, 2003; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  329. See Die Bahn, 2002b–2005b; Mehr Bahnen, 2003; VATM, 2001 and 2002, for typical position papers which represent this style.

    Google Scholar 

  330. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Heinrichs, 2003; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  331. See Schütz, 2005a, pp. 166 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  332. See RegTP, 2004. This is obviously not the case for all circumstances, as for example RegTP publishes a project plan every year.

    Google Scholar 

  333. See Schütz, 2005a, pp. 178 ff., for a definition of MVNO; Bieler, 2005, for the market situation of MVNOs in Germany.

    Google Scholar 

  334. See Kruse, 1992, p. 4, for a discussion on scarcity of frequencies.

    Google Scholar 

  335. See Bornshten/ Schjter, 2003, for an international overview.

    Google Scholar 

  336. See Cullen International, 2005, table 29.

    Google Scholar 

  337. See Tele2, 2005, pp. 15 ff., for an example of such an MVNO.

    Google Scholar 

  338. See Deutscher Bundestag, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  339. See Spiller, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  340. See Wirtschaftsrat, 2004, p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  341. See Frost&Sullivan, 2004, for an international overview of how this issue is handled differently (based on individual situations) in the different countries.

    Google Scholar 

  342. See Heinrichs, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  343. See Die Bahn, 2005b, pp. 34 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  344. See Kirchner, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  345. See Miller, 2003, pp. 170 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  346. See Scheurle, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003; Werner, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  347. See Rochlitz, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  348. See TK-dialog, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  349. See Scheurle, 2003, for this specific example. See Poel, 2002, for an overview of all such associations that exist internationally; Kohlstedt, 2003a, gives an overview of the AKNN; Bruce/ Marriottt, 2002, p. 52, present the ACIF as an international example of how such associations can develop to become a support mechanism for all actors.

    Google Scholar 

  350. See Drahos, 2003, p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  351. See Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Arbeit, 2003, for an example of such a benchmark produced on a regular basis in Germany by the federal ministry of economics.

    Google Scholar 

  352. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  353. See Vogelsang, 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  354. See Schütz, 2005b, p. VI.

    Google Scholar 

  355. See Schmidt/ Winkelhage, 2005, p. 13; Telekom-Control-Kommission, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  356. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  357. See VATM, 2003, pp. 1 ff., as a demonstration that the VATM in Germany seems to have made a leap forward by moving from the ‘regulatoryassociation’ to a association that moves forward on (innovative) contents.

    Google Scholar 

  358. See Newbery, 2000; Pelkmans, 2001, p. 455; Bundesregierung, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  359. See Piepenbrock, 2004. He highlights the fact that conflicts do not disembogue into regulatory cases because of the contents, but because negotiations never take place.

    Google Scholar 

  360. See Engel, 2002b, for a description of how negotiations are run in network markets.

    Google Scholar 

  361. See Die Bahn, 2002b–2005b.

    Google Scholar 

  362. See Die Bahn, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  363. See Die Bahn, 2004, p. 31.

    Google Scholar 

  364. See Die Bahn, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  365. See RegTP, 2005b.

    Google Scholar 

  366. See Kirchner, 2002, for background and case; Neumann, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  367. See Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  368. See Rochlitz, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  369. See Böhmer/ Delhaes, 2004, p. 62; Ott, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  370. See Krummheuer, 2005b, p. 17. “There is no peace between DB and Connex, because there was no war — only competition and our effort to gain fair access to infrastructure.” Own translation from German to English.

    Google Scholar 

  371. See Wünschmann, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  372. See Heng, 2004a, demonstrating that in the mobile telecommunications sector cooperation between some groups of operators and non-cooperation between others is executed at the same time.

    Google Scholar 

  373. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Röthig, 2002; FAZ, 2002b, p. 67.

    Google Scholar 

  374. See Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  375. See Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  376. See FAZ, 2005b, p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  377. See Die Bahn, 2002a, p. 21; Heng, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  378. See Die Bahn, 2004, pp. 23 ff. The incumbent DB describes here the cases that were handled by the EBA in the past year. In describing some of the cases DB tries to show that the reproaches of misuse of power were not conscious moves of Deutsche Bahn. See Die Bahn, 2003, p. 20 and Die Bahn, 2002b, pp. 15 ff., for a complete listing of the EBA cases from 2000–2002. DB differentiates between different classes of misuses and even comes to the conclusion that there are quite a few cases where the incumbent hurt himself the most, to make way for his competitors.

    Google Scholar 

  379. See Die Bahn, 2002b, p. 1, where the incumbent DB points to the fact that transparency is of importance in getting rid of strategic games.

    Google Scholar 

  380. See Die Bahn, 2002a, p. 21. Here it is openly stated that using the market power is seen as a promising strategy. But probably not even DB would consider this to be a fair strategy.

    Google Scholar 

  381. See Werner, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  382. See Axelrod, 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  383. See Tele2, 2005, pp. 13 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  384. See Vogelsang, 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  385. See Dialog Consult/ VATM, 2004. See Schmidt, 2004, for an opposing opinion.

    Google Scholar 

  386. See Höckels/ Rottenbiller, 2003, for the opinion of the incumbent. 400 See Essig, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  387. See Balsen, 2004, p. 9.

    Google Scholar 

  388. See Rochlitz, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  389. See Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  390. See Niemeier, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  391. See Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  392. See TK-dialog, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  393. See McKinsey, 2002; Die Bahn, 2002a.

    Google Scholar 

  394. See Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  395. See Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Arbeit, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  396. See Tele2, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  397. See Scheurle, 2003; Armstrong, 1998; Ypsilanti/ Xavier, 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  398. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Neuhoff, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  399. See Elixmann/ Schäfer/ Schwab, 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  400. See Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  401. See Schütz, 2005a, pp. 166 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  402. See Frieden, 2004, for the example of MCI.

    Google Scholar 

  403. See Schmidt, 2005a, p. 14, demonstrating that it seems to be common knowledge that the actors play foul.

    Google Scholar 

  404. See Hirschfeld, 2003; Heinrichs, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  405. See Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  406. See Michalowitz, 2004, pp. 269 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  407. See Schwerhoff, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  408. See Heinrichs, 2004; Scheurle, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  409. See Rochlitz, 2003; Hirschfeld, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  410. See Ritter, 2004, p. 125. She states that this applies to the situation in the German telecommunications market.

    Google Scholar 

  411. See Schelling, 1957.

    Google Scholar 

  412. Take the example of the German market, where Arcor, the second largest telecommunications operator, was originally founded on the basis of the telecommunications network from Deutsche Bahn. The existence of telecommunications networks in the rail sector is based on the need for high quality information networks. For more details on these networks see Matthies/ Schinkel, 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  413. See Miller, 2003, p. 170; Die Bahn, 2004, explicitly puts the different networkmarkets telecommunication and rail into a context where one market can learn from the lessons of the other.

    Google Scholar 

  414. For a critical view see McKinsey, 2002, p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  415. See Rochlitz/ Winkler, 2005; Neuscheler, 2005, p. 45; Bötsch, 2005, p. 13; Schütz, 2005c; Bundesrat, 2005; FAZ, 2005f, p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2006 Physica-Verlag Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2006). Negotiations in network markets. In: Negotiations with Asymmetrical Distribution of Power. Contributions to Economics. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/3-7908-1744-9_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics