Advertisement

The Political Economy of the Allocation of State Government Expenditures for the Industrial Sector

  • Atsushi KatoEmail author
  • Atsushi Fukumi
Chapter
  • 3 Downloads
Part of the India Studies in Business and Economics book series (ISBE)

Abstract

We investigate why some governments do not institute public policy conducive to industrialization from the viewpoint of the balance of political power between the agricultural and industrial sectors. More specifically, we examine whether a higher rural Gini coefficient—a proxy for the degree of political power of rural elites—tends to reduce the allocation of development expenditures favorable to the industrial sector at the state level in India. Our estimation results suggest that both the rural Gini coefficient and the rural population share have significant negative coefficients. These results imply that the political influence of the agricultural sector can limit the allocation of expenditures conducive to industrialization, resulting in the stagnation of regional state economies.

Keywords

Political economy Political power Gini coefficient Development expenditure Development capital expenditure 

JEL Classification No

D7 H72 H76 O14 

References

  1. Ahlwalia, M. S. (2000). Economic performance of states in post-reform period. Economic and Political Weekly, 35, 1637–1648.Google Scholar
  2. Aiyar, S. (2001). Growth theory and convergence across Indian States: A panel study. In: T. Calen et al., eds., India at Crossroads: Sustaining Growth and Reducing Poverty. International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  3. Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 651–678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Alesina, A., Baqir, R., & Easterly, W. (1999). Public goods and ethnic divisions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 1243–1284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Alesina, A., & Roubini, N. (with Gerald D. Cohen). (1999). Political cycles and the macroeconomy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  6. A, G. A., & Verba, S. (1963). The civic culture: political attitudes and democracy in five nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  7. Bajpai, N., & Sachs, J. D. (1999). The progress of policy reform and variations in performance at the sub-national level in India. Development Discussion Paper No. 730, Harvard Institute for International Development.Google Scholar
  8. Banerjee, A. (2001). Comment. (on Karla Hoff and Joseph E. Stiglitz “Modern economic theory and development.”) In: G. M. Meier & J. E. Stiglitz, (Eds.), Frontiers of development economics: The future in perspective (pp. 464–477). New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Banerjee, A., & Somanathan, R. (2007). The political economy of public goods: Some evidence from India. Journal of Development Economics, 82, 287–314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Banerjee, A., Gertler, P., & Ghatak, M. (2002). Empowerment and efficiency: Tenancy program in West Bengal. Journal of Political Economy, 110(2), 239–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Bardhan, P. (1984). The political economy of development in India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  12. Baru, S. (2000). Economic policy and the development of capitalism in India: The role of regional capitalists and political parties. In F. R. Frankel, et al. (Eds.), Transforming India: Social and political dynamics of democracy (pp. 207–230). New Delhi: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Beck, N., & Katz, J. N. (1995). What to do (not to do) with time-series cross-section data. American Political Science Review, 89(3), 634–647.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Besley, B., & Burgess, R. (2002). The political economy of government responsiveness: Theory and evidence from India. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1415–1451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Betancourt, R., & Gleason, S. (2000). The allocation of publicly-provided goods to rural households in India: On some consequences of caste, religion and democracy. World Development, 28(12), 2169–2182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Boix, C. (1997). Political parties and the supply side of the economy: the provision of physical and human capital in advanced economies, 1960–1990. American Journal of Political Science, 41(3), 814–845.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2000). Geography, international trade, and political mobilization in U.S. industry. American Journal of Political Science, 44(4), 720–732.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Chandra, K. (2004). Why ethnic parties succeed: Patronage and ethnic headcounts in India. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Chhibber, P., & Nooruddin, Irfan. (2004). Do party systems count? The number of parties and government performance in the Indian States. Comparative Political Studies, 37(2), 152–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Dahl, R. (1961). Who governs? Democracy and power in an American City. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  21. Dahl, R. (1991). Modern political analysis (5th ed.). Englewood Cliffs: New Jersey, Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
  22. De Mesquita, B. B., Smith, A., Morrow, J. D., & Siverson, R. M. (2003). The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  23. Evans, P., Dietrich, R., & Theda, S. (1985). Bringing the state back in. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Finger, J. M., Hall, H. K., & Nelson, D. R. (1982). The political economy of administered protection. American Economic Review, 72(3), 452–466.Google Scholar
  25. Frankel, F., & Rao, M. S. A. (1987). Dominance and state power in modern India. Delhi, India: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  26. Franzese, R. J., Jr. (2002). Electoral and partisan cycles in economic policies and outcomes. Annual Reviews of Political Science, 5, 369–421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Gaur, A. K. (2010). Regional disparities in economic growth: A case study of Indian States. Paper prepared for the 31st Conference of the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth.Google Scholar
  28. Gawande, K., & Bandyopadhyay, U. (2000). Is protection for sale? Evidence of the Grossman-Helpman theory of endogenous protection. Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(1), 139–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Goldberg, P. K., & Maggi, G. (1999). Protection for sale: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 98(5), 1135–1155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2001). Special interest politics. MIT Press.Google Scholar
  31. Iarossi, G. (2009). The investment climate in 16 Indian states. Policy Research Working Paper No. 4817. The World Bank.Google Scholar
  32. Irwin, D. A. (1996). Industry or class cleavages over trade policy? Evidence from the british general election of 1923. In R. C. Freenstra, G. M. Grossman, & D. A. Irwin (Eds.), The political economy of trade theory: Essays in honor of Jagdish Bhagwati (pp. 53–76). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  33. Irwin, D. A., & Kroszner, R. (1999). Interests, institutions, and ideology in securing policy change: The republican conversion to trade liberalization after Smoot-Hawley. Journal of Law and Economics, 42, 643–673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Jenkins, R. (2004). Introduction. In R. Jenkins (Ed.), Regional reflections: Comparing politics across India’s states. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  35. Kennedy, L., Kim, R., & Diego, Z. (2013). Comparing state-level policy responses to economic reforms in India. Economie Politique de l’Asie (1).Google Scholar
  36. Kitschelt, H., & Wilkinson, S. (2007). Patrons, clients, and policies. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  37. Kolhi, A. (1987). The state and poverty in India. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  38. Kolhi, A. (2009a). Parliamentary communism and agrarian reform: The evidence from India’s Bengal. In: Kohli, A. Democracy and development in India. Delhi, India: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  39. Kolhi, A. (2009b). “Karnataka’s land reforms: A model for India?” In: Atul Kohli, Democracy and development in India. Delhi, India: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  40. Lee, J.-W., & Swagel, P. (1997). Trade barriers and trade flows across countries and industries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(3), 373–382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Magee, S. (1980). Three simple tests of Stolper-Samuelson theorem. In P. Oppenheimer (Ed.), Issues in international economics (pp. 138–153). London: Oriel Press.Google Scholar
  42. Marjit, S., Sasmal, J., & Sasmal, R. (2013). Distributive politics, public expenditure and economic growth: experience from the Indian states. Manuscript. http://dial2013.dauphine.fr/fileadmin/mediatheque/dial2013/documents/Papers/78_Inde_Sasmal.pdf.
  43. Mills, W. (1956): The power elite. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  44. Mukherjee, S., & Chakraborty, D. (2010). Is there any relationship between economic growth and human development? Evidence from Indian States. MPRA Paper No. 22997.Google Scholar
  45. Nagaraj, R., Varoudakis, A., Varoudakis, M. A. (2000). Long-run growth trends and convergence across Indian States. OECD Development Centre Working Paper 131.Google Scholar
  46. Nayyar, G. (2008). Economic growth and regional inequality in India. Economic and Political Weekly, February 9, 2008.Google Scholar
  47. Nordhaus, W. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 160–190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Nooruddin, I., & Chhibber, P. (2008). Unstable politics: Fiscal space and electoral volatility in the Indian states. Comparative Political Studies, 41(8), 1069–1091.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Olson, M. Jr. (1965). The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  50. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: Explaining economic policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  51. Persson, T., Tabellini, G., & Trebbi, F. (2003). Electoral rules and corruption. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(4), 958–989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Pincus, S. (2009). 1688: The first modern revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  53. Reserve Bank of India (2010). State finances: A study of budgets of 2009–10. Reserve Bank of India.Google Scholar
  54. Robinson, J. (2009). Industry policy and development: A political economy perspective. Paper prepared for the 2009 World Bank ABCDE conference in Seoul June (pp. 22–24).Google Scholar
  55. Rodrik, D. (2005). Growth strategies. In P. Aghion & Steven N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. A1, pp. 967–1014). Amsterdam, the Netherlands: Elsevier. (Chapter 14).Google Scholar
  56. Rodrik, D. (2007). One economics many recipes: Globalization, institutions, and economic growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  57. Rogowski, R. (1989). Commerce and coalitions: How trade affects domestic political alignments. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  58. Rudolph, S., & Rudolph, L. (1987). In pursuit of Lakshmi: The political economy of the Indian state. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  59. Saez, L., & Sinha, A. (2009). Political cycles, political institutions and public expenditure in India, 1980–2000. British Journal of Political Science, 40, 91–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Sinha, A. (2005). The regional roots of development politics in India: A divided leviathan. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
  61. Trefler, D. (1993). Trade liberalization and the theory of endogenous protection: An econometric study of U.S. import policy. Journal of Political Economy, 101(1), 138–160.s.Google Scholar
  62. Trivedi, K. (2002). Regional convergence and catch-up in India between 1960 and 1992. Working Paper, Nuffield College, University of Oxford.Google Scholar
  63. World Bank (2006). India: Inclusive growth and service delivery: building on India’s success. Development Policy Review Report No. 34580-IN.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsWaseda UniversityTokyoJapan
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsUniversity of HyogoKobeJapan

Personalised recommendations