Advertisement

Production Technologies

  • Christopher J. O’Donnell
Chapter

Abstract

To explain variations in managerial performance, we need to know something about what can and cannot be produced using different production technologies. In this book, a production technology (or simply ‘technology’) is defined as a technique, method or system for transforming inputs into outputs. For most practical purposes, it is convenient to think of a technology as a book of instructions, or recipe. In this book, the set of technologies that exist in a given period is referred to as a technology set. If we think of a technology as a book of instructions, then we can think of a technology set as a library. The input-output combinations that are possible using different technologies can be represented by output sets, input sets and production possibilities sets. Under certain conditions, they can also be represented by distance, revenue, cost and profit functions. This chapter defines, and discusses the properties of, these different sets and functions.

References

  1. Badin L, Daraio C, Simar L (2012) How to measure the impact of environmental factors in a nonparametric production model. Eur J Oper Res 223(3):818–833CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Balk B (1998) Industrial price, quantity, and productivity indices: the micro-economic theory and an application. Kluwer Academic Publishers, BostonCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Caselli F, Coleman W (2006) The world technology frontier. Am Econ Rev 93(3):499–522CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Casu B, Ferrari A, Zhao T (2013) Regulatory reform and productivity change in Indian banking. Rev Econ Stat 95(3):1066–1077CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Chambers R, Quiggin J (2000) Uncertainty, production, choice and agency: the state-contingent approach. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  6. Chambers R, Chung Y, Färe R (1996) Benefit and distance functions. J Econ Theory 70:407–419CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Chambers R, Chung Y, Färe R (1998) Profit, directional distance functions, and Nerlovian efficiency. J Optim Theory Appl 98(2):351–364CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Coelli T, Rao D, O’Donnell C, Battese G (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis, 2nd edn. Springer, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  9. Cuesta R, Zofio J (2005) Hyperbolic efficiency and parametric distance functions: with application to Spanish savings banks. J Prod Anal 24(1):31–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Färe R, Grosskopf S (2000) Theory and application of directional distance functions. J Prod Anal 13(2000):93–103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Färe R, Primont D (1994) The unification of Ronald W. Shephard’s duality theory. J Econ 60(2):199–207CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Färe R, Primont D (1995) Multi-output production and duality: theory and applications. Kluwer Academic Publishers, BostonCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell C (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production. Kluwer Academic Publishers, BostonCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell C (1986) Scale economies and duality. J Econ 46(2):175–182CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell C, Yaisawarng S (1993) Derivation of shadow prices for undesirable outputs: a distance function approach. Rev Econ Stat 75(2):374–380CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Zaim O (2002) Hyperbolic efficiency and return to the dollar. Eur J Oper Res 136(3):671–679CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Fried H, Lovell CAK, Schmidt S (2008) Efficiency and productivity. In: Fried H, Lovell CAK, Schmidt S (eds) The measurement of productive efficiency and productivity growth. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 3–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Griliches Z (1987) Productivity: measurement problems. In: Eatwell J, Milgate M, Newman P (eds) The new Palgrave: a dictionary of economics, 1st edn. Palgrave Macmillan, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  19. Hsieh CT, Klenow P (2009) Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in China and India. Q J Econ 124(4):1403–1448CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Humphrey DB, Pulley LB (1997) Banks’ responses to deregulation: profits, technology, and efficiency. J Money Credit Bank 29(1):73–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Kumbhakar S (2006) Specification and estimation of nonstandard profit functions. Empir Econ 31(1):243–260CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Kumbhakar S, Lovell C (2000) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Lau L (1972) Profit functions of technologies with multiple inputs and outputs. Rev Econ Stat 54(3):281–289CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Luenberger D (1992) New optimality principles for economic efficiency and equilibrium. J Optim Theory Appl 75(2):221–264CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. O’Donnell C (2016) Using information about technologies, markets and firm behaviour to decompose a proper productivity index. J Econ 190(2):328–340CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. O’Donnell C, Rao D, Battese G (2008) Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios. Empir Econ 34(2):231–255CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. O’Donnell C, Fallah-Fini S, Triantis K (2017) Measuring and analysing productivity change in a metafrontier framework. J Prod Anal 47(2):117–128CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Rasmussen S (2003) Criteria for optimal production under uncertainty. The state-contingent approach. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 47(4):447–476CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Shephard R (1953) Cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  30. Shephard R (1970) The theory of cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  31. Solow R (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat 39(3):312–320CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of QueenslandBrisbaneAustralia

Personalised recommendations