Advertisement

Simulating Cooperation and Competition: Present State and Future Objectives

  • Ramzi Suleiman
Conference paper

Abstract

One hardly needs to argue that cooperation and competition constitute major components of most social interactions. Not surprisingly, then, that the study of these behaviors has occupied many scientists from the fields of biology, economy, sociology, political science, psychology and other disciplines of the behavioral sciences. Whereas no claim is made here in favor of any single approach, I argue that the application of game theory for studying minimal situations of cooperation and competition has proven quite beneficial.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Axelrod, R. (1980a) Effective choice in the Prisoner’s Dilemma. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution. 24, pp. 3–25.Google Scholar
  2. Axelrod, R. (1980b) More effective choice in the Prisoner’s Dilemma. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution. 24, pp. 379–403.Google Scholar
  3. Axelrod, R. (1981) The Emergence Of Cooperation among Egoists. In: The American political Science Review. 75, pp. 306–318.Google Scholar
  4. Axelrod, R. (1984) The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
  5. Axelrod, R. (1986) An evolutionary approach to norms. In: American Political Science Review. 80, pp. 1095–1111.Google Scholar
  6. Axelrod, R., and Hamilton, W.D. (1981) The evolution of cooperation. In: Science. 211, pp. 1390–1396.Google Scholar
  7. Austin, W.G., and Worchel, S. (1979) The Social Psychology of Intergroup Relations. Brooks/Cole, Monterey, CA.Google Scholar
  8. Behr, R.L. (1981) Nice guys finish last–sometimes. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution. 25, pp. 289–300.Google Scholar
  9. Bendor, J., and Mookherjee, D. (1987) Institutional structure and the logic of ongoing collective action. In: American Political Science Review 81, pp. 129–154.Google Scholar
  10. Bendor, D., Kramer, R.M., and Stout, S. (1991) “When in doubt… ”, cooperation in a noisy prisoner’s dilemma. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution. 35, pp. 691–719.Google Scholar
  11. Billig, M.G. (1976) Social Psychology and Intergroup Relations. Academic Press, London.Google Scholar
  12. Bornstein, G., Erev, I., and Rosen, O. (1990) Intergroup competition as a structural solution to social dilemmas. In: Social Behavior. 5, pp. 247–260.Google Scholar
  13. Bornstein, G. (1992) The free-rider problem in intergroup conflict over step-level and continuous public goods. In: Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 62 (4), pp. 597–606.Google Scholar
  14. Bornstein, G., and Ben-Yossef, M. (1994) Cooperation in intergroup and single-group social dilemmas. In: Journal of Experimental Social psychology. 30, pp. 52–67.Google Scholar
  15. Brahms, S. (1975) Game theory and politics. Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
  16. Conte, R., and Sichman, J.S. (in press) How to benefit from social dependence. In: Journal of Mathematical Sociology.Google Scholar
  17. Dawes, R.M. (1980) Social dilemmas. In: Annual Review of Psychology. 31, pp. 169–193.Google Scholar
  18. Dixit, A.K., and Nalibuff, B.J. (1992) Thinking Strategically. Norton and Company, New York.Google Scholar
  19. Ernst, A.M., and Spada, H. (1993) Modeling actors in a resource dilemma: a computerized social learning environment. In: Towne, D.M., de Jong, T., and Spada, H. eds. (1993) Simulation-Based Experimental Learning. Springer, Berlin, pp. 105–120Google Scholar
  20. Granovetter, M. (1978) Threshold models of collective behavior. In: American Journal of Sociology. 83, pp. 1420–1443.Google Scholar
  21. Hardin, G.R. (1968) The tragedy of the commons. In: Science. 162, pp. 1243–1248.Google Scholar
  22. Hardin, R. (1982) Collective Action. The John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.Google Scholar
  23. Hegselmann, R. (in press) Modeling social dynamics by cellular automata. In: Liebrand, W.B.G., Hegselmann, R., and Nowak, A. eds. (in press) Computer Modeling and the Study of Dynamic Social Processes. Sage Publications.Google Scholar
  24. Hirshleifer, J., and Martinez Coll, J.C. (1988) What strategies can support the evolutionary emergence of cooperation. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution. 32 (2), pp. 367–398.Google Scholar
  25. Kim, O., and Walker, M. (1984) The free rider problem: Experimental Evidence. In: Public Choice. 1984, 43, pp. 3–24.Google Scholar
  26. Kirchkamp, O. (1996) Spatial evolution of automata in the Prisoners’ Dilemma. This volume, pp. 307–??.Google Scholar
  27. Komorita, S.S., and Parks, C.D. (1995) Interpersonal relations: Mixed motive interaction. In: Annual Review of Psychology. 46, Pergamon Press, New York, pp. 183–207.Google Scholar
  28. Lipman, B.L. (1986) Cooperation among egoists in Prisoners’ Dilemma and Chicken games. In: Public Choice. 51, pp. 315–331.Google Scholar
  29. Lomborg, B. (1992) Game theory vs. multiple agents: the iterated prisoner’s dilemma. In: Castelfranchi, C., and Werner, E. eds. Artificial Social Systems. Springer -Verlag, pp. 69–93Google Scholar
  30. Lorberbaum, J. (1994) No strategy is evolutionary stable in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. In: Journal of Theoretical Biology. 168, pp. 117–130.Google Scholar
  31. Luce, R.D., and Raiffa, H. (1957) Games and decisions: Introduction and Critical Survey. John Wiley and Sons, New York.Google Scholar
  32. Macy, M.W. (1990) Learning theory and the logic of critical mass. In: American Sociological Review. 55, pp. 809–826.Google Scholar
  33. Macy, M.W. (1991 a) Chains of cooperation: Threshold effects in collective action. In: American Sociological Review. 56, pp. 730–747.Google Scholar
  34. Macy, M.W. (1991b) Learning to cooperate: stochastic and tacit collusion in social exchange. In: American Journal of Sociology. 97 (3), pp. 808–843.Google Scholar
  35. Marinoff, L. (1992) Maximizing expected utilities in the Prisoner’s Dilemma. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution. 36 (1), pp. 183–216.Google Scholar
  36. Marwell, G., Oliver, P.E., and Prahl, R. (1988) Social networks and collective action: a theory of the critical mass. III. In: American Journal of Sociology. 94 (3), pp. 502–534.Google Scholar
  37. Maynard Smith, J. (1976) Evolution and the theory of games. In: American Scientist. 64, pp. 41–45.Google Scholar
  38. Maynard Smith, J. (1982) Evolution and The Theory of Games. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Maynard Smith, J., and Price, G.R. (1973) The logic of animal conflict. In: Nature. 246 (2), pp. 15–18.Google Scholar
  40. Messick, D.M., and Brewer, M.B. (1983) Solving social dilemmas: A review. In: Wheeler, L., and Shaver, P. eds. Review of Personality and Social Psychology. Vol. 4. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, pp. 11–44Google Scholar
  41. Messick, D.M., Wilke, H.A.M., Brewer, M.B., Kramer, R.M., Zemke, P.E., and Luci, L. (1983) Individual adaptation and structural change as solutions to social dilemmas. In: Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 44, pp. 294–309.Google Scholar
  42. Messick, D.M., and Liebrand, W.B.G. (1995) Individual heuristics and the dynamics of cooperation in large groups. In: Psychological Review. 102 (1), pp. 131–145.Google Scholar
  43. Molander, P. (1985) The optimal level of generosity in a selfish, uncertain environment. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution. 29 (4), pp. 611–618.Google Scholar
  44. Mueller, U. (1987) Optimal retaliation for optimal cooperation. In: Journal of Conflict Resolution. 31 (4), pp. 692–724.Google Scholar
  45. Nowak, A., Szamrej, J., and Latané, B. (1990) From private attitude to public opinion: a dynamic theory of social impact. In: Psychological Review. 97 (3), pp. 362–374.Google Scholar
  46. Nowak, A., Latané, B., and Lewenstein, M. (1994) Social dilemmas exist in space. In: Schulz, U., Albers, W, and Mueller, U. eds. Social Dilemmas and Cooperation. Springer-Verlag, pp. 269–289Google Scholar
  47. Nowak, M.A., and May, R.M. (1992) Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. In: Nature. 395, pp. 826–829.Google Scholar
  48. Nowak, M.A., and May, R.M. (1993) The spatial dilemmas of evolution. In: International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos. 3, pp. 35–78.Google Scholar
  49. Oliver, P.E., and Marwell, G. (1988) The paradox of group size in collective action: a theory of the critical mass. In: American Sociological Review 53, pp. 1–8.Google Scholar
  50. Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
  51. Rapoport, A., and Guyer, M. (1966) A taxonomy of 2x2 games. In: General Systems. 11, pp. 203–214.Google Scholar
  52. Rutte, C.G., Wilke, H.A.M., and Messick, D.M. (1987) Scarcity and abundance caused by people or the environment as determinants of behavior in the resource dilemma. In: Journal of Experimental Social Psychology. 23, pp. 208–216.Google Scholar
  53. Sakoda, J.M. (1971) The checkerboard model of social interaction. In: Journal of Mathematical Sociology. 1, pp. 119–132.Google Scholar
  54. Schelling, Th.C. (1960) The Strategy of Conflict. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MS. Schelling, Th.C. (1969) Models of segregation. In: American Economic Review 59, pp. 488493.Google Scholar
  55. Schelling, Th.C. (1971) Dynamic models of segregation. In: Journal of Mathematical Sociology. 1, pp. 143–186.Google Scholar
  56. Suleiman, R., and Fischer, I. (in press) The evolution of cooperation in intrergroup conflict. In: Liebrand, W.B.G., and Messick, D.M. eds. (in press) Frontiers in Social Research. Springer-Verlag, Berlin.Google Scholar
  57. Yamagishi, T. (in press) Social dilemmas. To appear in Cook, K., Fine, G., and House, J. eds. Sociological Perspectives on Social Psychology.Google Scholar
  58. Takigawa, T., and Messick, D.M. (1993) Group size uncertainty in shared resource use. In: Japanese Psychological Research. 35 (4), pp. 193–203.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1996

Authors and Affiliations

  • Ramzi Suleiman
    • 1
  1. 1.Department of PsychologyUniversity of HaifaHaifaIsrael

Personalised recommendations