Advertisement

Why China Needs a Real Property Tax? Empirical Evidence

  • Yilin Hou
Chapter
Part of the Politics and Development of Contemporary China book series (PDCC)

Abstract

This chapter elaborates on why a real property tax is necessary, given that the real estate sector has become so strong in the country. If our answer to why China should adopt a local real property tax is “yes,” then what are the rationales? Since at least 2003, the academic and policy communities in China have debated this question without achieving consensus. This chapter offers an empirical analysis of the tremendous inequity and inefficiency of the current scheme of education finance in the absence of a local property tax. The analysis uses capitalization data of basic education and is based on micro-level housing data in central Beijing that illustrates how the differential treatment of tiered schools, coupled with school attendance by rigid proximity plus the household registration system, is the root cause of these problems.

References

  1. Black, S. E. (1999). Do better school matters? Parental valuation of elementary education. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(2), 577–599.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bogart, W. T., & Cromwell, B. A. (1997). How much more is a good school worth? National Tax Journal, 50(2), 215–232.Google Scholar
  3. Brunner, E. J., & Sonstelie, J. (2003). Homeowners, property values, and the political economy of the school voucher. Journal of Urban Economics, 54(2), 239–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Brunner, E. J., Cho, S. W., & Reback, R. (2012). Mobility, housing markets, and schools: Estimating the effects of inter-district choice programs. Journal of Public Economics, 96(7), 604–614.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Chakrabarti, R., & Roy, J. (2015). Housing markets and residential segregation: Impacts of the Michigan school finance reform on inter-and intra-district sorting. Journal of Public Economics, 122, 110–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Chin, H. C., & Foong, K. W. (2006). Influence of school accessibility on housing values. Journal of Urban Planning and Development, 132(3), 120–129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Dee, T. S. (2000). The capitalization of education finance reforms. Journal of Law and Economics, 43(1), 185–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Dhar, P., & Ross, S. L. (2012). School district quality and property values: Examining differences along school district boundaries. Journal of Urban Economics, 71(1), 18–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Feng, H., & Lu, M. (2010). Entering school by buying house: An empirical research from Shanghai. Journal of World Economy (in Chinese), 12, 89–104.Google Scholar
  10. George, H. (1879). Progress and poverty: An inquiry into the cause of industrial depressions and of increase of want with increase of wealth. The Remedy Aziloth Books, 2016.Google Scholar
  11. Hou, Y. L., & Ma, H. T. (2016). China’s local property tax: Principles of design and strategies for implementation. Public Finance Research 《财政研究》, 2016(2), 65–78.Google Scholar
  12. Hou, Y. L., Ren, Q., & Ma, H. T. (2014, August 20–23). Testing the capitalization theory in a transitional economy: Education quality and property value in urban China. Paper presented at the annual conference of the International Institute of Public Finance (IIPF), Lugano.Google Scholar
  13. Hou, Y. L., Ren, Q., & Ma, H. T. (2015, November 11–14). Imposed school tiers, attendance by home proximity, and property value: Evidence from China. Paper presented at the annual conference of the National Tax Association, Boston.Google Scholar
  14. Leech, D., & Campos, E. (2003). Is comprehensive education really free? A case study of the effects of secondary school admissions policies on house prices in one local area. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society), 166(1), 135–154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Nguyen-Hoang, P., & Yinger, J. (2011). The capitalization of school quality into house values: A review. Journal of Housing Economics, 20(1), 30–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Oates, W. E. (1969). The effects of property taxes and local public spending on property values: An empirical study of tax capitalization and the Tiebout hypothesis. Journal of Political Economy, 77(6), 957–971.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Reback, R. (2005). House prices and the provision of local public services: Capitalization under school choice programs. Journal of Urban Economics, 57(2), 275–301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Ren, Q., Hou, Y. L., & Ma, H. T. (2017). Public service capitalization and real property value: The case for a local property tax in China. Economics of Finance and Trade (in Chinese), 12, 21–35.Google Scholar
  19. Ross, S., & Yinger, J. (1999). Sorting and voting: A review of the literature on urban public finance. In P. Cheshire & S. M. Edwin (Eds.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 3, pp. 2001–2060). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  20. Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Zheng, S. Q., & Kahn, M. E. (2008). Land and residential property markets in a booming economy: New evidence from Beijing. Journal of Urban Economics, 63(2), 743–757.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Zheng, S. Q., Hu, W. Y., & Wang, R. (2016). How much is a good school worth in Beijing? Identifying price premium with paired resale and rental data. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 53(2), 184–199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  • Yilin Hou
    • 1
  1. 1.The Maxwell SchoolSyracuse UniversitySyracuseUSA

Personalised recommendations