Advertisement

Introduction

  • Nichole Torpey-Saboe
Chapter

Abstract

This chapter discusses why education inequality matters, both from the perspective of human rights and that of economic development. While there has been much focus on income inequality, education inequality is important as it signifies disparity in opportunities. Access to education has been recognized as a human right and is critical to the realization of other rights, such as health, legal protections, political participation, and so on. Moreover, when large portions of society lag behind in education, this constrains overall economic growth and development. Yet, despite wide recognition of the importance of education, there is large variation between countries in the scope of educational opportunity—well beyond what would be expected according to GDP. Some poor countries provide education very broadly, while in some rich countries, significant parts of the population are excluded from education.

References

  1. Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, political instability, and investment. European Economic Review, 40(6), 1203–1228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Anand, S., & Kanbur, S. R. (1993). The Kuznets process and the inequality—Development relationship. Journal of Development Economics, 40(1), 25–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Atkinson, A. B., & Bourguignon, F. (2000). Introduction: Income distribution and economics. Handbook of Income Distribution, 1, 1–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Barro, R. J. (2000). Inequality and growth in a panel of countries. Journal of Economic Growth, 5(1), 5–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Bartels, L. M. (2008). Unequal democracy: The political economy of the new gilded age. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  7. Becker, G. S. (1994). Human capital revisited. InHuman capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education (3rd ed., pp. 15–28). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  8. Becker, G. S., Murphy, K. M., & Tamura, R. (1990). Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5, Part 2), S12–S37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Boix, C. (2010). Origins and persistence of economic inequality. Annual Review of Political Science, 13, 489–516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Brown, D. S., & Hunter, W. (1999). Democracy and social spending in Latin America, 1980–92. American Political Science Review, 93(4), 779–790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Brown, D. S., & Hunter, W. (2004). Democracy and human capital formation: Education spending in Latin America, 1980 to 1997. Comparative Political Studies, 37(7), 842–864.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Cardoso, F. H., & Faletto, E. (1979). Dependency and development in Latin America (Dependencia y desarrollo en América Latina, engl.). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  13. Cleland, J. G., & Van Ginneken, J. K. (1988). Maternal education and child survival in developing countries: The search for pathways of influence. Social Science & Medicine, 27(12), 1357–1368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Dabla-Norris, M. E., Kochhar, M. K., Suphaphiphat, M. N., Ricka, M. F., & Tsounta, E. (2015). Causes and consequences of income inequality: A global perspective. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
  15. Denison, E. F. (1962). The sources of economic growth in the US and the alternatives before us. New York: Committee for Economic Development.Google Scholar
  16. Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
  17. Galbraith, J. K., & Kum, H. (2005). Estimating the inequality of household incomes: A statistical approach to the creation of a dense and consistent global data set. Review of Income and Wealth, 51(1), 115–143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Gift, T., & Wibbels, E. (2014). Reading, writing, and the regrettable status of education research in comparative politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 17, 291–312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Grossman, M. (2006). Education and nonmarket outcomes. Handbook of the Economics of Education, 1, 577–633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Hibbs, D. A. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Political Science Review, 71(4), 1467–1487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Huber, E., & Stephens, J. D. (2001). Development and crisis of the welfare state: Parties and policies in global markets. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Huntington, S. P. (1993). The third wave: Democratization in the late twentieth century (Vol. 4). Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press.Google Scholar
  23. Inglehart, R., & Welzel, C. (2005). Modernization, cultural change, and democracy: The human development sequence. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Jejeebhoy, S. J. (1995). Women’s education, autonomy, and reproductive behaviour: Experience from developing countries. OUP Catalogue, Oxford University Press, Number 9780198290339.Google Scholar
  25. Kaufman, R. R., & Segura-Ubiergo, A. (2001). Globalization, domestic politics, and social spending in Latin America: A time-series cross-section analysis, 1973–97. World Politics, 53(4), 553–587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Kawachi, I., Kennedy, B. P., Lochner, K., & Prothrow-Stith, D. (1997). Social capital, income inequality, and mortality. American Journal of Public Health, 87(9), 1491–1498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality. The American Economic Review, 45(1), 1–28.Google Scholar
  28. Lake, D. A., & Baum, M. A. (2001). The invisible hand of democracy: Political control and the provision of public services. Comparative Political Studies, 34(6), 587–621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Li, H., Squire, L., & Zou, H. F. (1998). Explaining international and intertemporal variations in income inequality. The Economic Journal, 108(446), 26–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Lipset, S. M. (1960). Political man: The social basis of modern politics. Garden City, NY: Doubleday and Company.Google Scholar
  31. Muller, E. N. (1985). Income inequality, regime repressiveness, and political violence. American Sociological Review, 50, 47–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. North, D. C. (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 97–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Olson, M. (1991). Autocracy, democracy, and prosperity. Strategy and Choice, 131(157), 131–157.Google Scholar
  34. Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Przeworski, A., Limongi, F., & Giner, S. (1995). Political regimes and economic growth. InDemocracy and development (pp. 3–27). London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Psacharopoulos, G. (1985). Returns to education: A further international update and implications. Journal of Human Resources, 20, 583–604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Psacharopoulos, G. (1994). Returns to investment in education: A global update. World Development, 22(9), 1325–1343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Psacharopoulos, G., & Patrinos*, H. A. (2004). Returns to investment in education: A further update. Education Economics, 12(2), 111–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Rodrik, D. (1997). Has globalization gone too far? California Management Review, 39(3), 29–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Rogowski, R., & MacRae, D. (2008). Inequality and institutions: What theory, history, and (some) data tell us. InDemocracy, inequality and representation: A comparative perspective (pp. 354–386). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
  41. Romer, P. M. (1994). The origins of endogenous growth. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(1), 3–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Ross, M. (2006). Is democracy good for the poor? American Journal of Political Science, 50(4), 860–874.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Sachs, J. D., Warner, A., Åslund, A., & Fischer, S. (1995). Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1995(1), 1–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Schultz, T. W. (1961). Investment in human capital. The American Economic Review, 51(1), 1–17.Google Scholar
  45. Schultz, T. P. (1994). Human capital, family planning, and their effects on population growth. The American Economic Review, 84(2), 255–260.Google Scholar
  46. Sen, A. (1999). Development as freedom. New York: Anchor Books.Google Scholar
  47. Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39, 312–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Stasavage, D. (2005). Democracy and education spending in Africa. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2), 343–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Wallerstein, M. (1999). Wage-setting institutions and pay inequality in advanced industrial societies. American Journal of Political Science, 43, 649–680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Wilkinson, R. G., & Pickett, K. E. (2006). Income inequality and population health: A review and explanation of the evidence. Social Science & Medicine, 62(7), 1768–1784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  • Nichole Torpey-Saboe
    • 1
  1. 1.Colorado Department of Higher EducationDenverUSA

Personalised recommendations