Advertisement

A Public Good Perspective on the Rural Environment: Theory and History

  • Martijn van der Heide
  • Wim HeijmanEmail author
Chapter
Part of the Palgrave Advances in Bioeconomy: Economics and Policies book series (PABEP)

Abstract

The literature on the theory of public goods is voluminous. This chapter provides an overview of public goods related to rural amenities. Many of these amenities tend to be non-exclusive and rival (e.g. forests and irrigation systems), exclusive and subject to some rivalry (e.g. nature reserves) or non-exclusive and non-rival (e.g. scenic views and clean air and water). Many beneficiaries of these amenities choose not to pay and will free ride on the efforts and activities of others (such as farmers and agro-foresters). This can present a problem for provision. Hence, rural amenities require collective action to be properly and efficiently provided since the logic of individual interests results in a socially less than optimum response.

References

  1. Allouch, N., J.P. Conley, and M. Wooders. 2009. Anonymous Price Taking Equilibrium in Tiebout Economies with a Continuum of Agents: Existence and Characterization. Journal of Mathematical Economics 45 (9–10): 492–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Anderies, J.M. 2000. On Modeling Human Behaviour and Institutions in Simple Ecological Economic Systems. Ecological Economics 35 (3): 393–412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Banzhaf, H.S., and R.P. Walsh. 2008. Do People Vote with Their Feet? An Empirical Test of Tiebout’s Mechanism. American Economic Review 98 (3): 843–863.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Barkley, P.W. 1974. Public Goods in Rural Areas: Problems, Policies and Population. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 56 (5): 1135–1142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Baumol, W.J., and W.E. Oates. 1988. The Theory of Environmental Policy. 2nd ed. Cambridge: University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Berglas, E. 1976. On the Theory of Clubs. American Economic Review 66 (2): 116–121.Google Scholar
  7. ———. 1981. The Market Provision of Club Goods Once Again. Journal of Public Economics 15 (3): 389–393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. ———. 1984. Quantities, Qualities and Multiple Public Services in the Tiebout Model. Journal of Public Economics 25: 299–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Berglas, E., and D. Pines. 1981. Clubs, Local Public Goods and Transportation Models; A Synthesis. Journal of Public Economics 15: 141–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Berglas, E., E. Helpman, and D. Pines. 1982. The Economic Theory of Clubs. Economics Letters 10: 343–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Berkes, F. 2008. Commons in a Multi-Level World. International Journal of the Commons 2 (1): 1–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Bewley, T.F. 1981. A Critique of Tiebout’s Theory of Local Public Expenditures. Econometrica 49 (3): 713–740.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Bischoff, I. 2008. Endowment Effect Theory, Prediction Bias and Publicly Provided Goods: An Experimental Study. Environmental and Resource Economics 39 (3): 283–296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Bovenberg, A.L., and C.N. Teulings. 1999. Op zoek naar de grenzen van de staat: publieke verantwoordelijkheid tussen contract en eigendomsrecht. In Over Publieke en Private Verantwoordelijkheden, ed. W. Derksen, M. Ekelenkamp, F.J.P.M. Hoefnagel, and M. Scheltema. Den Haag: Sdu Uitgevers, WRR, Voorstudies en Achtergronden, V105.Google Scholar
  15. Bromley, D.W. 1989. Property Relations and Economic Development: The Other Land Reform. World Development 17 (6): 867–877.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. ———. 1991. Environment and Economy; Property Rights and Public Policy. Oxford/Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  17. ———. 1992. The Commons, Common Property, and Environmental Policy. Environmental and Resource Economics 2 (1): 1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. ———. 1997. Property Regimes in Environmental Economics. In The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 1997/1998, ed. H. Folmer and T. Tietenberg. Cheltenham/Lyme: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  19. Brouwer, F., and C.M. van der Heide. 2009. Conclusions and Prospects. In Multifunctional Rural Land Management; Economics and Policies, ed. F. Brouwer and C.M. van der Heide. London/Sterling: Earthscan.Google Scholar
  20. Buchanan, J.M. 1965. An Economic Theory of Clubs. Economica 32: 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Byalsky, M., M. Keren, and D. Levhari. 1999. The Kibbutz as a Labor-Managed Club: Public and Private Goods, Incentives and Social Control. In Trade, Growth and Development; Essays in Honor of Professor T.N. Srinivasan, ed. G. Ranis and L.K. Raut. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.Google Scholar
  22. Caplan, B. 2001. Standing Tiebout on His Head: Tax Capitalization and the Monopoly Power of Local Governments. Public Choice 108: 101–122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Chiang, A.C. 1984. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics. 3rd ed. Singapore: McGraw-Hill Book Company.Google Scholar
  24. Clark, C.W. 1990. Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources. 2nd ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
  25. Coase, R.H. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Cole, D.H., and P.Z. Grossman. 2002. The Meaning of Property Rights: Law Versus Economics? Land Economics 78 (3): 317–330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Cooper, T., K. Hart, and D. Baldock. 2009. Provision of Public Goods Through Agriculture in the European Union. London: Institute for European Environmental Policy, Report Prepared for DG Agriculture and Rural Development.Google Scholar
  28. Cornes, R., and T. Sandler. 1996. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods. 2nd ed. Cambridge: University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Cox, M., G. Arnold, and S. Villamayor Tomás. 2010. A Review of Design Principles for Community-Based Natural Resource Management. Ecology and Society 15 (4): article 38. http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol15/iss4/art38/.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Dasgupta, P. 2008. Nature in Economics. Environmental and Resource Economics 39 (1): 1–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Deng, F.F. 2002. Ground Lease-Based Land Use System Versus Common Interest Development. Land Economics 78 (2): 190–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Dietz, T., E. Ostrom, and P.C. Stern. 2003. The Struggle to Govern the Commons. Science 302 (5652): 1907–1912.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Dowding, K. 2008. A Pandemonium of Confusions: Kay and Marsh on Tiebout. New Political Economy 13 (3): 335–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Dowding, K., P. John, and S. Biggs. 1994. Tiebout: A Survey of the Empirical Literature. Urban Studies 31 (4–5): 767–797.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Epple, D., and T. Romer. 1991. Mobility and Redistribution. Journal of Political Economy 99 (4): 828–858.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Epple, D., and H. Sieg. 1999. Estimating Equilibrium Models of Local Jurisdictions. Journal of Political Economy 107 (4): 645–681.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Epple, D., and A. Zelenitz. 1981. The Implications of Competition Among Jurisdictions: Does Tiebout Need Politics? Journal of Political Economy 89 (6): 1197–1217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Feeny, D., S. Hanna, and A.F. McEvoy. 1996. Questioning the Assumptions of the “Tragedy of the Commons” Model of Fisheries. Land Economics 72 (2): 187–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Figlio, D.N., T.A. Husted, and L.W. Kenny. 2004. Political Economy of the Inequality in School Spending. Journal of Urban Economics 55 (2): 338–349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Fisher, A.C., and J.V. Krutilla. 1972. Determination of Optimal Capacity of Resource-Based Recreation Facilities. Natural Resources Journal 12 (3): 417–444.Google Scholar
  41. Hanley, N., J.F. Shogren, and B. White. 1997. Environmental Economics in Theory and Practice. Houndmills-London: Macmillan Press Ltd.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Hanson, R.A. 1978. Toward an Understanding of Politics Through Public Goods Theory: A Review Essay. In Public Goods and Public Policy, ed. W. Loehr and T. Sandler. Beverly Hills/London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
  43. Hardin, G. 1968. The Tragedy of the Commons. Science 162: 1243–1248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. ———. 1998. Extensions of “The Tragedy of the Commons”. Science 280: 682–683.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Heikkila, E.J. 1996. Are Municipalities Tieboutian Clubs? Regional Science and Urban Economics 26: 203–226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Hoel, M. 1999. Transboundary Environmental Problems. In Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, ed. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh. Cheltenham/Northampton: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  47. Hoel, M., and P. Shapiro. 2000. Transboundary Environmental Problems with a Mobile Population: Is There a Need for Central Policy? Oslo: Mimeo, University of Oslo.Google Scholar
  48. Howell-Moroney, M. 2008. The Tiebout Hypothesis 50 Years Later: Lessons and Lingering Challenges for Metropolitan Governance in the 21st Century. Public Administration Review 68 (1): 97–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Jongeneel, R., and L. Slangen. 2004. Multifunctionality in Agriculture and the Contestable Public Domain in the Netherlands. In Sustaining Agriculture and the Rural Environment; Governance, Policy and Multifunctionality, ed. F. Brouwer. Cheltenham/Northampton: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  50. Kay, A., and A. Marsh. 2007. The Methodology of the Public Choice Research Programme: The Case of ‘Voting with Feet’. New Political Economy 12 (2): 167–183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Kollman, K., J.H. Miller, and S.E. Page. 1997. Political Institutions and Sorting in a Tiebout Model. American Economic Review 87 (5): 977–992.Google Scholar
  52. Lindberg, E. 2009. Club Goods and Inefficient Institutions: Why Danzig and Lübeck Failed in the Early Modern Period. Economic History Review 62 (3): 604–628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Loehr, W., and T. Sandler. 1978. On the Public Character of Goods. In Public Goods and Public Policy, ed. W. Loehr and T. Sandler. Beverly Hills/London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
  54. Markusen, J.R. 1975. Cooperative Control of International Pollution and Common Property Resources. Quarterly Journal of Economics 89: 618–632.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Mc Laughlin, K. 2019. Exploding Demand for Cashmere Wool Is Ruining Mongolian Grasslands. Last modified January 30, 2019. https://www.sciencemag.org/news/2019/01/exploding-demand-cashmere-wool-ruining-mongolia-s-grasslands
  56. Moretto, M., and P. Rosato. 2002. The Use of Common Property Resources: A Dynamic Model. Milan: Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, Nota di Lavoro 13.2002.Google Scholar
  57. Nitzan, S., and K. Ueda. 2009. Collective Contests for Commons and Club Goods. Journal of Public Economics 93 (1–2): 48–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Oakland, W.H. 1987. Theory of Public Goods. In Handbook of Public Economics, ed. A.J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein, vol. II, 485–535. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons; The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. ———. 1999. Coping with Tragedies of the Commons. Annual Review of Political Science 2: 493–535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. ———. 2000. Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (3): 137–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. ———. 2002. Common-Pool Resources and Institutions: Toward a Revised Theory. In Handbook of Agricultural Economics; Volume 2, ed. B. Gardner and G. Rausser. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
  63. ———. 2003. How Types of Goods and Property Rights Jointly Affect Collective Action. Journal of Theoretical Politics 15 (3): 239–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. ———. 2008. Institutions and the Environment. Economic Affairs 28 (3): 24–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Ostrom, E., J. Burger, C.B. Field, R. Norgaard, and D. Policansky. 1999. Revisiting the Commons: Local Lessons, Global Challenges. Science 284: 278–282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Perman, R., Y. Ma, and J. McGilvray. 1996. Natural Resource and Environmental Economics. London/New York: Longman.Google Scholar
  67. Perrings, C., C.F. Folke, and K.-G. Mäler. 1992. The Ecology and Economics of Biodiversity Loss: The Research Agenda. Ambio 21 (3): 201–211.Google Scholar
  68. Pigou, A. 1920. The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  69. Prakash, A., and M. Potoski. 2007. Collective Action Through Voluntary Environmental Programs: A Club Theory Perspective. The Policy Studies Journal 35 (4): 773–792.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Proost, S. 1999. Public Economics and Environmental Policy. In Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, ed. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh. Cheltenham/Northampton: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  71. Ross, S., and J. Yinger. 1999. Sorting and Voting: A Review of the Literature on Urban Public Finance. In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics; Volume 3 Applied Urban Economics, ed. P. Cheshire and E.S. Mills. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.Google Scholar
  72. Rubinfeld, D.L. 1987. The Economics of the Local Public Sector. In Handbook of Public Economics; Volume II, ed. A.J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.Google Scholar
  73. Sandberg, A. 2007. Property Rights and Ecosystem Properties. Land Use Policy 24 (4): 613–623.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Sandler, T., and J. Tschirhart. 1980. The Economic Theory of Clubs: An Evaluative Survey. Journal of Economic Literature 18: 1481–1521.Google Scholar
  75. ———. 1997. Club Theory: Thirty Years Later. Public Choice 93: 335–355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Schlager, E. 2016. Introducing the “the Importance of Context, Scale, and Interdependencies in Understanding and Applying Ostrom’s Design Principles for Successful Governance of the Commons”. International Journal of the Commons 10 (2): 405–416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Schmid, A.A. 1995. The Environment and Property Rights Issues. In Handbook of Environmental Economics, ed. D.W. Bromley. Basil Blackwell Ltd: Oxford/Cambridge.Google Scholar
  78. Sharpe, L.J., and K. Newton. 1984. Does Politics Matter? The Determinants of Public Policy. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  79. Singh, K. 2018. Air Pollution in Delhi: A Case of Tragedy of the Commons. Last modified January 4, 2018. https://medium.com/@KatarSingh1/air-pollution-in-delhi-a-case-of-tragedy-of-the-commons-83975642ef3
  80. Slangen, L.H.G., L.A. Loucks, and A.H.L. Slangen. 2008. Institutional Economics and Economic Organisation Theory; An Integrated Approach. Wageningen: Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  81. Sowell, T. 2007. Basic Economics; A Common Sense Guide to the Economy. 3rd ed. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  82. Starrett, D.A. 2003. Property Rights, Public Goods and the Environment. In Handbook of Environmental Economics; Volume 1 Environmental Degradation and Institutional Responses, ed. K.-G. Mäler and J.R. Vincent. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
  83. Steinberg, P.F. 2009. Institutional Resilience amid Political Change: The Case of Biodiversity Conservation. Global Environmental Politics 9 (3): 61–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Steins, N.A., and V.M. Edwards. 1999. Platforms for Collective Action in Multiple-Use Common-Pool Resources. Agriculture and Human Values 16: 241–255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Sukhdev, P. 2012. The Corporate Climate Overhaul. Nature 486: 27–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. Sustainable Food Trust. 2017. The Hidden Cost of UK Food. Bristol.Google Scholar
  87. Tiebout, C.M. 1956. A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures. Journal of Political Economy 64 (3): 416–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. Tisdell, C. 1984. The Provision of Wilderness by Clubs. Revista Internazionale di Scienze Economiche e Commerciali (International Review of Economics and Business) 31 (8): 758–761.Google Scholar
  89. Turner, R.W. 2000. Managing Multiple Activities in a National Park. Land Economics 76 (3): 474–485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Turner, R.K., D. Pearce, and I. Bateman. 1994. Environmental Economics; An Elementary Introduction. London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
  91. van der Heide, C.M. 2005. An Economic Analysis of Nature Policy. PhD Dissertation, Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam, Tinbergen Institute, Research Series No. 356.Google Scholar
  92. van der Heide, C.M., and W.J.M. Heijman, eds. 2013. The Economic Value of Landscapes. London/New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  93. van Kooten, G.C., and E.H. Bulte. 2000. The Economics of Nature; Managing Biological Assets. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers Ltd.Google Scholar
  94. Weisbrod, B.A. 1964. Collective-Consumption Services of Individual-Consumption Goods. Quarterly Journal of Economics 78: 471–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  95. Wildasin, D.E. 1987. Theoretical Analysis of Local Public Economics. In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics; Volume II Urban Economics, ed. E.S. Mills. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.Google Scholar
  96. WRR. 2000. Het Borgen van Publiek Belang. Den Haag: Sdu Uitgevers, Rapporten aan de Regering, nr. 56.Google Scholar
  97. Zeng, D.-Z. 2008. New Economic Geography with Heterogeneous Preferences: An Explanation of Segregation. Journal of Urban Economics 63 (1): 306–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Ministry of Agriculture, Nature and Food QualityThe HagueThe Netherlands
  2. 2.Agricultural Economics and Rural Policy GroupWageningen UniversityWageningenThe Netherlands

Personalised recommendations