Advertisement

The Process of Development: The Contribution of Régulation Theory

  • Robert Boyer
Chapter

Abstract

Development is not the search for an optimal static macro-equilibrium but it derives from the art of creating, if not miracles, at least virtuous circles in which social values, organizations, institutions and technological systems co-evolve. Development modes are therefore built upon the discovery of possible institutional arrangements that fulfil two conditions: the viability of the accumulation process and a political legitimacy around an implicit or explicit institutionalized compromise. The survey of economic history reveals a limited number of these modes: import substitution development, export-led, foreign direct investment-led and finally based upon low wage and poor welfare. Contemporary China explores a genuine development mode built upon the acute competition between a myriad of local corporatism under the aegis of a party-State. Most of these modes rely upon the resilience of an open world economy. Its stability is not guaranteed given the obstacles to the defense of global public goods and to the creation of new Commons. Last but not least, the merits of an anthropogenetic model based on education, health and culture should not be underestimated.

Keywords

Development mode Regulation theory Accumulation regime Institutionalized compromise Viability 

References

  1. Aboites J. (1986). Régime d’accumulation, rapport salarial et crises au Mexique (1940–1982), ronéotypé, Cepremap, mai.Google Scholar
  2. Abramowitz, M. (1979) Rapid growth potential and its realization: The experience of capitalist economies in the postwar period. In E. Malinvaud (Dir.), Economic growth and resources, the major issues. Londres: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  3. Abramowitz, M. (1986, June). Catching-up, forging ahead, and falling behind. Journal of Economic History, 46(2), 385–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. New York: Crown.Google Scholar
  5. Aglietta, M. (1982). Regulation and crisis of capitalism, Monthly Review Press, New York.Google Scholar
  6. Amable, B. (2003). The diversity of modern capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Amable, B., Barré, R., & Boyer, R. (1997). Les systèmes d’innovation à l’ère de la globalisation. Paris: OST/Economica.Google Scholar
  8. Amable, B., Guillaud, E., & Palombarini, S. (2012). L’Économie politique du néolibéralisme. Le cas de la France et de l’Italie. Paris: Editions de l’ENS, rue d’Ulm.Google Scholar
  9. Amsden, A. (1989). Asia’s next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Aoki, M. (2001). Towards a comparative institutional analysis, Mimeo, Stanford University, juillet 2000 (à paraître, MIT Press).Google Scholar
  11. Arthur, B. (1994). Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Banerjee, A., & Duflo, E. (2012). Poor economics: A radical rethinking of the way to fight global poverty, Public Affairs.Google Scholar
  13. Barro, R. J. (1996). Democracy and Economic Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 1–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Benassy, J. P. (1983). The economics of market disequilibrium. London: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  15. Bertrand, H. (1978). Une nouvelle approche de la croissance française de l’après-guerre: l’analyse en sections productives. Économie & Prévision Année, 1978(35), 3–36. http://www.persee.fr/doc/ecop_0338-4217_1978_num_35_1_2268.Google Scholar
  16. Borras, S., & Seebrooke, L. (2015). Sense-making and institutional change. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  17. Boyer, R. (1990). The régulation school: A critical introduction. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Boyer, R. (1994). Do labour institutions matter for economic development? A régulation approach for the OECD and Latin America with an extension to Asia. In G. dans Rodgers (Ed.), Workers, Institutions and Economic Growth in Asia (pp. 25–112). Genève: ILO/ILLS.Google Scholar
  19. Boyer, R. (1997). The variety of unequal performance of really existing markets: Farewell to doctor pangloss? In J.-R. dans Hollingsworth & R. Boyer (Eds.), Contemporary capitalism: The embeddedness of institutions (pp. 55–93). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Boyer, R. (2002). L’après consensus de Washington: institutionnaliste et systémique ? L’Année de la régulation 2001–2002, Vol. 5, p. 13–56. (Presses de Sciences PO).Google Scholar
  21. Boyer, R. (2006). Half a century of development theories: an institutionalist survey. In G. Stathakis & G. Vaggi (Eds.), Economic development and social change: Historical roots and modern perspectives (pp. 29–73). Oxon/New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  22. Boyer, R. (2011a). A new epoch but still diversity within and between capitalism: China in comparative perspective. In C. Lane & G. T. Wood (Eds.), Capitalist diversity and diversity within capitalism (pp. 32–68). Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
  23. Boyer, R. (2011b). Les financiers détruiront-ils le capitalisme ? Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
  24. Boyer, R. (2012). Diversité et évolution des capitalismes en Amérique latine. De la régulation économique au politique, Revue de la régulation [Online], 11 | 1er semestre / Spring 2012, Online since 03 May 2012, connection on 21 February 2018. URL: http://journals.openedition.org/regulation/9720.
  25. Boyer, R. (2012a). The four fallacies of contemporary austerity policies: The lost Keynesian legacy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 36, 283–312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Boyer, R. (2015a). Economie politique des capitalismes. Paris: La Découverte.Google Scholar
  27. Boyer, R. (2015b). Transformación del Estado y paradigmas de desarrollo en América Latina, Capítulo XI, in Neoestructuralismo y corrientes heterodoxas en América Latina a inicios del siglo XXI, CEPAL, Enero.Google Scholar
  28. Boyer R. (2017b). Les théories économiques contemporaines à l’épreuve de la trajectoire chinoise. Revue de la Régulation, [En ligne], 21 | 1er semestre / Spring 2017, mis en ligne le 05 septembre 2017, consulté le 16 février 2018. URL: http://journals.openedition.org/regulation/12319; DOI:  https://doi.org/10.4000/regulation.12319.
  29. Boyer, R. (2018). Expectations, Narratives, and Socio-Economic Regimes. In J. Becker & R. Bronk (Eds.), Uncertain Futures: Imaginaries, Narratives and Calculation in the Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  30. Boyer, R., & Neffa, J. C. (Eds.). (2004). La crisis argentina (1976–2001): una vision desde la theorias institucionalistas y regulacionistas. Editorial Mino y Davila Madrid: Buenos Aires.Google Scholar
  31. Boyer, R., & Neffa, J. C. (Eds.). (2007). Salida de crisis y estrategias alternativas de desarollo. La experiencia argentina. Mino y Davila Madrid et: Buenos Aires.Google Scholar
  32. Boyer, R., & Orléan, A. (1992). How do conventions evolve? Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 2, 165–177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Boyer, R., & Saillard, Y. (2001). Regulation Theory: The State of the Art. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  34. Braudel, F. (1979). Civilisation matérielle, économie et capitalisme XV-XVIIIe siècles, 3 tomes, Paris, Armand Colin.Google Scholar
  35. Bresser-Pereira, L. C. (2009). Mondialisation et compétition: Pourquoi certains pays émergents réussissent et d’autres non. Paris: La Découverte.Google Scholar
  36. Bresser-Pereira, L. C. (Coord.) (2010), Ten theses on New Developmentalism, São Paulo School of Economics of Getulio, Vargas Foundation, Development Macroeconomics Center, May 25.Google Scholar
  37. Cardoso, F. H. (2001). Charting a new course: The politics of globalization and social transformation. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
  38. Cardoso, F. H., & Faletto, E. (1979). Dependency and development in Latin America. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  39. Cassiers, I. (Ed.). (2011). Redéfinir la prospérité. Jalons pour un débat. Editions de l’Aube: Brussels.Google Scholar
  40. CEPAL. (2012). Cambio Estructural para la Igualdad. Una visión integrada del desarrollo. Santiago, Chile: Nations Unies.Google Scholar
  41. CEPAL. (2015). Neoestructuralismo y corrientes heterodoxas en Amecirana Latina y el Caraibes a los inicios del siglo XXI, Alica Barcena y Antonio Prado (Eds), Libros de la CEPAL, n° 132 (LC/G.2633-P), Santiago de Chile, Comision Economica para America Latina y el Caribe (CEPAL).Google Scholar
  42. Chandrasekar, C. P. (2016). Development planning. In E. S. Reinert, J. Gosh, & R. Kattel (Eds.), Handbook of alternative theories of economic development. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  43. Chang, H.-J. (2002). Kicking away the ladder: Development strategy in historical perspective. London: Anthem Press.Google Scholar
  44. Chavance, B. (2017). Ownership transformation and system change in China, Revue de la régulation [En ligne], 21 | 1er semestre / Spring 2017, mis en ligne le 20 juin 2017, consulté le 16 février 2018. URL: http://journals.openedition.org/regulation/12298; DOI:  https://doi.org/10.4000/regulation.12298.
  45. Combarnous, F., & Rougier, E. (Eds.). (2017). The diversity of emerging capitalisms globalization, institutional convergence and experimentation. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
  46. Cutler, D., & Lleras-Muney, A. (2006). Education and health: Evaluating theories and evidence (Working paper NBER 12352). http://www.nber.org/papers/w12352
  47. Dardot, P., & Laval, C. (2014). Commun. Essai sur la révolution au XXIe siècle. Paris: La Découverte.Google Scholar
  48. David, P. A. (1985). Clio and the Economics of QWERTY. The American Economic Review, 75(2), 332–337.Google Scholar
  49. Day, R. (1999). Complex dynamics; An introduction to macroeconomic dynamics. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  50. De Soto Polar, H. (2000), El misterio del capital: ¿Por qué el capitalismo triunfa en occidente y fracasa en el resto del mundo?.Google Scholar
  51. De Soto Polar, H. (2006), Realizing property rights, Frank/Wynkin de Worde.Google Scholar
  52. Debreu, G. (1959). Theory of value. An axiomatic analysis of general equilibrium. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  53. Devereux, S. (2007). The new famines: Why famines persist in an era of globalization. Abingdon: Routledge Studies in Development Economics.Google Scholar
  54. Díaz-Alejandro, C.F. (1985). Good-bye Financial Repression, Hello Financial Crash, Journal of Development Economics, 19, reprinted in A. Velasco (ed.), Trade, Development and the World Economy: Selected Essays of Carlos Díaz-Alejandro, Oxford, UK: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  55. Esping Andersen, G. (2008). Childhood investments and skill formation. International tax and Public Finance, 15, 14–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Fourquet, F. (2018). Penser la longue durée. Contribution à une histoire de la mondialisation. Paris: La Découverte.Google Scholar
  57. Gallardo, J. (2008). La economía de Michael Kalecki y el capitalismo actual: ensayos de teoría económica y economía aplicada. México: Fondo de Cultura Económica.Google Scholar
  58. Giraud, G. (2017). Construire un monde commun. Les Communs comme projet politique. Conférence 7 mars, http://www.les-communs-dabord.org/conference-de-gael-giraud-construire-monde-commun-communs-projet-politique/
  59. Gordon, R. (2016). The rise and fall of American growth. The US standard of living since the civil war. Princeton University Press: Princeton.Google Scholar
  60. Hagen, E. E. (1982). On the theory of social change. Homewood: Dorsey Press.Google Scholar
  61. Hahn, F. (1985). Money, growth and stability. London: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  62. Hall, P., & Soskice, D. (Eds.). (2001). Varieties of capitalism, The institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  63. Harada, Y., & Tohyama, H. (2011). Asian capitalisms: institutional con-figurations and firm Heterogeneity. In R. Boyer, H. Uemura, & A. Isokai (Eds.), Diversity and transformations of Asian capitalisms (pp. 243–263). London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  64. Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248.  https://doi.org/10.1126/science.162.3859.1243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Hausmann, R. (1981). State landed property, oil rent and accumulation in the Venezuelan economy, Ph.D. Thesis, Cornell University.Google Scholar
  66. Hausmann, R., & Hidalgo, C. (2014). The Atlas of Economic Complexity: Mapping Paths to Prosperity. Cambridge: Center for International Development (CID) & MIT Media Lab.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Hausmann, R., Rodrik, D., Velasco, A. (2005). Growth diagnostics. In The Washington consensus reconsidered: Towards a new global governance (pp. 324–355). Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN: 978-0199534098CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, XXXV(4), 519–530.Google Scholar
  69. Hollingsworth, R., & Boyer, R. (Eds.). (1997). Contemporary capitalism: The embeddedness of institutions. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  70. Ingrao, B., & Israel, G. (1990). The invisible hand: Economic equilibrium in the history of science. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  71. Jerven, M. (2015). Africa: Why economists get it wrong. London: Zed Books.Google Scholar
  72. Johnson, C. (1982). MITI and the Japanese miracle. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  73. Juillard, M. (2002). Régimes d’accumulation », chapitre 22, dans Boyer R & Saillard Y. (ed), La théorie de la régulation: l’état des savoirs, La découverte, Paris.Google Scholar
  74. Kindleberger, C. P. (1967). French planning. In M. F. Millikan (Ed.), National economic planning (pp. 279–303). Cambridge, MA: NBER. http://www.nber.org/chapters/c1426.Google Scholar
  75. Kornai, J. (1992). The socialist system, The political economy of communism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Krugman, P. (1995, September). Development, geography, and economic theory. Ohlin Lectures, ISBN 0-262-11203-5Google Scholar
  77. Krugman, P. (2001, March 25–26). Crises: The next generation? Razin conference, Tel Aviv University. http://econ.tau.ac.il/research/sapir/Krugman.pdf
  78. La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(4), 1113–1155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origin. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(2), 285–332. http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?.  https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.46.2.285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Labrousse, E., & Braudel, F. (1970). Histoire économique de la société française: 1660–1789, tome 2 Relié, Presses Universitaires de France, Paris, Janvier.Google Scholar
  81. Landes, D. (2006, Spring). Why Europe and the West? Why not China? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2), 3–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  82. Lebrun, F. (2002), L’Europe et le monde. XVIe-XVIIIe siècle. Armand Colin.Google Scholar
  83. Lewis, D. (2002). Convention. A philosophical study. Oxford: Blackwell Publisher.Google Scholar
  84. Lin, J. Y. (1995, January). The Needham Puzzle: Why the industrial revolution did not originate in China. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 43(2), 269–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. List, F. (1841). The national system of political economy, trad. anglaise par Sampson S. Llyod [1885]. DOI:  https://doi.org/10.1002/9781118011690.ch16CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. Lucas, R. (1983). Studies in business cycle theory. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  87. Lucas, R. (1988). On the mechanisms of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 72, Juillet, 3–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. Lucas, R. (1993). Making a miracle. Econometrica, 61(2), 251–272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. MacKenzie, D., & Millo, Y. (2003). Constructing a market, performing theory: The historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 109, 107–145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Maddison, A. (2001). The world economy. A millennial perspective. Paris: OECD.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Maddison, A. (2003). The world economy. Historical statistics. Paris: OECD.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Massé, P. (1965). Le Plan ou l’anti-hasard. Paris: Gallimard.Google Scholar
  93. Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1990). The economics of modern manufacturing: technology, strategy and organization. American Economic Review, 80(3), 511–528.Google Scholar
  94. Miotti, L., Quenan C. et T. Zane E. (2012). Continuités et ruptures dans l’accumulation et la régulation en Amérique latine dans les années 2000: le cas de l’Argentine, du Brésil et du Chili, Revue de la régulation, n° 11, premier semestre.Google Scholar
  95. Miotti, L., & Quenan, C. (2004). Analyse des grandes crises structurelles: le cas de l’Argentine. In N. Julio (Ed.), Analises regulationistas de la crisis argentina. Buenos Aires.Google Scholar
  96. Mjoset, L. (2016). The Nordic route to development. In E. S. Reinert, J. Gosh, & R. Kattel (Eds.), Handbook of Alternative Theories of Economic Development (pp. 533–569). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  97. Naughton, B. (2007). The Chinese economy: Transition and growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  98. Nelson, R. (2016). Economic development as an evolutionary process. In E. S. Reinert, J. Gosh, & R. Kattel (Eds.), Handbook of Alternative theories of economic development (pp. 323–335). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  99. Nelson, R., & Winter, S. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  100. Nove, A. (1987). Planned Economy. The new Palgrave. A dictionary of economics, 3, 879.Google Scholar
  101. Nurkse, R. (1953). Problems of capital formation in under-developed countries. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  102. Ocampo, J., & Bertola, L. (2012). The economic development of Latin America since independence. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  103. Ocampo, J. A., Rada, C., & Taylor, L. (2009). Growth and policy in developing countries: A structuralist approach. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  104. Olson, M. (1982). Rise and decline of nation. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  105. Ominami, C. (1986). Le Tiers Monde dans la crise. Essai sur la transformation récente des rapports Nord-Sud. Paris: La Découverte.Google Scholar
  106. Ostrom, E. (2015). Governing the commons the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  107. Ostrom E., & Basurto X. (2011). Crafting analytical tools to study institutional change. Journal of Institutional Economics, 7, 317–343. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137410000305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  108. Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Harvard: Belknap Press World.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  109. Piketty, T. (2015, Winter). Putting distribution back at the center of economics: Reflections on capital in the twenty-first century. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 29(1), 67–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  110. Pomeranz, K. (2000). The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  111. Posner, R. (2011). Economic Analysis of Law. New York: Wolters Kluwer Law & Business edition.Google Scholar
  112. Prebisch, R. (1950). The economic development of Latin-America and its principal problems. New York: United Nations, Economic Commission for Latin America.Google Scholar
  113. Prebisch, R. (1971). Change and development: Latin-America’s great task, report to the Inter American Development Bank. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
  114. Quémia, M. (2001). Théorie de la régulation et développement: trajectoires latino-américaines. In L’année de la régulation (vol. 5, pp. 57–104). Paris: Presses de Sciences-Po.Google Scholar
  115. Rajan, R., & Zingales, L. (2004). Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists: Unleashing the Power of Financial Markets to Create Wealth and Spread Opportunity. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  116. Razafindrakoto, M., Roubaud, F., & Wachsberger, J.-M. (2007), L’énigme et le paradoxe, Économie politique de Madagascar, IRD Éditions/AFD - Collection: Synthèses.Google Scholar
  117. Reinhart, C., & Rogoff, K. S. (2009). This Time is Different: Eight-Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton University Press: Princeton.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  118. Revue d’Économie du Dévelopement. (2000), Gouvernance, équité et marchés mondiaux, sélection des Actes, Conférence ABCDE-Europe, Paris, 21 au 23 juin 1998 (1–2), numéro spécial, Paris, PUF.Google Scholar
  119. Revue d’Économie du Dévelopement. (2001), Penser le développement au tournant du millénaire, Conférence ABCDE-Europe, Paris, 26 au 28 juin 2000, 9 (1–2), numéro spécial, Paris, PUF.Google Scholar
  120. Revue de la régulation. (2012), Les capitalismes en Amérique Latine. De l’économique au politique, numéro 11, http://journals.openedition.org/regulation/9602
  121. Revue de la régulation. (2013), The Topicality of Ostrom’s Approach: the Commons, Property Rights and Methodological Institutionalism, numero 14, http://journals.openedition.org/regulation/10287
  122. Revue de la régulation. (2017), Lectures institutionnalistes de la Chine, n° 21, 1er semestre / Spring, http://journals.openedition.org/regulation/12228
  123. Rodrik, D. (2006). Goodbye Washington Consensus, Hello Washington Confusion? A Review of the World Bank’s. Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform. Journal of Economic Literature, XLIV(December), 973–987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  124. Rogers, J. and A. Singh (2017), Mexico’s productivity puzzle: What the state economies can tell us, MOODY’s Analytics. https://www.economy.com/home/products/samples/2017-06-15-mexicos-productivity-puzzle.pdf
  125. Romer, P. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5 pt. 2), S71–S102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  126. Ros, J. (2015). ¿Cómo salir de la trampa del lento crecimiento y alta desigualdad?, El Colegio de México-UNAM.Google Scholar
  127. Rose-Ackerman, S. (2000). Corruption bureaucratique et responsabilité politique. Revue d’économie du développement 8(1–2), numéro spécial, 145–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  128. Rotberg, R. (2003). The failure and collapse of nation-states, breakdown, prevention and repair. In R. I. Rotberg (Ed.), When States Fail (p. 1). Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  129. Sapir, J. (1989). Les fluctuations économiques en URSS, 1941–1985. Paris: Éditions de l’École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales.Google Scholar
  130. Sapir, J. (1996), Le chaos russe, Coll. « Cahiers Libres », série « Essais », Paris, La Découverte.Google Scholar
  131. Schultz, T. W. (1980). Nobel lecture: The economics of being poor. Journal of Political Economy, 88(4), 639–651.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  132. Schultz, T. W. (1964). Transforming Traditional Agriculture. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  133. Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development: An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. Harvard Economic Studies, 46.Google Scholar
  134. Sen, A. (1988). The concept of development. In H. dans Chenery & T. N. Srinivasan (Eds.), Handbook of development economics (Vol. I, pp. 10–26). Genève: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.Google Scholar
  135. Sen, A. (1997). Development thinking at the beginning of the XXI century. In L. dans Emmerij (Ed.), Economic and social development into the XXI century (pp. 531–551). Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank-John Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
  136. Shafaeddin, M. (2016). Competitiveness and development. In E. S. Reinert, J. Gosh, & R. Kattel (Eds.), Handbook of alternative theories of economic development (pp. 570–593). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  137. Socio Economic Review. (2005). Dialogue on ‘Institutional complementarity and political economy’. avec Amable Bruno, Boyer Robert, Crouch Colin, Halland Peter, Jackson Gregory & Wolfgang Streeck, Vol. 3Google Scholar
  138. Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94, & in Sen A. (Ed.). (1970). Growth economics. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, pp. 161–192.Google Scholar
  139. Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economics and Statistics, 39, 312–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  140. Stiglitz, J. E., & Greenwald, B. C. (2014). Creating a learning society. A New approach to growth, development, and social progress. New York: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  141. Streeck, W., & Thelen, K. (Eds.). (2005). Beyond continuity: Institutional change in advanced political economy. Oxford: Oxford University press.Google Scholar
  142. Summers, L. (2017, May 25). Secular stagnation truer today. Wall Street Journal. https://blogs.wsj.com/economics/2017/05/25/secular-stagnation-even-truer-today-larry-summers-says/
  143. Théret, B. (1999). Vers un socialisme civil ? L’épreuve de la contrainte démocratique de différenciation de la société. dans Chavance B., Magnin E., Motamed-Nejad R., Sapir J. (Dir.), Capitalisme et socialisme en perspective (pp. 43–78). Paris: La Découverte.Google Scholar
  144. Thurbon, E., & Weiss, L. (2016). The developmental state in the late twenties century. In E. S. Reinert, J. Gosh, & R. Kattel (Eds.), Handbook of alternative theories of economic development (pp. 637–650). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  145. UNDP. (2014). human development report 2014: Sustaining human progress: Reducing vulnerabilities and building resilience. New York: UN Publication.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  146. Wade, R. (1990). Governing the market: economic theory and the role of government in East Asian industrialization. Princeton University Press: Princeton.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  147. Wallerstein, I. (1978). Le système du monde du XVe siècle à nos jours. Paris: Flammarion.Google Scholar
  148. Whittaker, H., Zhu, T., Sturgeon, T., Han, M., Tsai, T., & Okita, T. (2010, December). Compressed development. Studies in Comparative international Development, 45(4), 439–467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  149. Williamson, J. (1997). The Washington consensus revisited. In L. dans Emmerij (Ed.), Economic and social Development into the XXI Century (pp. 41–61). Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank-John Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
  150. Wolf, C. J.-R. (1990). Markets or governments, choosing between imperfect and alternatives. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  151. World Bank. (1993). The East Asian miracle: Economic growth and public policy. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
  152. World Bank. (1996). From Plan to Market. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
  153. World Bank. (1997). State and Development. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  • Robert Boyer
    • 1
  1. 1.Institut des AmériquesParisFrance

Personalised recommendations