Advertisement

Catastrophic Agglomeration

  • Aaron Gurwitz
Chapter
Part of the Palgrave Studies in American Economic History book series (AEH)

Abstract

This chapter begins by framing an economic model of the urbanization process. This conceptual framework, referred to as “the new economic geography,” aims to identify the determinants of when cities will coalesce and of the size distribution of urban places in a country or region. The conditions identified by the model as being conducive to the formation of cities include declining transportation costs, rising demand for goods produced under increasing returns to scale, and a preference for variety in the commodities and services households buy. The second part of the chapter shows that these conditions came into much greater effect in the United States during the years between 1815 and about 1850 than they had been before. The chapter concludes with a theoretical consideration of where on the map urbanization is likely to take place.

References

  1. Adams, D. R. (1982). The Standard of Living During American Industrialization: Evidence from the Brandywine Region, 1800–1860. The Journal of Economic History, 42(4), 903–917.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Baron, S. (1962). Brewed in America: A History of Beer and Ale in the United States. Boston: Little Brown.Google Scholar
  3. Britannica Encyclopedia on Line. (2018). Catastrophe Theory. Retrieved from http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/99235/catastrophe-theory.
  4. Carter, S. B. (1976). Historical Statistics of the United States Millennial Edition Online. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  5. Davis, D. R. (1998). The Home Market, Trade and Industrial Structure. American Economic Review, 88(5), 1264–1276.Google Scholar
  6. Davis, D. R., & Weinstein, D. E. (1998, November). Market Access, Economic Geography and Comparative Advantage: An Empirical Assessment (National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 6787).Google Scholar
  7. Davis, J. H. (2004). An Annual Index of U.S. Industrial Production, 1790–1915. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(4), 1177–1215. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Fishlow, A. (2000). Internal Transportation in the Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries. In S. Engerman & R. E. Gallman (Eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of the United States, Volume II, The Long Nineteenth Century (pp. 543–642). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Fujita, M., Krugman, P., & Venables, A. (1999). The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions, and International Trade. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  10. Johnston, L., & Williamson, S. H. (2018). What Was the U.S. GDP Then? Retrieved from MeasuringWorth.com https://www.measuringworth.com/datasets.html.
  11. Neary, J. P. (2001). Of Hype and Hyperbolas: Introducing the New Economic Geography. Journal of Economic Literature, 536–561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. North, D. C. (1968). Sources of Productivity Change in Ocean Shipping, 1600–1850. Journal of Political Economy, 76(5), 953–970.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Paullin, C. O., & Wright, J. K. (1932). Rates of Travel from New York City, 1857. Retrieved from Atlas of the Historical Geography of the United States http://dsl.richmond.edu/historicalatlas/138/c/.
  14. Segal, H. H. (1972). Cycles of Canal Construction. In C. Goodrich (Ed.), Canals in American Economic Development (pp. 211–213). Port Washington, NY: Kennikat Press.Google Scholar
  15. Taylor, G. R. (1951). The Transportation Revolution: 1815–1860. New York: Rinehart & Co., Inc.Google Scholar
  16. U.S. Census Bureau. (2018). State Area Measurements and Internal Point Coordinates. Retrieved from Geography https://www.census.gov/geo/reference/state-area.html.

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  • Aaron Gurwitz
    • 1
  1. 1.New YorkUSA

Personalised recommendations