Advertisement

From National to Cross-Border Support of Renewable Electricity in the European Union

  • Sebastian BuschEmail author
  • André Ortner
Chapter

Abstract

The ability to cooperate in the expansion of renewable energies has long been recognized as welfare improving. However, the existing cooperation mechanisms introduced in the European Union appear to be insufficient to facilitate an efficient level of trade across borders. In this chapter we focus on the electricity sector and identify several characteristics of the market for renewable electricity support that contribute to this failure. We then propose a novel mechanism for cross-border support of renewable electricity capacity that addresses these failures in two steps: First, a cross-border impact factor is derived that provides an approximate indication of the spillover of benefits induced from renewable electricity capacity across the member states of the European Union. Second, a cross-border auction in which member states and generators of renewable electricity bid to either buy or supply additional renewable electricity capacity. The auctioneer uses the cross-border impact factor to determine the aggregate cross-border willingness to pay for additional renewable electricity capacity in each member state and selects the set of bids, which maximizes the EU-wide surplus. Inevitably, the design of the mechanism uses a simplified representation of the underlying system ‘reality’ in order to achieve the complexity reduction needed to create a ‘level playing field’, but in our view it would still represent cross-border impacts accurately enough to spur efficiency improvements in the right direction. Moreover, the fact that it could be integrated into the emerging market and regulatory framework in the European Union fairly easily is appealing.

Keywords

Renewable electricity Efficient support Cross-border impacts Auctions Energy Union Cooperation mechanisms Support scheme opening Lindahl equilibrium 

Notes

Acknowledgements

The work in this chapter synthesizes and updates earlier work by the authors (Busch et al. 2016) and parts of the PhD work conducted by Sebastian Busch (Busch 2017). For their valuable feedback and assistance on earlier versions of this work we wish to thank Mario Ragwitz, Karsten Neuhoff, Gustav Resch, Nick Bedard, Reinhard Haas, Daniel Huppmann, Corinna Klessmann, Lukas Liebmann and Gerhard Totschnig. We also recognize the two anonymous reviewers and the lector of this chapter for their valuable suggestions.

References

  1. Bailey, E. E., & Friedlaender, A. F. (1982). Market structure and multiproduct industries. Journal of Economic Literature, 20, 1024–1048.Google Scholar
  2. Börgers, T. (2015). An introduction to the theory of mechanism design. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Brückmann, R. (2015). Smart policies to reduce renewable energy cost of capital status quo in the EU MSs. A report compiled within the European IEE project Diacore.Google Scholar
  4. Busch, S. (2017). An efficient mechanism for cross-border support of renewable electricity in the European Union. Dissertation, Technische Universität Wien, 2017.Google Scholar
  5. Busch, S., Ortner, A., & Resch, G. (2016). An efficient mechanism for cross-border support of renewable electricity in the European Union. Issue paper no. 8. A report compiled within the European IEE project towards 2030-dialogue.Google Scholar
  6. Clarke, E. (1971). Multipart pricing of public goods. Public Choice, 11, 17–33.  https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01726210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Dangerman, A. J., & Schellnhuber, H. J. (2013). Energy systems transformation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110, E549–E558.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Eecke, W. V. (2013). The concepts of private, public and merit goods. In W. Ver Eecke (Ed.), Ethical reflections on the financial crisis 2007/2008: Making use of Smith, Musgrave and Rajan (pp. 23–44). Heidelberg: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. ENTSO-E. (2018). TYNDP website [WWW document]. http://tyndp.entsoe.eu/
  10. European Commission. (2013). Guidance on the use of renewable energy cooperation mechanisms. SWD (2013) final.Google Scholar
  11. European Commission. (2014) Guidelines on state aid for environmental protection and energy 2014–2020 (2014/C 200/01).Google Scholar
  12. European Commission. (2015). Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, The Council, The European Economic and Social Committee, The Committee of the Regions and the European Investment Bank. A framework strategy for a Resilient Energy Union with a forward-looking climate change policy.Google Scholar
  13. European Commission. (2016). Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources (recast). Brussels.Google Scholar
  14. European Parliament and Council. (2009). Directive2009/28/EC on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources.Google Scholar
  15. Gallagher, K. S., Grübler, A., Kuhl, L., Nemet, G., & Wilson, C. (2012). The energy technology innovation system. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 37, 137–162.  https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-environ-060311-133915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Gronberg, T. (n.d.). Theory of public goods. Lecture Notes [WWW Document]. Accessed May 9, 2016, from http://econweb.tamu.edu/tgronberg/pdf/econ603%20lecture%20notes.%20theory%20of%20Public%20Goods.pdf
  17. Groves, T. (1973). Incentives in teams. Econometrica, 41, 617.  https://doi.org/10.2307/1914085.MathSciNetCrossRefzbMATHGoogle Scholar
  18. Groves, T., & Ledyard, J. (1977). Optimal allocation of public goods: A solution to the “free rider” problem. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 45, 783–809.MathSciNetCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Grübler, A., Nakićenović, N., & Victor, D. G. (1999). Dynamics of energy technologies and global change. Energy Policy, 27, 247–280.  https://doi.org/10.1016/S0301-4215(98)00067-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Healy, P. J. (2007). Comment on “Thirteen reasons why the Vickrey-Clarke-Groves process is not practical” by Michael Rothkopf. Operations Research (Online Forum Commentary), 55(2), 2.MathSciNetGoogle Scholar
  21. Helfat, C. E., & Eisenhardt, K. M. (2003). Inter-temporal economies of scope, organizational modularity, and the dynamics of diversification. Strategic Management Journal, 25(13), 1217–1232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Hirth, L., Ueckerdt, F., & Edenhofer, O. (2015). Integration costs revisited—An economic framework for wind and solar variability. Renewable Energy, 74, 925–939.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.renene.2014.08.065.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Klessmann, C., Lamers, P., Ragwitz, M., & Resch, G. (2010). Design options for cooperation mechanisms under the new European renewable energy directive. Energy Policy, 38, 4679–4691.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2010.04.027.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Klessmann, C., de Visser, E., Wigand, F., Gephart, M., Resch, G., & Busch, S. (2014). Cooperation between EU MSs under the RES directive.Google Scholar
  25. Klinge Jacobsen, H., Pade, L. L., Schröder, S. T., & Kitzing, L. (2014). Cooperation mechanisms to achieve EU renewable targets. Renewable Energy, 63, 345–352.  https://doi.org/10.1016/j.renene.2013.09.035.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D., & Green, J. R. (1995). Microeconomic theory. New York: Oxford University Press.zbMATHGoogle Scholar
  27. Neuhoff, K., Barquin, J., Bialek, J. W., Boyd, R., Dent, C. J., Echavarren, F., et al. (2013). Renewable electric energy integration: Quantifying the value of design of markets for international transmission capacity. Energy Economics, 40, 760–772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Newbery, D., Strbac, G., & Pudjianto, D. (2013). Directorate-General Energy European Commission.Google Scholar
  29. Nicolosi, M. (2012). The economics of renewable electricity market integration. An empirical and model-based analysis of regulatory frameworks and their impacts on the power market. Universität zu Köln.Google Scholar
  30. Panzar, J. C., & Willig, R. D. (1977). Economies of scale in multi-output production. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91, 481.  https://doi.org/10.2307/1885979.CrossRefzbMATHGoogle Scholar
  31. Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.  https://doi.org/10.2307/1925895.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Sanders, N. (2006). Lindahl pricing and equilibrium – proof of Pareto optimality. UC Davis Graduate Department of Economics.Google Scholar
  33. Unteutsch, M., (2014). Who benefits from cooperation? - A numerical analysis of redistribution effects resulting from cooperation in European RES-E support. EWI working papers 2014-2, Energiewirtschaftliches Institut an der Universitaet zu Koeln (EWI).Google Scholar
  34. Vickrey, W. (1961). Counterspeculation, auctions and competitive sealed tenders. The Journal of finance, 16, 8–37.MathSciNetCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Young, H. P. (1998). Cost allocation, demand revelation, and core implementation. Mathematical Social Sciences, 36(3), 213–228.MathSciNetCrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.International Institute for Applied Systems AnalysisLaxenburgAustria
  2. 2.Knowledge for the Energy Union UnitEuropean Commission, Joint Research CentreIspraItaly
  3. 3.Technische Universität WienWienAustria

Personalised recommendations