Advertisement

Creating a Breeding Ground for Compliance and Honest Reporting Under the Landing Obligation: Insights from Behavioural Science

  • Sarah B. M. KraakEmail author
  • Paul J. B. Hart

Abstract

Fisheries regulations aim to maintain fishing mortality and fishing impacts within sustainable limits. Although sustainability is in the long-term interest of fishers, the regulations themselves are usually not in the short-term interest of the individual fisher because they restrict the fisher’s economic activity. Therefore, as is the case with all regulations, the temptation exists for non-compliance and dishonest reporting. In the EU and elsewhere, top-down, complex regulations, often leading to unintended consequences, with complex and non-transparent governance-science interactions, may decrease the credibility and legitimacy of fisheries management among fishers. This, in turn, may decrease the motivation to comply and report honestly. The Landing Obligation may make things worse because following the regulation to the letter would often strongly and negatively impact the individual fishers’ economic situation. Behavioural science suggests factors that may influence compliance and honesty. Compliance is not necessarily a function of the economic benefits and costs of rule violation: compliance may be more or less, depending on intrinsic motivations. An increased level of self-decision may lead to greater buy-in to sustainable fishing practices and voluntary compliance to catch limits and the Landing Obligation. All else being equal, people in small and self-selected groups are inherently more likely to behave “prosocially”. In this chapter, some key recommendations based on behavioural science are given for changes in institutional settings that may increase voluntary compliance and sustainable fishing practices. However, transition to a system allowing for more freedom from top-down regulation, with more self-governance, may be difficult due to institutional and cultural barriers and therefore may take many years.

Keywords

Behavioural economics Being watched Carrot or stick Hidden cost of control Honest reporting Lack of trust Loss aversion Moral priming Nonmonetary incentives Self-decision Self-selected groups Voluntary compliance 

Notes

Acknowledgements

The ideas brought forward in this chapter are largely based on the BehavFish workshop funded by the ICES Science Fund and the Fisheries Society of the British Isles (Kraak et al. 2015), and we therefore thank all participants of this workshop: Chris Anderson, Dorothy Dankel, Matteo Galizzi, Mark Gibson, Diogo Gonçalves, Katell Hamon, Ciaran Kelly, Jean-Jacques Maguire, Jeroen Nieboer, Ingrid van Putten, Andrew Reeson, Dave Reid, Andries Richter and Alessandro Tavoni.

References

  1. Ariely, D. (2012). The (honest) truth about dishonesty. New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
  2. Aronson, E., & Aronson, J. (2012). The social animal, 11th edn. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  3. BBC (2007). http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/uk/7102241.stm. Accessed 12 June 2018.
  4. Becker, G.S. (1974). Crime and punishment: an economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 169–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Behavioural Insights Team (2018). https://www.behaviouralinsights.co.uk/. Accessed 26 June 2018.
  6. BLE (Bundesanstalt für Landwirtschaft und Ernährung) (2018). Bekanntmachung zur Fischerei auf Dorsch im Jahr 2018 unter der Ausnahmemöglichkeit innerhalb der Schonzeiten nach der Verordnung (EU) 2017/1970. Bundesanzeiger vom 8. Januar 2018.Google Scholar
  7. Booker, C. (2007). Fishing quotas are an ecological catastrophe. https://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/uknews/1570439/Fishing-quotas-are-an-ecological-catastrophe.html. Accessed 21 June 2018.
  8. Borges, L., & Penas-Lado, E. (this volume). Discards in the common fisheries policy: The evolution of the policy. In S.S. Uhlmann, C. Ulrich, S.J. Kennelly (Eds.), The European Landing Obligation – Reducing discards in complex multi-species and multi-jurisdictional fisheries. Cham: Springer.Google Scholar
  9. Bowles, S. (2008). Policies designed for self-interested citizens may undermine “the moral sentiments”: evidence from economic experiments. Science, 320(5883), 1605–1609.PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Brekke, K.A., Hauge, K.E., Lind, J.T., Nyborg, K. (2011). Playing with the good guys. A public good game with endogenous group formation. Journal of Public Economics, 95(9), 1111–1118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cardenas, J.C., Stranlund, J., Willis, C. (2000). Local environmental control and institutional crowding-out. World Development, 28, 1719–1733.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Carpenter, J.P., & Seki, E. (2011). Do social preferences increase productivity? Field experimental evidence from fishermen in Toyama Bay. Economic Inquiry, 49(2), 612–630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Chuenpagdee, R. (Ed.). (2011). World small-scale fisheries. Contemporary visions. Delft: Eburon.Google Scholar
  14. Congdon, W.J., & Shankar, M. (2018). The role of behavioural economics in evidence-based policymaking. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 678(1), 81–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Couper, A., Smith, H.D., Ciceri, B. (2015). Fishers and plunderers. Theft, slavery and violence at sea. London: Pluto Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Daw, T., & Gray, T. (2005). Fisheries science and sustainability in international policy: a study of failure in the European Union’s Common Fisheries Policy. Marine Policy, 29(3), 189–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Dhami, S. (2016). The foundations of behavioral economic analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Drupp, M.A., Khadjavi, M., Quaas, M.F. (2016). Truth-telling and the regulator. Evidence from a field experiment with commercial fishermen (Kiel Working Paper 2063). https://www.ifw-kiel.de/datenmigration/publikationen/document-store/truth-telling-and-the-regulator-evidence-from-a-field-experiment-with-commercial-fishermen-7902/. Accessed 19 November 2018.
  19. Eliasen, S.Q., & Bichel, N. (2016). Fishers sharing real-time information about “bad” fishing locations. A tool for quota optimisation under a regime of landing obligations. Marine Policy, 64, 16–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. European Union. (2008). Council Regulation (EC) No 1342/2008 of 18 December 2008 establishing a long-term plan for cod stocks and the fisheries exploiting those stocks and repealing Regulation (EC) No 423/2004. Official Journal of the European Union L, 348, 20–33.Google Scholar
  21. European Union. (2013). Regulation (EU) No 1380/201308 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 December 2013 on the Common Fisheries Policy, amending Council Regulations (EC) No 1954/2003 and (EC) No 1224/2009 and repealing Council Regulations (EC) No 2371/2002 and (EC) No 639/2004 and Council Decision 2004/585/EC. Official Journal of the European Union. L, 354, 22–61.Google Scholar
  22. Falk, A., & Kosfeld, M. (2006). The hidden costs of control. American Economic Review, 96(5), 1611–1630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Fishing into the Future (2018). https://www.fishingintothefuture.co.uk/. Accessed 31 May 2018.
  24. Fitzpatrick, M., Frangoudes, K., Fauconnet, L., Quetglas, A. (this volume). Fishing industry perspectives on the EU Landing Obligation. In S.S. Uhlmann, C. Ulrich, S.J. Kennelly (Eds.), The European Landing Obligation – Reducing discards in complex multi-species and multi-jurisdictional fisheries. Cham: Springer.Google Scholar
  25. Frey, B.S., & Torgler, B. (2007). Tax morale and conditional cooperation. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(1), 136–159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Gächter, S., & Schulz, J.F. (2016). Intrinsic honesty and the prevalence of rule violations across societies. Nature, 531, 496–499.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Gino, F., Ayal, S., Ariely, D. (2009). Contagion and differentiation in unethical behavior: the effect of one bad apple on the barrel. Psychological Science, 20(3), 393–398.PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Gürerk, Ö., Irlenbusch, B., Rockenbach, B. (2006). The competitive advantage of sanctioning institutions. Science, 312(5770), 108–111.PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Hart, P.J.B. (1997). Controlling illegal fishing in closed areas: the case of mackerel off Norway. In: D.A. Hancock, D.C. Smith, A. Grant, et al. (Eds.), Developing and sustaining world fisheries resources: the state of science and management. 2nd world fisheries congress proceedings. Brisbane, Australia, pp. 411–414.Google Scholar
  30. Harth, S.N., Leach, C.W., Kessler, T. (2013). Guilt, anger, and pride about in-group environmental behaviour: different emotions predict distinct intentions. Journal of Environmental Psychology, 34, 18–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Hatcher, A., Jaffry, S., Bennett, E. (2000). Normative and social influences affecting compliance with fishery regulations. Land Economics, 76(3), 448–461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Henrich, J. (2004). Cultural group selection, coevolutionary processes and large-scale cooperation. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 53, 3–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Hermann, B., Thöni, C., Gächter, S. (2008). Antisocial punishment across societies. Science, 219 (5868), 1362–1367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Hetherington, S.J. (2014). MB0125 & C6122: common fisheries policy reform implementation: aligning zero quota species and improving fisheries management – a spurdog case study, Defra Funded Research Programme (2013–2015).Google Scholar
  35. Holland, D.S., & Jannot, J.E. (2012). Bycatch risk pools for the US West Coast Groundfish Fishery. Ecological Economics, 78, 132–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Imas, A., Sadoff, S., & Samek, A. (2017). Do people anticipate loss aversion? Management Science, 63(5), 1271–1284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Jacobsen, R.B., Wilson, D.C.K., Ramirez-Monsalve, P. (2012). Empowerment and regulation – dilemmas in participatory fisheries science. Fish and Fisheries, 13, 291–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. James, K.M., Campbell, N., ViÞarsson, J.R., Vilas, C., Plet-Hansen, K.S., Borges, L., et al. (this volume). Tools and technologies for the monitoring, control and surveillance of unwanted catches. In S.S. Uhlmann, C. Ulrich, S.J. Kennelly (Eds.), The European Landing Obligation – Reducing discards in complex, multi-species and multi-jurisdictional fisheries. Cham: Springer.Google Scholar
  39. Jentoft, S. (1998). Social theory and fisheries co-management. Marine Policy, 22, 423–436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Kelleher, K. (2005). Discards in the world’s marine fisheries. An update. Rome: FAO. No. 470, 131 pp.Google Scholar
  42. Kraak, S.B.M. (2011). Exploring the ‘Public Goods Game’ model to overcome the tragedy of the commons in fisheries management. Fish and Fisheries, 12(1), 18–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Kraak, S.B.M., Bailey, N., Cardinale, M., Darby, C., José, A.A.D.O, Eero, M., et al. (2013). Lessons for fisheries management from the EU cod recovery plan. Marine Policy, 37, 200–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Kraak, S.B.M., Kelly, C., Anderson, C., Dankel, D., Galizzi, M., Gibson, M., et al. (2015). ICES science fund 2014 project report: insights from behavioral economics to improve fisheries management. Report of the Workshop jointly funded by ICES and FSBI held 21–23 October 2014 at ICES HQ, Copenhagen, Denmark, 46 pp. http://www.ices.dk/community/icessciencefund/Documents/06_Report%20of%20the%20BehavFish%20Workshop_final.pdf. Accessed 29 June 2018.
  45. Kraak, S.B.M., Drupp, M.A., Quaas, M. (2016). Carrot or stick? Experimental tests on a potential trade-off between effectiveness and compliance of alternative management approaches, ICES CM 2016/B:293. http://www.ices.dk/sites/pub/ASCExtended2016/Shared%20Documents/B%20-%20Predictably%20Irrational%20%E2%80%93%20a%20new%20scientific%20research%20field%20for%20the%20science%20underpinning%20marine-resource%20management/abstract%20Kraak%20Drupp%20Quaas%20-%20carrot%20stick%20and%20prosocial%20behaviour_final.pdf. Accessed 19 Nov 2018.
  46. Kubanek, J., Snyder, L.H., Abrams, R.A. (2015). Reward and punishment act as distinct factors in guiding behaviour. Cognition, 139, 154–167.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Kuperan, K., & Sutinen, J.G. (1998). Blue water crime: deterrence, legitimacy, and compliance in fisheries. Law & Society Review, 32(2), 309–337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Le Gallic, B., & Cox, A. (2006). An economic analysis of illegal, unreported and unregulated (IUU) fishing: Key drivers and possible solutions. Marine Policy, 30, 689–695.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Mangi, S.C., Dolder, P.J., Catchpole, T.L., Rodmell, D., de Rozarieux, N. (2013). Approaches to fully documented fisheries: Practical issues and stakeholder perceptions. Fish and Fisheries, 16(3), 426–452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Mangi, S.C., Kupschus, S., Mackinson, S., Rodmell, D., Lee, A., Bourke, E., et al. (2018). Progress in designing and delivering effective fishing industry-science data collection in the UK. Fish and Fisheries. https://doi.org/10.1111/faf.12279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Mann, H., Garcia-Rada, X., Houser, D., Ariely, D. (2014). Everybody else is doing it: Exploring social transmission of lying behavior. PLoS ONE, 9(10), e109591.  https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0109591.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Mazar, N., Amir, O., Ariely, D. (2008). The dishonesty of honest people: A theory of self-concept maintenance. Journal of Marketing Research, 45(6), 633–644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Mead, N.L., Baumeister, R.F., Gino, F., Schweitzer, M.E., Ariely, D. (2009). Too tired to tell the truth: Self-control resource depletion and dishonesty. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 45(3), 594–597.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Milinski, M., & Rockenbach, B. (2007). Spying on others evolves. Science, 317(5837), 464.PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Mortensen, L.O., Ulrich, C., Eliasen, S., Olesen, H.J. (2017). Reducing discards without reducing profit: Free gear choice in a Danish result-based management trial. ICES Journal of Marine Science, 74(5), 1469–1479.Google Scholar
  56. Needle, C.L., Dinsdale, R., Buch, T.B., Catarino, R.M.D., Drewery, J., Butler, N. (2015). Scottish science applications of remote electronic monitoring. ICES Journal of Marine Science, 72(4), 1214–1229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Nielsen, J.R. (2003). An analytical framework for studying: Compliance and legitimacy in fisheries management. Marine Policy, 27(5), 425–432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Nielsen, J.R., & Mathiesen, C. (2003). Important factors influencing rule compliance in fisheries lessons from Denmark. Marine Policy, 27(5), 409–416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Norton, M.I., Mochon, D., Ariely, D. (2012). The IKEA effect: When labor leads to love. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 22, 453-460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. O’Keefe, C.E., & DeCelles, G.R. (2013). Forming a partnership to avoid bycatch. Fisheries, 38(10), 434–444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Ostrom, E. (1998). A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action: Presidential address, American Political Science Association, 1997 American Political Science Review, 92(1), 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Ostrom, E. (2001). Reformulating the commons. In J. Burger, E. Ostrom, R.B. Norgaard, D. Policansky and B.D. Golsdstein (Eds.), Protecting the commons. a framework for resource management in the Americas (pp. 17–41). Washington, DC: Island Press.Google Scholar
  64. Ostrom, E. (2009). A general framework for analyzing sustainability of social-ecological systems. Science, 325, 419–422.PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Ouwerkerk, J.W., Kerr, N.L., Gallucci, M., van Lange, P.A.M. (2005) Avoiding the social death penalty: Ostracism and cooperation in social dilemmas. In K.D. Williams, J.P. Forgas, W. von Hippel (Eds.), The social outcast: Ostracism, social exclusion, rejection and bullying. New York: Psychology Press.Google Scholar
  66. Panagopoulos, C. (2010). Affect, social pressure and prosocial motivation: Field experimental evidence of the mobilizing effects of pride, shame and publicizing voting behavior. Political Behavior, 32, 369–386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Prellezo, R., Kraak, S.B.M., Ulrich, C., et al. (2016). Research for PECH Committee – the discard ban and its impact on the maximum sustainable yield objective on fisheries: Workshop. Brussels: European Union.Google Scholar
  68. Richter, A.P., & van Soest, D.P. (2012). Global environmental problems, voluntary action and government intervention. In E. Brousseau, T. Dedeurwaerdere, P.-A. Jouvet, et al. (Eds.), Global environmental commons: Analytical and political challenges in building governance mechanisms (pp. 223–248). Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Schou, M. (2011). Introducing transferable fishing concessions – A check list for operative considerations, (15.08.2011), unpublished.Google Scholar
  70. Schou, M. (2015). BalticSea2020, (16.06.2015), unpublished.Google Scholar
  71. SeafoodSource (2018). First QR code sushi on UK menu. https://www.seafoodsource.com/news/environment-sustainability/first-qr-code-sushi-on-uk-menu. Accessed 31 May 2018.
  72. Sumaila, U.R., Alder, J., Keith, G. (2006). Global scope and economics of illegal fishing. Marine Policy, 30, 696–703.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Thaler, R.H., & Sunstein, C.R. (2009). Nudge, improving decisions about health, wealth and happiness. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
  74. This Fish. (2018). http://thisfish.info. Accessed 31 May 2018.
  75. Toonen, H.M., & Bush, S.R. (2018). The digital frontiers of fisheries governance: Fish attraction devices, drones and satellites. Journal of Environmental Policy & Planning.  https://doi.org/10.1080/1523908X.2018.1461084.
  76. Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1039–1061.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Tyler, T.R. (2006). Why people obey the law. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  79. van Helmond, A.T.M., Chen, C., Poos, J.J. (2015). How effective is electronic monitoring in mixed bottom-trawl fisheries? ICES Journal of Marine Science, 72, 1192–1200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Vohs, K.D., Mead, N.L., Goode, M.R. (2006). The psychological consequences of money. Science, 314, 1154–1156.PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Vyrastekova, J., & van Soest, D. (2003). Centralized common-pool management and local community participation. Land Economics, 79(4), 500–514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  82. Wageningen University Research. (2018). Over Kenniskringen. https://www.wur.nl/nl/Onderzoek-Resultaten/Projecten/Kenniskring-Visserij/Over-Kenniskringen.htm. Accessed 31 May 2018.
  83. Wilson, D.C., Nielsen, J.R., Degnbol, P. (Eds.). (2003). The fisheries co-management experience. Accomplishments, challenges and prospects. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and indicate if changes were made.

The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Thünen Institute of Baltic Sea FisheriesRostockGermany
  2. 2.Department of Neuroscience, Psychology and BehaviourUniversity of LeicesterLeicesterUK

Personalised recommendations