Advertisement

Venture Work pp 59-101 | Cite as

Reason and Rationality in Organization Studies: Employee Motivation

  • Alexander Styhre
Chapter

Abstract

The chapter examines the literature that contrasts reason and rationality, wherein the former is defined as the human cognitive faculty being responsive to social, cultural, and behavioral conditions wherein the individual acts and makes decisions. When enacting reason, concepts such as norms, beliefs, and values are included in, for example, decision-making. In contrast, rationality is a term reserved for calculative and instrumental thinking wherein factors that cannot be accommodated by current calculative practices are either excluded or simplified to the point wherein they are lending themselves to numerical operations and metrics. Reason and rationality are thereafter discussed in terms of their value and role in social and economic activities, including, for example, the domain of venture work, dependent on both these human cognitive faculties. For instance, to tolerate ambiguities and uncertainty at work, one of the core features of any innovative or entrepreneurial pursuit, the capacity to construct meaningful images of work is helpful to impose a structure and a direction on everyday work.

Keywords

Reason Rationality Norms Values Job crafting Delegatory relationships Deeply meaningful work 

References

  1. Amadae, S. M. (2003). Rationalizing capitalist democracy: The Cold War origins of rational choice liberalism. Chicago/London: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  2. Arnoldi, J. (2016). Computer algorithms, market manipulation and the institutionalization of high frequency trading. Theory, Culture & Society, 33(1), 29–52.Google Scholar
  3. Berg, J. M., Grant, A. M., & Johnson, V. (2010). When callings are calling: Crafting work and leisure in pursuit of unanswered occupational callings. Organization Science, 21, 973–994.Google Scholar
  4. Bernstein, L. (1992). Opting out of the legal system: Extralegal contractual relations in the diamond industry. The Journal of Legal Studies, 21(1), 115–157.Google Scholar
  5. Blair, M. M., & Stout, L. A. (2001). Director accountability and the mediating role of the corporate board. Washington University Law Review, 79(2), 403–449.Google Scholar
  6. Bunderson, J. S., & Thompson, J. A. (2009). The call of the wild: Zookeepers, callings, and the double-edged sword of deeply meaningful work. Administrative Science Quarterly, 54(1), 32–57.Google Scholar
  7. Buturovic, Z., & Tasic, S. (2015). Kahneman’s failed revolution against economic orthodoxy. Critical Review, 27(2), 127–145.Google Scholar
  8. Cardon, M. S., Post, C., & Forster, W. R. (2017). Team entrepreneurial passion: Its emergence and influence in new venture teams. Academy of Management Review, 42(1), 283–305.Google Scholar
  9. Charny, D. (1990). Nonlegal sanctions in commercial relationships. Harvard Law Review, 104(2), 393–467.Google Scholar
  10. Christensen, J. (2017). The power of economists within the state. Redwood City: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  11. Citron, D. K., & Pasquale, F. A. (2014). The scored society: Due process for automated predictions. Washington Law Review, 89(1), 1–33.Google Scholar
  12. Collins, R. (1981). On the microfoundations of macrosociology. American Journal of Sociology, 86(5), 984–1014.Google Scholar
  13. Coombs, N. (2016). What is an algorithm? Financial regulation in the era of high-frequency trading. Economy and Society, 45(2), 278–302.Google Scholar
  14. Correll, S. J., Ridgeway, C. L., Zuckerman, E. W., Jank, S., Jordan-Bloch, S., & Nakagawa, S. (2017). It’s the conventional thought that counts: How third-order inference produces status advantage. American Sociological Review, 82(2), 297–327.Google Scholar
  15. Dobbin, F., & Dowd, T. J. (2000). The market that antitrust built: Public policy, private coercion, and railroad acquisitions, 1825 to 1922. American Sociological Review, 65(5), 631–657.Google Scholar
  16. Dobbin, F., & Kelly, E. L. (2007). How to stop harassment: Professional construction of legal compliance in organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 112(4), 1203–1243.Google Scholar
  17. Edelman, L. (1992). Legal ambiguity and symbolic structures: Organizational meditation of civil rights law. American Journal of Sociology, 97(6), 1531–1576.Google Scholar
  18. Edelman, L. B., Uggen, C., & Erlanger. Howard S. (1999). The endogeneity of legal regulation: Grievance procedures as rational myth. American Journal of Sociology, 105(2), 406–454.Google Scholar
  19. Erickson, P., Klein, J. L., Daston, L., Lemov, R., Sturm, T., & Gordin, M. D. (2013). How reason almost lost its mind: The strange career of Cold War rationality. Chicago/London: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  20. Fourcade, M. (2009). Economists and societies: Discipline and profession in the United States, Britain, and France, 1890s to 1990s. Princeton/London: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  21. Fourcade, M., & Healy, K. (2017). Seeing like a market. Socio-Economic Review, 15(1), 9–29.Google Scholar
  22. Fourcade, M., Ollion, E., & Algan, Y. (2015). The superiority of economists. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 29(1), 89–113.Google Scholar
  23. Fukuyama, F. (2016). Governance: What do we know, and how do we know it? Annual Review of Political Science, 19, 89–105.Google Scholar
  24. Green, D. P., & Shapiro, I. (1994). Pathologies of rational choice theory: A critique of applications in political science. New Haven/London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  25. Hirsh, C. E. (2009). The strength of weak enforcement: The impact of discrimination charges, legal environments, and organizational conditions on workplace segregation. American Sociological Review, 74(2), 245–271.Google Scholar
  26. Hyman, L. (2011). Debtor nation: The history of America in red ink. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  27. Johns, F. (2016). Global governance through the pairing of list and algorithm. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 34(1), 126–149.Google Scholar
  28. Jolls, C., Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. R. (1998). A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Review, 50, 1471–1550.Google Scholar
  29. Kar, R. (2016). Contract as empowerment. The University of Chicago Law Review, 83(2), 759–834.Google Scholar
  30. Keys, B. J., Mukherjee, T., Seru, A., & Vig, V. (2009). Did securitization lead to lax screening? Evidence from subprime loans. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125, 307–362.Google Scholar
  31. Lang, A. T. F. (2013). The legal construction of economic rationalities. Journal of Law and Society, 40(1), 155–171.Google Scholar
  32. Lange, A.-C., Lenglet, M., & Seyfert, R. (2016). Cultures of high-frequency trading: Mapping the landscape of algorithmic developments in contemporary financial markets. Economy and Society, 45(2), 149–165.Google Scholar
  33. Lenglet, M., & Mol, J. (2016). Squaring the speed of light? Regulating market access in algorithmic finance. Economy and Society, 45(2), 201–229.Google Scholar
  34. Liu, Y., & Grusky, D. B. (2013). The payoff to skill in the third industrial revolution. American Journal of Sociology, 118(5), 1330–1374.Google Scholar
  35. Macaulay, S. (1963). Non-contractual relations in business: A preliminary study. American Sociological Review, 28(1), 55–67.Google Scholar
  36. Mead, G. H. (1934). Mind, self, and society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  37. Mills, C. W. (1959). The sociological imagination. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  38. Murphy, J. B. (1995). Rational choice theory as social physics. Critical Review, 9(1–2), 155–174.Google Scholar
  39. Neyland, D. (2015). On organizing algorithms. Theory, Culture and Society, 32(1), 119–132.Google Scholar
  40. Offer, A., & Söderberg, G. (2016). The Nobel factor: The prize in economics, social democracy, and the market turn. Princeton/London: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  41. Pasquale, F. (2015). The black box society: The secret algorithms that control money and information. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  42. Pedriana, N., & Stryker, R. (2004). The strength of a weak agency: Enforcement of Title VII of the 1964 Civil Rights Act and the expansion of state capacity, 1965–1971. American Journal of Sociology, 110(3), 709–760.Google Scholar
  43. Polillo, S. (2011). Money, moral authority, and the politics of creditworthiness. American Sociological Review, 76(3), 437–464.Google Scholar
  44. Posner, E. A. (1996). Law, economics, and inefficient norms. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 144(5), 1697–1744.Google Scholar
  45. Reynaud, B. (2017). Forms of trust and conditions for their stability. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 41(1), 127–1145.Google Scholar
  46. Rizzo, M. J., & Whitman, D. G. (2009). The knowledge problem of new paternalism. Brigham Young University Law Review, 905(4), 905–968.Google Scholar
  47. Rona-Tas, A., & Hiss, S. (2010). The role of ratings in the subprime mortgage crisis: The art of corporate and the science of consumer credit rating. Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 30A, 115–155.Google Scholar
  48. Schabram, K., & Maitlis, S. (2017). Negotiating the challenge of a calling: Sensemaking in animal shelter work. Academy of Management Journal, 60(2), 584–609.Google Scholar
  49. Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
  50. Selznick, P. (1959). The sociology of law. Journal of Legal Education, 12, 521–531.Google Scholar
  51. Selznick, P. (1963). Legal institutions and social controls. Vanderbilt Law Review, 17, 79–90.Google Scholar
  52. Simmel, G. (1978). The philosophy of money. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
  53. Simmons, O. S. (2015). Delaware’s global threat. Journal of Corporation Law, 41(1), 217–264.Google Scholar
  54. Smith, D. G. (2002). Critical resource theory of fiduciary duty. Vanderbilt Law Review, 55, 1399–1497.Google Scholar
  55. Steiner, C. (2012). Automate this: How algorithms came to rule our world. New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
  56. Sullivan, T. A., Warren, E., & Westbrook, J. L. (2006). Less stigma and more financial distress: An empirical analysis of the extraordinary increase in bankruptcy filings. Stanford Law Review, 59(1), 213–256.Google Scholar
  57. Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2003). Libertarian paternalism. The American Economic Review, 93(2), 175–179.Google Scholar
  58. Totaro, P., & Ninno, D. (2014). The concept of algorithm as an interpretative key of modern rationality. Theory, Culture and Society, 31(4), 29–49.Google Scholar
  59. Troyer, L., & Younts, C. W. (1997). Whose expectations matter? The relative power of first-order and second-order expectations in determining social influence. American Journal of Sociology, 103(3), 692–732.Google Scholar
  60. Wilde, O. (2016). Only dull people are brilliant at breakfast. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
  61. Willer, R., Kuwabara, K., & Macy Michael, W. (2009). The false enforcement of unpopular norms. American Journal of Sociology, 115(2), 451–490.Google Scholar
  62. Wittgenstein, L. (1953). Remarks in the foundations of mathematics (G. H. von Wright, R. Rhees & G. E. M. Anscombe, Ed., & G. E. M. Anscombe, Trans.). Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  63. Wright, A. L., Zammuto, R. F., & Liesch, P. W. (2017). Maintaining the value of a profession: Institutional work and moral emotions in the emergency department. Academy of Management Journal, 60(1), 200–237.Google Scholar
  64. Wrzesniewski, A., & Dutton, J. E. (2001). Crafting a job: Revisioning employees as active crafters of their work. Academy of Management Review, 26, 179–201.Google Scholar
  65. Zarsky, T. (2016). The trouble with algorithmic decisions: An analytic road map to examine efficiency and fairness in automated and opaque decision making. Science, Technology, & Human Values, 41(1), 118–132.Google Scholar
  66. Ziewitz, M. (2016). Governing algorithms: Myth, mess, and methods. Science, Technology, & Human Values, 41(1), 3–16.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  • Alexander Styhre
    • 1
  1. 1.School of Business, Economics and LawUniversity of GothenburgGothenburgSweden

Personalised recommendations